* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Use Green Taxes and Market Instruments to Reduce Greenhouse Gas
Economics of global warming wikipedia , lookup
Kyoto Protocol wikipedia , lookup
German Climate Action Plan 2050 wikipedia , lookup
Climate change mitigation wikipedia , lookup
Emissions trading wikipedia , lookup
2009 United Nations Climate Change Conference wikipedia , lookup
Politics of global warming wikipedia , lookup
European Union Emission Trading Scheme wikipedia , lookup
Citizens' Climate Lobby wikipedia , lookup
United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change wikipedia , lookup
Decarbonisation measures in proposed UK electricity market reform wikipedia , lookup
IPCC Fourth Assessment Report wikipedia , lookup
Climate change in New Zealand wikipedia , lookup
Economics of climate change mitigation wikipedia , lookup
Carbon pricing in Australia wikipedia , lookup
Low-carbon economy wikipedia , lookup
Carbon governance in England wikipedia , lookup
Views on the Kyoto Protocol wikipedia , lookup
Business action on climate change wikipedia , lookup
Mitigation of global warming in Australia wikipedia , lookup
Briefing February 2008 Use Green Taxes and Market Instruments to Reduce Greenhouse Gas Emissions At a Glance Tax measures, market forces, and efficient regulation will be key to setting a price for carbon and other greenhouse gas emissions. Green taxes and tax credits are needed by Canadian firms to accelerate their technological adaptation to a carbon-priced world. A cap and trade system should be implemented as a complement to green taxes. The Challenge: Greenhouse Gas Emissions Still Rising S igns of global warming are evident everywhere— mountain glaciers and the Arctic polar cap are melting, the sea level is rising, key stages in plant development are occurring earlier each year, and species distribution is changing rapidly. The 20th century was likely the warmest century in the past millennium, and the 1980s and 1990s were the warmest decades since record keeping began in the mid-1800s. The past 15 years alone have seen 10 of the warmest years on record. The scientific community has concluded with a high degree of confidence that anthropogenic greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions are responsible for the current warming of the planet. This changing climate is likely to have negative repercussions on many aspects of the economy and economic performance and trends | The Conference Board of Canada Overview: Canadian Tax Reform for Sustainable Prosperity The overall Canadian taxation system is pivotal in determining the country’s economic performance, productivity growth, international competitiveness, and environmental sustainability. Taxes do more than collect monies for governments to spend—they establish relative incentives for work, savings, and investment. Taxes can selectively encourage, or inhibit, behaviour by individuals and firms—behaviour that has a direct impact on productivity growth and on the environment. As such, it is important that all three levels of government in Canada understand and take into account the interaction of the structures of their respective tax regimes and related tax rates when designing the reforms needed to enhance Canadian economic performance, competitiveness, and sustainability. In recent budgets and economic statements, our governments have taken steps to restructure the tax system and to reduce tax rates. While many of these steps are welcome, the fundamental issue is whether the evolving tax system as a whole is being optimized to create sustainable wealth for Canadians. Therefore, the objective of this briefing series is to consider specific reforms to the Canadian tax system, guided by the concept of “sustainable prosperity.” The theme of sustainable prosperity emerged from the Conference Board’s Canada Project. This three-year research program will serve as a foundation for the Conference Board’s new research program, CanCompete, as well as for the Board’s work more broadly. Our intention is to produce several tax reform briefings that will appear periodically during the coming year. All of them will adhere to a set of principles for tax reform that are set out here and shall be included in each briefing. the environment. There is great uncertainty and debate about these repercussions, but scientists believe a relatively small change in average global temperatures could have drastic impacts. These include an increase in costly climatic events (such as flooding and drought) and potentially irreversible disruptions. For example, critical infrastructure will be at greater risk from extreme weather events and natural catastrophes. Roads, harbours, bridges, and buildings will face more extreme conditions than before, and existing infrastructure may suffer damage or even destruction. Climate change will likely exacerbate the problem of rising health spending. The aging population will be adversely affected— especially by extreme heat. Urban air will become more polluted since heat tends to increase smog, and this will add to the problems of those suffering from respiratory and cardiac diseases (among many other health concerns). Extreme weather events and natural disasters will lead to injury and to illnesses related to such things as contamination of drinking water. There will be damage to civic and public-health infrastructure. Mental health distress, especially in populations whose way of life will be threatened (the Inuit, for example), will become more prevalent. Under the Kyoto Protocol, Canada is supposed to reduce GHG emissions to 6 per cent below 1990 levels, on average, during the years 2008–12. However, little real progress has been made by governments, businesses, or individuals, and 2005 levels were 32.7 per cent higher than Canada’s Kyoto benchmark. It was no surprise that the federal government announced in the 2007 Speech from the Throne that Canada’s emissions cannot be brought to the level required under the Kyoto Protocol within the compliance period. Critical infrastructure will be at greater risk from extreme weather events and natural catastrophes. At a global level, thanks to the economic boom led by India and China and their reliance on fossil fuels as energy sources, GHG emissions have been growing much faster since 1990 than anticipated. Current concentration levels in the atmosphere (and their consequences) were expected 10 years from now. Many scientists believe that we are near or at a tipping point. Mitigation measures are urgently needed in order to curb future emissions and to capture carbon before it enters the atmosphere. Investing in adaptation measures is also required, since climate change is occurring faster than expected, and global emissions are likely to continue growing for several more years. Moreover, climate change would continue to occur over the coming decades even if global GHG emissions were reduced significantly in the near future. Even with early concerted action, the concentration of GHGs already in the atmosphere would not diminish enough to make a difference over the next couple of decades. Reducing emissions significantly in the near term is critically important, but it will take time to reverse the concentration of greenhouse gases. The Conference Board of Canada | Canada produces about 2 per cent of the world’s annual GHG emissions. Whether or not we reduce GHG emissions matters only a little in global terms. However, reducing GHG emissions requires the global participation of as many countries as possible. Decisive domestic policy action and a commitment to develop and deploy leadingedge technologies that improve both our environmental and economic performance will have a dual benefit: it will help position Canada as a leader in global negotiations and build a consensus for effective global action, and it will support domestic technological innovation. Specific Tax Reforms for Sustainability On January 7, the National Roundtable on the Environ ment and the Economy (NRTEE) released its path-breaking report Getting to 2050: Canada’s Transition to a LowEmission Future. The report calls for a market-based policy on climate change that takes the form of a green tax, a cap and trade system, or a combination of the two. The Conference Board of Canada, working independently from the NRTEE, has reached essentially the same policy conclusions (although in greater detail). We believe that price signals via the tax system, coupled with market forces and efficient regulation, will be central to successful climate change adjustment by Canadian firms and the Canadian economy. We also believe that Canadian firms need other tax incentives to accelerate their technological adaptation to a carbon-priced world. Use Taxes and Markets to Put a Price on Carbon GHG emissions are a negative consequence of economic activity, or what economists call a “negative externality.” Since there is no price on these negative consequences, consumers and producers have no need to factor the cost of GHG emissions into their decision-making. The challenge, therefore, is to derive a price for carbon and GHGs, which consumers and producers would then take into account. The answer is to establish the long-term price of carbon and other greenhouse gases, and build that price into business and consumer decision-making. There are essentially two options for determining the price of carbon and other GHGs: a market-based “cap and trade” system (also called a tradable permits system); and green taxes. Under the cap and trade option, governments issue permits that cap overall GHG production for specific emissions sources (for example, power stations or industrial plants). The cap and trade option would also include a market for emissions permits in which emitters that have more efficient systems or technology in place, or adjust faster, have the opportunity to sell “carbon credits” to firms that cannot meet their cap targets as quickly. A spot price for carbon will emerge from these trades. There are essentially two options for determining the price of carbon and other GHGs: a market-based “cap and trade” system (also called a tradable permits system); and green taxes. The green tax option would see the government directly set a benchmark price for carbon and other GHGs by introducing taxes on GHG producers and consumers. The challenge is to set a GHG emission or “green” tax at a level that encourages changed behaviour by producers and consumers. (The newly introduced rebate and tax system for automobiles purchased in Canada is a specific variation of a green tax—it is based on a given vehicle’s fuel efficiency, which translates into its potential emission levels.) The economic literature and experience elsewhere suggest that the current average price of carbon is US$20–30 per tonne. However, to quote the British government’s acclaimed report Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change, “the pricing signal should reflect the marginal damage caused by emissions, and rise over time to reflect the increasing damages as the stock of GHGs grows.” The price for EU emissions permits for the next EU trading period (2008–12) is about $25 per tonne. See David Victor and Danny Cullenward, “Making Carbon Markets Work,” Scientific American, December 2007. We used the online version, dated September 24, 2007. Sir Nicholas Stern, Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change, (London: Cambridge University Press, 2007), p. 309. This report was released by the U.K. government in October 2006 and published by Cambridge University Press the following year. | The Conference Board of Canada In more concrete terms, the green tax level that would spur adjustment by carbon dioxide (CO2) producers will need to be at least as high as the cost of “abatement” for a given sector or firm. In the short term, abatement may mean a different mix and level of outputs; in the longer term, it means switching to new technologies or systems. Over time, therefore, green taxes will need to increase, since GHG abatement costs rise along a cost curve for most emitters. Abatement costs in some sectors are well above the current estimated average price for GHGs. A tax around $25 per tonne might encourage short-term adjustment, but it will not on its own induce significant change in behaviour in those sectors. The same rationale applies for consumers—a low carbon price might not trigger the change in goods consumed (e.g., more efficient vehicles and appliances, upgraded furnaces and insulation) or behaviour modification (e.g., driving less, using public transit, lowering the thermostat) that would result in significantly lower consumer-related emissions. Direct GHG taxation is less politically appealing than a cap and trade system that can be positioned as a marketbased approach in which governments set GHG targets via regulation and then let market forces work. A cap and trade system would determine the short-term spot price of GHGs and can be readily adapted to international circumstances through cross-border trading of emissions permits, as is currently occurring in Europe. The current systems in Canada for constraining GHG emissions tend to blend aspects of both approaches. Alberta’s system (discussed briefly here) might be considered a hybrid of the tax and cap systems. The coming federal program to cap the intensity of emissions is another variation and may or may not lead to lower overall emissions. (See box “A Work in Progress: The Federal Plan for Emissions” on page 9.) Introduce Green Taxes Green taxes should be introduced for industrial and consumer emitters in order to establish in the public’s mind a visible price for carbon. The whole point of a green tax is to put a price on “negative externalities” that are not captured by the market price system. That means raising the price of goods and services that produce more GHGs (of which carbon dioxide is the most important). The change in relative prices, based on the added cost of GHGs, will influence long-term decision-making by businesses and consumers, and gradually reduce the level of GHG emissions. The simplest system would set a common initial tax rate for all emitters—for example, $25 per tonne of GHGs emitted. As discussed here, the tax would need to rise gradually over time to encourage switching to new technologies and systems that will permit the ongoing reduction of GHGs from higher-cost sources of emissions. Canada’s 2005 level of CO2-equivalent GHG emissions was 747 megatonnes. That implies an initial potential tax revenue of just under $19 billion. Since the primary purpose of a green tax is to change behaviour, not to generate additional government revenues, a national GHG tax system should be designed to be either revenue neutral or fiscally neutral for governments as a whole. To be revenue neutral, green tax revenues should therefore be offset by cuts to other taxes, particularly taxes that impede Canada’s international competitiveness. The whole point of a green tax is to put a price on “negative externalities” that are not captured by the market price system. Fiscal neutrality would mean taking into account the fact that a green tax would fall disproportionately on specific regions and sectors. Alberta currently accounts for approximately 30 per cent of Canada’s GHG emissions, Ontario 26 per cent, and Quebec 12 per cent. The regional impacts would depend in part on whether the green taxes were For an excellent detailed description and analysis of the economic advantages of using green taxes to price carbon, see William Nordhaus, “The Challenge of Global Warming: Economic Models and Environmental Policy,” [online]. New Haven: Yale University, July 2007 [cited January 15, 2008]. http://nordhaus.econ.yale.edu/dice_mss_072407_all.pdf The January 2008 report by the National Roundtable on the Environment and the Economy, Getting to 2050: Canada’s Transition to a Low-Emission Future, sets out four different carbon tax adjustment paths, with varying impacts on CO2 emissions and on the economy according to their modelling. The Conference Board of Canada | applied against all emission sources or focused on large, final emitters. The latter approach would place a larger burden on Alberta, because a large proportion of its economy is related to oil and gas development and production and because of its reliance on coal-fired power generation. Furthermore, a green tax that leads to intended reductions in fossil fuel consumption would adversely impact fossil fuel producers and provinces. Adjustments, therefore, should be made to other taxes, expenditures, and transfers to minimize the overall financial burden and impact of a green tax on any one region or sector. This would go a long way toward making the implementation of green taxes more politically palatable in regions and sectors where emissions are highest. For all industrial emitters, a benchmark green tax could be introduced on their emissions resulting from production. If a trading system were then introduced, the green tax could be rebated to those firms that make use of the tradable permits system. Sellers and buyers of GHG permits should both be eligible for tax rebates on GHGs that are traded at or above the GHG tax rate. Transportation is another important source of GHG emissions. Hence, consumers of fossil fuel for transportation should pay an identified green consumption tax, so that the end price of fuel for consumers would reflect the cost of emitting GHGs into the atmosphere. In addition to a green tax on fuel consumption, a combination of regulations that promote ongoing improvement in fuel efficiency, and other price signals, should be adopted. For example, the recently introduced federal auto “feebate” system (fees and rebates on new cars Achieving Global Consensus: Carrots or Sticks? One of the many unresolved issues in the development of a global strategy on climate change is how to create an international level playing field. From the perspective of fair international business competition, there should be no “free riders”—firms and countries that keep producing GHGs for free. In order to avoid a “race to the bottom,” major trading countries must be included in a consensus on climatechange policy. This means that all major emitting countries (including not only the United States, but China and India, as well) should be part of any international agreement on climate change. As the Stern Review pointed out, in the struggle to stabilize and reduce emissions we no longer have the luxury of time. The next two or three decades are expected to be critical in determining the extent and duration of the impacts of a warming climate. Losing another decade to squabbling over a global consensus will result in much higher long-term costs. The nations that have taken action must redouble their efforts. Nations such as Canada that participated in the Kyoto process but are unlikely to meet their commitments still need to introduce policy instruments to curb emissions growth. They must then reach the point of reducing emissions levels as soon as possible—certainly within the next two decades. Countries such as China, India, and the United States must also commit to action. So what happens if certain countries refuse to join a global consensus for action on climate change? Up to now, there has been insufficient discussion of “carrots and sticks”—the combination of positive incentives for change and punitive action against countries (and goods and services from those countries) that are not part of a global consensus on climate change. Positive incentives—such as providing emerging markets with special access to state-of-the-art environmental technology— would be encouraged. But punitive actions must also be considered. International trade mechanisms—such as a system of green tariffs—may emerge. These would be needed to ensure that footing the bill for GHG reduction does not leave countries less competitive than their trade competitors that refuse to join in. This issue deserves to be debated at length in international organizations such as the World Trade Organization, International Monetary Fund, and World Bank. French Prime Minister Nicolas Sarkozy has already threatened to impose green tariffs on China if it does not introduce GHG taxes on its industries. Conversely, exporters from countries that put a price on GHGs could receive green tax credits to ensure they do not face a competitive disadvantage. The Conference Board of Canada has been a long-time champion of free trade, a position based upon the significant evidence of trade’s positive effect on living standards. We are certainly not advocating arbitrary barriers to trade in any form. However, there is logic to using a combination of positive incentives and green tariffs, if required, to ensure compliance with international climate agreements and a level playing field internationally for business. In the absence of a global consensus on using GHG taxes or other mechanisms to price GHGs, a green tariff could be an efficient mechanism for pricing GHGs on imports from countries that are not complying. Any green tariff regime would have to be simple and include safeguards to ensure such tariffs were not used as protectionist measures. The bottom line is that we see this “carrots and sticks” debate as unavoidable in a world of GHG pricing where all countries do not meet international norms. | The Conference Board of Canada linked to fuel efficiency) should be expanded and refined. Instead of trigger and cutoff points at specific average fuel consumption levels, as is currently the case, the adjustments in the rebates or fees should be more gradual across the full range of vehicles, with the zero point (no fee or rebate) set at the desired level of average fuel consumption (and GHG emissions) per vehicle. Such a policy would more effectively encourage the purchase of fuel-efficient cars and eliminate the sharp adjustment points that exist under the current system. Cars that have been on the road awhile generally produce more GHGs per kilometre than new vehicles. Older vehicles should have a fee price on emissions, too. A GHG-based fee system could be progressively introduced for all vehicles as part of the provincially-run licence permit system, to encourage consumers to accelerate their purchase of newer, cleaner-running vehicles. Fossil fuels used in home, industrial, and office heating systems could also be taxed based on GHGs generated. Since the consumer will ultimately pay most of the green tax on all emissions, GHG tax credits could be used to mitigate the impact on lower income consumers. Current Status Canada does not yet have a national system of greenhouse gas taxes covering the full range of GHG emissions. Cautious initial steps have been taken, such as introducing a federal feebate program for new vehicles, based on fuel efficiency—but this is only a start. Conference Board of Canada Advice Canada needs to go much further, must faster, in introducing a national, comprehensive, and coordinated system of green taxes that would set a price on greenhouse gas emissions. This GHG tax system should be implemented in tandem with a cap and trade system. As a first principle, the national GHG tax system should be revenue neutral or fiscally neutral. Green tax revenues should be offset, either with cuts to other taxes (particularly taxes that impede Canada’s international competitiveness) or through increases to program spending or tax incentives that promote the development and adoption of clean technologies. Implement a “Cap and Trade” System for Major Emitters As a complement to green taxes across all sources of GHGs, a cap and trade system should be implemented for major emitters and others that want to access a trading system. Such a system combines regulation (a determination by government of the permitted level of greenhouse gas emissions and the desired distribution of permits among emitters) with market forces, via trading among emitters to determine a price for carbon and other greenhouse gases. In Canada, major emitters—those with facilities that emit at least 100,000 tonnes of CO2 per year—represent about 35 per cent of GHG emissions, according to Environment Canada data for 2005. Most major emitters are in the energy sector (concentrated in electricity production and extraction of fossil fuels) and in energy-intensive sectors such as steel, aluminum, chemicals, mining, cement, and forest products. The economic literature suggests that a cap and trade system may be preferable to a green tax for major emitters. The actual costs of GHG emissions abatement are unknown, as is the impact that taxes at a given level would have on overall emissions. It will take time to find the appropriate level and path for green taxes. We argued earlier that a green tax should be revenue or fiscally neutral, meaning it should be offset by a decrease in other existing taxes. However, for major emitters, much of the benefit of any reduction in general business taxation would be captured by businesses outside the energy and energyintensive sectors. This would take net revenues away from the energy-based sectors—revenues that could otherwise be invested in energy research and development and new technology. In comparison, a cap and trade system could start to reduce GHG emissions as soon as permits were distributed and a trading system established. The market price would vary depending on changes to the supply of and demand for permits. The allocation of GHG permits will therefore need to be fair-minded in order to build business and popular support and be consistent with declining The Conference Board of Canada | GHG emissions. There are many feasible options and mechanisms for distributing emissions permits. A cap and trade system would have the advantage of keeping revenues within the energy and energy-intensive sectors. As firms in the energy and energy-intensive sectors buy and sell permits among themselves, they would have both the incentive and the financing needed to play a central role in energy and technological innovation. As suggested earlier in this briefing, green taxes could be rebated to those firms making use of a tradable permits system. Statistics Canada’s current efforts to measure emissions would need to be supplemented by additional reporting requirements. out necessarily relying on a centralized trading system or permit trading on an exchange, as is done elsewhere. The liquidity of the Alberta credits market and its effectiveness at “discovering” the value of emissions will be key success factors. Current Status Under the current GHG reduction plan, Canada has taken the initial steps to promote the reduction of greenhouse gas emissions. However, these steps are modest. More needs to be done, including aggressively introducing market-based instruments such as a cap and trade system. Exhibit 1 Canadian GHG Emissions for 2005 (megatonnes CO2 equivalent) As firms in the energy and energy-intensive sectors buy and sell permits among themselves, they would have both the incentive and the financing needed to play a central role in energy and technological innovation. Concrete examples of cap and trade systems include the European Union’s carbon market and the U.S. market in sulfur emissions. However, the European carbon market has run into problems largely due to mismanagement of the initial allocation of permits and insufficient information on the supply of, and demand for, carbon credits. The legislation that came into force this year for large final emitters in Alberta is an example of an emissions permits system that does not currently include permit trading. Rather than creating a market for emissions, the Alberta system requires large final emitters to reduce their emissions to the capped level, purchase offsets within the province, or contribute $15 per tonne of excess emissions into a technology fund. Alberta companies whose emissions are below the target level will be permitted to sell credits, creating a form of market for emissions with Options could include attaching the green tax for major emitters directly to the distribution of emissions permits (e.g., emissions permits would cost $25 per tonne annually), or auctioning the permits to bidders with a pre-determined reservation price. For an excellent assessment of the shortcomings of the current EU carbon trading market, see Victor and Cullenward, Making Carbon Markets Work. Transportation 200 (27%) Fossil fuel production and upgrading 154 (21%) Electricity Generation 129 (17%) Other Industries (incl. manufacturing) 100 (13%) Residential and Commercial 79 (10%) Agriculture 57 (8%) Waste 28 (4%) Source: Environment Canada, National Inventory Report 1990–2005. | The Conference Board of Canada Conference Board of Canada Advice For major emitters, a cap and trade system has considerable benefits and needs to be put in place immediately. It should focus on actual reductions in GHGs by major emitters. The Canadian cap and trade system should be coordinated with world permit markets so that exchanges across borders can happen if that is judged to be the least costly solution to reducing carbon emissions. Introduce an Environmental Investment Tax Credit for Green Technologies As part of the climate change and sustainability policy agenda, governments should be prepared to help firms accelerate the adoption of more environmentally friendly Green Bonds—A Positive Idea, But No Magic Solution Government-backed “green bonds” have been proposed as a means of raising new risk capital for environmental investments. Proponents argue that, due to the riskier nature of investing in new environmental technologies, financing would be hard to come by. They say green bonds, supported in whole or in part by the government, would help fill the financing gap. This new instrument would be similar to an environmental investment tax credit in that the government’s fiscal capacity would be used to support targeted investment in greener technologies. Similar selection criteria would be needed to determine which environmental technologies would qualify for a green bond and which would qualify for an environmental investment tax credit. The challenge in both cases would be determining to what extent the bonds or credits actually support environmental investment (since investment in greener technologies at some level would still have occurred without government support). A key weakness of green bonds is that, since the return on investment in environmental technologies is unknown, it would be impossible to determine in advance the cost to government of covering its guarantees on the bonds. In comparison, the fiscal cost of an environmental investment tax credit could be determined with greater certainty. Firms would only qualify for the credit once they had actually made the investment. The environmental investment tax credit could be capped in total dollar terms or as a share of a given firm’s revenues or costs. A green investment tax credit would also be less complicated than a green bond to administer since it could be managed under the existing tax system. technologies. Therefore, The Conference Board of Canada recommends the introduction of a targeted environmental investment tax credit for green technologies. The credit would be available to firms in all sectors that are adapting to an economy in which carbon has an explicit price. Similar to the accelerated capital cost allowance that was introduced in the February 2007 federal budget, an environmental investment tax credit would be available to firms that actually spend cash on investments in green technologies. This would focus the use of such credits and reduce the opportunity for abuse. The environmental investment tax credit would be additional to the existing two-year accelerated capital cost allowances (CCA) for manufacturing. To avoid accusations of favouritism, an eligibility list of new environmental technologies that would qualify for the environmental investment tax credit could be determined and managed based on advice from an independent or arms-length panel of experts. Investment in new environmental techniques, such as carbon capture and storage (or “sequestration”), would be a top priority. To contain the fiscal costs of these credits, the amount of the credits available could be capped in total dollar terms, or capped for individual firms as a share of business revenues or expenses. Current Status Governments currently do not make aggressive use of the tax system to favour new investment in environmentally friendly technologies. Conference Board of Canada Advice Governments should introduce an environmental investment tax credit that would be available to firms. This would be similar to the accelerated CCA for manufacturing. An eligibility list for the environmental investment tax credit could be determined and managed based on advice from an expert panel. Such a credit would give added emphasis to clean technologies that reduce GHG emissions. The Conference Board of Canada | Conclusion In order to place Canada on a path toward slowing the growth of (and eventually reducing) greenhouse gas emissions, the time has come to put a price on CO2 and other GHGs. Green taxes should be introduced for industrial and consumer emitters. This would establish a visible price for carbon. A national GHG tax system should be designed to be either revenue neutral or fiscally neutral for governments as a whole. As a complement to green taxes across all sources of GHGs, a cap and trade system should be implemented for major emitters and others that want to access such a system. Green taxes could be rebated to those making use of a cap and trade system. Governments should also introduce an environmental investment tax credit. This would be available to firms in addition to the accelerated CCA for manufacturing. Introducing a combination of green taxes, market instruments, and efficient regulation at a national level would be a significant step toward putting Canada on a path to sustainability, and would have the added benefit of strengthening Canada’s leadership position in the coming international negotiations on climate change. A Work in Progress: The Federal Plan for Emissions Canada’s Regulatory Framework for Air Emissions, published by the federal government in April of 2007, sets out “. . . the cornerstone of the government’s broader efforts to address the challenges of climate change and air pollution.” The framework indicates that industrial sources account for 50 per cent of Canada’s greenhouse gas emissions, and it targets the following sectors for new regulations: Electricity generation produced by combustion Oil and gas Forest products Smelting and refining Iron and steel Some mining Cement, lime, and chemicals. In December of 2007, Environment Minister John Baird announced that those industries will be required to report on and reduce emissions intensity. According to the framework, existing facilities will be required to reduce their emissions intensity by 18 per cent from the 2006 level by the end of 2010. An additional 2 per cent intensity reduction will be required each year thereafter through 2020. Firms will be permitted to meet these obligations through direct emissions reduction, contributions to a technology fund, emissions trading, credits from Kyoto clean development mechanisms, and recognition of early actions between 1992 and 2006. The details of each of these measures are being developed. For new facilities, initial emissions standards must be met for a three-year period, with a 2 per cent annual reduction required thereafter. Government of Canada. Regulatory Framework for Air Emissions. (Ottawa: Author, 2007.) p. iii. According to data published for 2005, the selected industries account for approximately one-third of Canada’s total GHG emissions. The group experienced an increase of 57.1 MtCO2e (mega tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent)—or 30 per cent in total emissions—between 1990 and 2005. Most of this increase was concentrated in electricity generation by combustion (33.7 MtCO2e increase), oil and gas (21 MtCO2e increase), and mining (9.42 MtCO2e increase). In a rapidly expanding sector such as oil and gas, it remains to be seen how large a reduction in total emissions will result from an 18 per cent reduction in intensity for existing facilities over a three-year period, coupled with annual 2 per cent longer-term reductions in intensity for all facilities. Additional measures are included in the framework to increase use of public transit, to improve average new vehicle fuel efficiency, and to encourage Canadians to use energy more efficiently. The overall objective is to reduce GHG emissions 20 per cent from their 2006 level by 2020, and 60 percent to 70 percent by 2050. This compares with the Kyoto target of a 6 per cent reduction from the 1990 level to be achieved on average between 2008 and 2012. Given the 32.7 per cent growth in GHG emissions between 1990 and 2005, the Kyoto target for emissions will be met at least a decade late. It is noteworthy that, according to Environment Canada’s sustainability indicators, emissions intensity for the economy as a whole fell by an average of 1.3 per cent per year between 1990 and 2005 while total emissions rose 25 per cent. Environment Canada. National Inventory Report, Greenhouse Gas Sources and Sinks In Canada, 1990-2005. (Ottawa: Author, 2007.) Data extracted from Tables 2-2, 2-3, 3-3, 3-5, and 4-1. Environment Canada. Canadian Environmental Sustainability Indicators 2007. (Ottawa: Author, 2007.) 10 | The Conference Board of Canada Guiding Principles: Tax Reform for Sustainable Prosperity Any fundamental reform of the Canadian tax system should be guided by an understanding of the underlying principles of taxation. The reform must also be workable within the existing fiscal context of fiscal balance, or surplus, and declining public sector debt burdens. Our analysis of the extensive economic literature on tax system design and implementation has led us to propose the following eight principles for tax reform that would support sustainable prosperity for Canada. Principles 1. Implement any tax reform within a framework of long-term fiscal sustainability. 2. Tax least what you value the most. For example, if savings and investment are more beneficial than consumption to the economy over the long term (which is the consensus view in the economic literature), then the tax system should have a bias toward lower rates of taxation on employment earnings, savings, and investment, and higher rates on consumption. 3. Make the tax system as simple and transparent as possible. It has been many decades since the Canadian tax system underwent a comprehensive assessment. Successive governments at all levels have introduced special tax treatment for specific sectors and interests, adding layer upon layer of complexity to the system, usually without examining the overall (and unintended) consequences for the economy. A strong case can therefore be made for tax reform that simplifies the overall system and makes it more transparent and accessible for all Canadians. 4. Design business taxation so that Canadian businesses have at least a level playing field with their major competitors. In an era of globalization, businesses are able to move elements of production to whatever location offers the best competitive advantage. Therefore, business tax competitiveness has become a critical factor in business decision-making. 5. When setting tax reform priorities, give priority treatment to boosting productivity growth and the impact of taxes on efficiency. Given the strong evidence that Canada is an under-performer on productivity, a desire to improve our productivity performance should be front and centre when establishing tax reform priorities. Using productivity improvement as a guide should help determine the relative weight given to reform of business taxes versus personal taxes and to broadly based reforms versus targeted intervention. It should be further emphasized that all taxes dampen economic activity, but some taxes have a more negative impact than others. For example, cuts to corporate or personal income taxes boost gross domestic product many times more than cuts to consumption taxes such as the federal goods and services tax. Federal and provincial governments should take the efficiency of different tax instruments into account as they seek to promote economic and productivity growth. 6. Maximize tax harmonization across three levels of government to make tax application and administration efficient. A patchwork quilt of tax regimes and rates spreads out across the country. For reasons of efficiency (in terms of tax administration) and, more importantly, to support a strong and competitive national business environment, tax harmonization should be pursued aggressively. 7. Use the tax system to price externalities. The ever-expanding climate change debate has raised public awareness of production of greenhouse gases in general (and CO2—or carbon dioxide—in particular) as a by-product of our everyday life. Production of CO2 and other greenhouse gases is what economists call a “negative externality”—something that is a negative by-product of our economy but which the market-pricing system has so far been unable to capture. The tax system can address this form of market failure by attaching a price to carbon through the implementation of a specific tax on carbon emissions. Similar taxes could be applied to other negative externalities—such as waste water or soil depletion—to ensure that the prices of products in the marketplace reflect the full costs of their production. 8. Consider the distributional impacts of tax reform. Tax reform can have significant impacts on the distribution of after-tax income, whether it is between rich and not-sorich households, or among different types of households (i.e., those with or without children). These differences should be taken into account when considering major tax reforms. Tax reforms that generate significant economic gains would allow some of these gains to be used to compensate specific parts of society through such measures as targeted tax credits or income transfers. The Conference Board of Canada has a unique ability to bring together the senior leaders of Canada’s top organizations to discuss issues, share and compare best practices, and learn from each other. Our main services are: Executive Networks: Exchange Ideas and Make New Contacts on Strategic Issues Conferences, Seminars and Workshops: Learn from Best-Practice Organizations and Industry Experts Custom-Ordered Research: Tap Our Research Expertise to Address Your Specific Issues The Niagara Institute: Develop Leaders of the Future with Interactive and Engaging Leadership Development Programs Customized Solutions: Help Your Organization Meet Challenges and Sustain Performance e-Data: Stay on Top of Major Economic Trends e-Library: Access In-Depth Insights, When You Need Them Most The Directors College: Canada’s only university accredited corporate director development program For more information, contact our Corporate Account Executive Team at 1-866-711-2262 or go to www.conferenceboard.ca. About CanCompete: Competitiveness for Sustainable Prosperity CanCompete is a three-year program of research and dialogue designed to help leading decision makers advance Canada on a path of national competitiveness. The program will help build a National Competitiveness Action Plan to give the public and private sectors a common road map for collaborating to achieve their competitiveness goals. CanCompete builds on five of the seven strategies presented in the Conference Board’s report, Mission Possible: Sustainable Prosperity for Canada. The Board has created five new research centres, each focusing on turning a particular strategy into concrete outcomes. 1. Centre on Productivity—Productivity Strategy 2. Centre on Regulation—Single Canadian Market Strategy 3. Centre on the Future Workforce—Rethink the Workforce Strategy 4. Centre on Infrastructure—Successful Cities Strategy 5. International Trade and Investment Centre—Trade and Investment Strategy Launched in October 2007, CanCompete actively engages private and public sector leaders in setting national policy direction. Some 30 companies and organizations have invested in the projects, providing invaluable financial, leadership, and knowledge support. For more information about CanCompete, please visit the Conference Board website at www.conferenceboard.ca. Use Green Taxes and Market Instruments to Reduce Greenhouse Gas Emissions by Glen Hodgson, Gilles Rhéaume, and Len Coad About The Conference Board of Canada We are: Publication 08-118 E-copy: Complimentary • The foremost, independent, not-for-profit applied research organization in Canada. • Objective and non-partisan. We do not lobby for specific interests. • Funded exclusively through the fees we charge for services to the private and public sectors. • Experts in running conferences but also at conducting, publishing, and disseminating research; helping people network; developing individual leadership skills; and building organizational capacity. • Specialists in economic trends, as well as organizational performance and public policy issues. • Not a government department or agency, although we are often hired to provide services for all levels of government. • Independent from, but affiliated with, The Conference Board, Inc. of New York, which serves nearly 2,000 companies in 60 nations and has offices in Brussels and Hong Kong. 255 Smyth Road, Ottawa ON K1H 8M7 Canada Tel. 613-526-3280 • Fax 613-526-4857 • Inquiries 1-866-711-2262 The Conference Board, Inc. 845 Third Avenue, New York NY 10022-6679 USA Tel. 212-759-0900 • Fax 212-980-7014 • www.conference-board.org The Conference Board Europe Chaussée de La Hulpe 130, Box 11, B-1000 Brussels, Belgium Tel. +32 2 675 54 05 • Fax +32 2 675 03 95 The Conference Board Asia–Pacific 2802 Admiralty Centre, Tower 1, 18 Harcourt Road, Admiralty Hong Kong SAR Tel. +852 2511 1630 • Fax +852 2869 1403 ©2008 The Conference Board of Canada* Printed in Canada • All rights reserved ISSN 1205-1675 • ISBN 978-0-88763-820-6 Agreement No. 40063028 *Incorporated as AERIC Inc. For more information, please contact us at the numbers listed above or e-mail [email protected]. This publication is available on the Internet at www.e-library.ca. Forecasts and research often involve numerous assumptions and data sources, and are subject to inherent risks and uncertainties. This information is not intended as specific investment, accounting, legal, or tax advice. www.conferenceboard.ca