* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Commentary of Adaptation Cost-Curves
ExxonMobil climate change controversy wikipedia , lookup
General circulation model wikipedia , lookup
Climate change denial wikipedia , lookup
Climate sensitivity wikipedia , lookup
Economics of climate change mitigation wikipedia , lookup
Politics of global warming wikipedia , lookup
Effects of global warming on human health wikipedia , lookup
Climatic Research Unit documents wikipedia , lookup
Climate resilience wikipedia , lookup
Attribution of recent climate change wikipedia , lookup
Soon and Baliunas controversy wikipedia , lookup
Climate governance wikipedia , lookup
Climate engineering wikipedia , lookup
Paris Agreement wikipedia , lookup
Solar radiation management wikipedia , lookup
Citizens' Climate Lobby wikipedia , lookup
German Climate Action Plan 2050 wikipedia , lookup
Climate change in the United States wikipedia , lookup
Scientific opinion on climate change wikipedia , lookup
Climate change in Tuvalu wikipedia , lookup
Climate change and agriculture wikipedia , lookup
Media coverage of global warming wikipedia , lookup
Public opinion on global warming wikipedia , lookup
Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme wikipedia , lookup
Years of Living Dangerously wikipedia , lookup
Economics of global warming wikipedia , lookup
Effects of global warming on humans wikipedia , lookup
Climate change, industry and society wikipedia , lookup
Surveys of scientists' views on climate change wikipedia , lookup
IPCC Fourth Assessment Report wikipedia , lookup
Commentary of Adaptation Cost-Curves: With reference to the paper “Research to identify potential low-regrets adaptation options to climate change in the residential buildings sector” (Davis Langdon 2011): background paper to the 2nd report of the UK Climate Change Committee’s Adaptation Sub-Committee Nicola Ranger Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment 11th July 2011 Summary This commentary aims to appraise the usefulness of the adaptation cost-curve methodology for decision making, with specific reference to its application in the paper “Research to identify potential low-regrets adaptation options to climate change in the residential buildings sector” by Davis Langdon (2011), which is one input to Chapter 5 of the 2nd report of the Climate Change Committee’s Adaptation Sub-Committee (ASC). Further work will extend this appraisal to other adaptation cost-curves available in the literature. The comments provided below focus on the relevance of these methodologies and findings for adaptation planning and decision making by householders and government today and how the work could be extended to increase its utility for these purposes. I conclude that the cost-curve methodology provides a useful approach to presenting information on the cost-benefit of different adaptation options and their effectiveness and the paper presents some useful findings; however there are several constraints on the application of these findings to decision making. To summarise, the most significant issues in terms of the application of this research are the lack of generality of the findings and the non-independence of measures within the cost-curves; these issues are most acute for the flood case, but may not be a significant problem for the water case. It is also important to note that the cost-curves presented provide only one input to this decision making; they contain only a small set of the information needed by a decision maker. The lack of consideration of climate change in the paper is a significant missed opportunity. While it should not affect the specific conclusions outlined in Chapter 5 of the ASC’s 2nd report, it has two important consequences: • For new build properties, it could lead missed opportunities to identify and build-in appropriate adaptation to cope with climate change cheaply and easily today; specifically, those measures that are not cost-beneficial in the current climate, but become so when climate change is considered. Identifying such measures is particularly important for buildings, which have a long lifetime and high sunk costs; not considering climate change in decisions today risks locking-in maladaptation and consequently, unnecessary additional costs and risks to homeowners in the future. • The method only looks at adaptation options implemented today and provides no information about the timing and circumstances under which measures should be implemented in the future with climate change. Adaptation is a continuous process and this should be reflected in adaptation planning today. Treating adaptation as a ‘one-off’ could also lead to maladaptation. This was, for example, demonstrated in the Thames Estuary 2100 project. Overview of Davis Langdon (2011) The paper applies the ‘cost-curve’ methodology to identify ‘low-regrets’ adaptation options within the residential buildings sector associated with three types of hazards: flood, water stress and overheating. ‘Low-regrets’ measures are defined in the paper as having a cost-benefit ratio of less than one today (i.e. a partial definition1). The paper is not a standalone piece of work and should be read alongside Chapter 5 of the ASC’s 2nd report, which outlines the objectives of the work and provides an analysis of its findings and implications for policy. I understand the objectives of the analysis to be: 1. to investigate the utility of the cost-curve methodology for adaptation planning 2. to inform government policy on adaptation planning related to low-regrets options in the building sector. The range of adaptation options considered is limited to those that can be implemented within the home and (largely) to those applicable to existing buildings as well as new buildings. Cost-curves show the cost-benefit ratio of measures versus their total economic benefit (in terms of a defined metric) and are presented for both a societal perspective and the householder perspective. Cost curves differentiate between applications to new builds and existing buildings (during repair or retrofit). Each hazard is studied for a specific region (as results are location-specific). Findings are aggregated over the regions and time (to 2020 and 2050). No representation of climate change is included in the cost-curves presented in the paper. General usefulness of the cost-curve methodology The cost-curve method provides a useful approach to presenting information on the economic cost-benefit of different adaptation options and their effectiveness (i.e. the reduction in economic losses). Clearly, this information is only one input to an adaptation decision and further information will be required. In addition, typically, as in this study, the definition of economic costs and benefits is limited to direct monetary costs and benefits, and no attempt is made to quantify nonmonetary2 or indirect3 costs and benefits. This may lead a decision maker to undervalue the impacts of an adaptation measure. Similarly, cost-curves provide a representation of the ‘technical potential’ of adaptation measures; this may be an overestimate of their benefits as it takes no account of behavioural issues (e.g. improper usage or inadequate maintenance over time) and risks of failure. Lack of generality of cost-curves A deficiency of the method (as applied) for informing national-level decision making is that the cost-curves are dependent on the scenario (i.e. the climate change scenario, but also scenarios, such as land-use changes over time), the location (including building types in this case), and assumptions about societal adaptation. This means that it can not be assumed that the findings from the cost curves are generally applicable and therefore, limits their usefulness for decision making. 1 In an adaptation context, the definition of ‘low-regrets’ requires that measures are robust under plausible climate change scenarios. In some cases, the definition to broadened further, for example, having minimal trade-offs with other objectives or strong co-benefits. None of these decision factors are considered in this paper. 2 For example, the benefits of increased comfort levels in the home in the overheating case. 3 Indirect costs and benefits includes, for example, a valuation of the trade-offs and cobenefits. This problem will be particularly acute for the flood cost-curves. In this case, the cost-benefit and effectiveness will be highly sensitive to location (i.e. the hazard level in the region of the property), the attributes of the specific building, and importantly, the other adaptation measures already in place both within the home and at a community level. For example, if the property is in a town that is protected by a flood wall, the economic benefits of household measures will decline significantly. For this reason, I conclude that the findings are more relevant to rural properties. For the flood case, the cost-curves could be made less location-specific (and therefore, more useful to planning) by showing the findings for different levels of inundation water depth within the home, rather than AEPs. The findings for the water case should be more generally applicable for national/regional policymaking (though for householders, there will be some differences in the economics of measures depending on individual water use). The findings for overheating will be location specific, though less so than for flood; however, I would expect differences between urban and rural locations. Independence/non-independence of measures within the cost-curve It is not clear from the cost-curves whether measures are substitutes or complements –i.e. should they be applied together or should one be selected? The way that costcurves are constructed (i.e. with measures sitting along the x-axis in order of increasing cost-benefit ratio) suggests that they can be combined to increase overall effectiveness up to the point that the cost-benefit ratio equals 1), but in some cases this is not correct, for both practical and economic reasons. In terms of the economic issues here, in the calculations, different measures are treated as independent (i.e. they are treated as if they were substitutes), when in reality this may not be the case. For example, household resistance and resilience measures for flood are normally complementary – the homeowner will usually employ a set of measures. However, this is not reflected in the calculations and this leads to an overestimate of the economic benefits of the measures. For example, if the household flood resistance measures are put in place, this will decrease the economic benefits of the resilience measures. The problem of non-independence will be most acute for the flood case. It should not be a problem for the water case, as in this case most measures act independently (using one measure will not effect the economic benefits of other measures). It could have some effect in the overheating case, but this should be quite small (some further modelling work here could be beneficial). Lack of representation of climate change and its implications The representation of climate change in the paper is disappointingly poor. In adaptation, the term ‘low-regrets’ usually refers to a measure that is cost-beneficial under most plausible future climate change scenarios. However, no attempt is made to quantify how measures will perform under a range of plausible climate change scenarios. Indeed, none of the results shown in the paper include any climate change. Considering climate change is particularly important for the buildings sector because buildings are long-lived (in some cases, lasting for more than 100 years) and so are potentially vulnerable to a changing climate. However, I agree with the conclusion of Chapter 5 of the ASC’s report that for the specific case explored, those measures that are shown to be cost-beneficial today will likely remain so if climate change were included. This is simply because most of the measures shown to be cost-beneficial today have: (a) a short-lifetime of less than about 15 years and/or (b) very low or zero costs. But, not including climate change in an assessment of adaptation for new build properties could be a significant oversight as it could lead to future underadaptation and consequently, unnecessary additional costs and risks to homeowners in the future. For those measures that do have longer lifetimes and higher costs (e.g. structural measures), incorporating climate change could in some cases make them cost-beneficial. This information is particularly important to identify for new build properties, where it is significantly cheaper and easier to build-in adaptation at the development stage rather than retrofit later on and therefore there may be justification for ‘over-adapting’ the building today for current climate such that it can cope with future climate. The paper does not consider this. A further disadvantage of this approach is that it only looks at adaptation options implemented today and provides no information about the timing and circumstances under which measures should be implemented in the future – this is a particularly important question for planning retrofits to existing properties, which may take several years to implement. Adaptation is not a one-off – it is a continuous process – and several previous academic and policy papers have demonstrated the importance of reflecting this in adaptation planning today. For example, the Thames Estuary 2100 (TE2100) project considers both measures that need to be implemented today and explores the timing of adaptation decisions over the coming decades. As a result, TE2100 provided information on potential future investment needs and made recommendations on appropriate strategies to review adaptation options over time to ensure opportunities are not missed; this approach would be useful in this case. Range of measures included The study (largely) includes only ‘structural’ or ‘physical’ adaptation measures. It ignores behavioural measures and other ‘non-structural’ measures such as insurance. To make an informed choice, it is important to have information on all the available adaptation options. In addition, the adaptation measures considered are relatively small-scale. In locations at high current or future risk, more significant adaptations might become low-regrets (e.g. structural changes to buildings). Additional issues for informing decision making The paper presents cost-curves from two perspectives, the homeowner perspective and the societal perspective. Each of the comments above will be relevant in both of these cases. In addition: Societal perspective: informing national-level decision making This perspective aims to inform adaptation policy, including for example, how public investments should be prioritised and how policies should be designed to incentivise appropriate individual (autonomous) adaptation. The cost-curves presented provide one input to this decision making, but they contain only a small set of the information needed by a decision maker interested in managing risk at the societal level. In particular, she will most likely need to consider a broader range of adaptation options than just those applicable to residential building. For example, to identify the appropriate measures to manage flood risk, she will need to compare the costeffectiveness of measures in the buildings sector to other measures, such as flood defences, risk transfer initiatives, or land-use planning. For flood risk management, community flood protection measures (such as dykes) can often be more cost- beneficial and effective than household measures in urban areas (whereas household measures tend to be most desirable in areas of low population and asset concentration). Similarly, for the water sector, efficiency at the household level will need to be compared with other demand reduction measures (e.g. reducing leakage) and supply-based measures. Considering this broader range of measures outside of the building sector is particularly important in adaptation to climate change, where it is unlikely that adaptations in the building sector alone could meet societal adaptation needs. An exception to this could be overheating, where residential adaptations are likely to be the most significant contributor to long-term risk reduction. The ‘societal’ decision maker will also probably need to consider more factors than just the (direct) economic cost-benefit ratio and (direct) economic effectiveness of measures. Firstly, she may consider a broader range of decision criteria, such as the number of people at risk and the protection of strategically important assets (e.g. major economic centres, such as London, or critical infrastructure). She is also likely to need to consider the broader co-benefits and trade-offs of measures with other objectives, such as the co-benefits of passive cooling within the home for emissions reductions, and the trade-offs involved in land-planning policy. Importantly, there may be fixed budgets constraints. None of these additional factors are captured in the cost-curves methodology. Homeowner perspective The fact that cost-curves are location specific (and building specific) is a crucial disadvantage for homeowners and particularly for the flood case. The utility of costcurves for homeowners could be improved by generating cost-curves for different location types and circumstances. In addition, while the metrics used to convey the effectiveness of measures seem useful from a policymaking perspective (e.g. economic benefits), other metrics might be more useable from the householder perspective, for example, the payback period of the investment (for water and flood) or the reduction in number of days in which indoor temperatures reach uncomfortable levels (for overheating). The cost-curves also do not account for the risk aversion of different homeowners. The decision maker is assumed to be risk neutral and while this may be appropriate for public sector decision making, it is not for individual decision making. For homeowner decision making, a welfare-based decision framework that reflects individual risk aversion might be more appropriate. Future work: increasing the utility of the flood case For most of the comments made above, the interpretation of findings from the flood case proves most difficult. The findings could be quickly made easier to generalise by presenting different cost-curves for different levels of water inundation within the home, rather than AEPs. This is because AEPs are highly dependent on the specific circumstances of the property and its location. In addition, flood must be treated stochastically; to calculate the total economic benefits of a flood measure one must aggregate the benefits of all possible flood depths within the building weighted by their probability. This approach was not used in the report and so the findings may be incorrect (note that this may also be true for overheating). The aggregation of benefits could increase the estimated effectiveness of measures and lower their cost-benefit ratio. Leading on from this, to develop a cost-curve for a region or the UK, cost-curves for individual flood depths and building types should be combined with data on the frequencies of flooding at each location (i.e. a PDF of flood depths at each location, taking account of adaptation measures). Such data is available at a national level.