* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Equity for Rural America: From Wall Street to Main Street
Stock trader wikipedia , lookup
Special-purpose acquisition company wikipedia , lookup
Investment banking wikipedia , lookup
Startup company wikipedia , lookup
History of investment banking in the United States wikipedia , lookup
Socially responsible investing wikipedia , lookup
Environmental, social and corporate governance wikipedia , lookup
Private money investing wikipedia , lookup
Investment fund wikipedia , lookup
Venture capital financing wikipedia , lookup
Investment management wikipedia , lookup
Venture capital wikipedia , lookup
Corporate venture capital wikipedia , lookup
Leveraged buyout wikipedia , lookup
History of private equity and venture capital wikipedia , lookup
Private equity wikipedia , lookup
Private equity secondary market wikipedia , lookup
Private equity in the 2000s wikipedia , lookup
Equity Capital and Entrepreneurs Stephen Prowse ow do small- and medium-sized firms raise external equity capital? In this paper, I describe two markets that entrepreneurs of small- and medium-sized enterprises use in the United States to raise equity: the organized private equity market and the market for angel capital. Both markets are important sources of equity capital for small- and mediumsized firms. However, until recently, not much was known about how the organized private equity market operated, while the market for angel capital still operates in almost total obscurity. In this paper, I try to shed some light on how these markets operate, and discuss some of the major issues that surround these markets today. In doing so, I draw on ongoing and new research done by others and me into the operation of these markets. H SOURCES OF EQUITY FINANCE FOR SMALL- AND MEDIUM-SIZED FIRMS Issuing public equity is usually not feasible for small- and medium-sized firms because of their small size, lack of a track record, or inadequate growth prospects. Such firms must usually issue private equity to meet their financing needs. Two sources of private equity are the organized private equity market and the market for angel capital. Defining the organized private equity market The organized private equity market consists of professionally managed equity investments in the unregistered securities of private and public companies. Professional management is provided by specialized intermediaries and, to a limited extent, by institutional investors. Private equity managers acquire large ownership stakes and take an active role monitoring and advising portfolio companies. In many cases they exercise as much control as company insiders, or more. As of year-end 1995, the outstanding capital in the organized private equity market totaled $175 billion, with new commitments to the private equity market running around $30 billion. Of this total, about one-quarter goes to venture capital, and three-quarters to nonventure capital. The venture capital sector of the private equity market typically finances smaller firms—sometimes start-ups—with very high growth prospects. The nonventure sector of the market typically provides capital to larger, middle-market firms with slower growth prospects but a need to finance expansion or a change in ownership. Defining angel capital Angel capital refers to investments by wealthy individuals in the unregistered equity 12 securities of small, closely held companies. It is a much more informal market than the organized private equity market, and little is known about how this market operates. However, what we do know about it suggests that angel investors may play quite an important role in the financing of small, private businesses. By some estimates the angel capital market is several times larger than the venture sector of the organized private equity market, and angel capital in particular is regarded as a critical source of seed capital. I will discuss the operation of each of these markets in turn. OPERATION OF THE ORGANIZED PRIVATE EQUITY MARKET The organized private equity market (or private equity market) is an important source of funds for start-up firms, private middle-market firms, firms in financial distress, and public firms seeking buyout financing. Since 1980 it has been the fastest growing market for corporate finance, by an order of magnitude over other markets such as the public equity and bond markets and the market for private placement debt. Today, the private equity market is roughly one-quarter the size of both the commercial and industrial bank loan market and the commercial paper market in terms of outstandings. In recent years, private equity capital raised by partnerships has matched, and sometimes exceeded, funds raised through initial public offerings and gross issuance of public high-yield corporate bonds. Limited partnership Until the late 1970s, private equity investments were undertaken mainly by wealthy families, industrial corporations, and financial institutions investing directly in issuing firms. Stephen Prowse By contrast, most investment since 1980 has been undertaken by professional private equity managers on behalf of institutional investors. The vehicle for organizing this activity is the limited partnership, with institutional investors as limited partners and investment managers as general partners. Advantages of limited partnerships. The emergence of the limited partnership as the dominant form of intermediary is a result of the extreme information asymmetries and potential incentive problems that arise in the private equity market. The specific advantages of limited partnerships are rooted in the way in which they address these problems. The general partners specialize in finding, structuring, and managing equity investments in closely held private companies. Partnerships are among the largest and most active shareholders with significant means of both formal and informal control, and thus are able to direct companies to serve shareholders’ interests. At the same time, partnerships employ organizational and contractual mechanisms that align the interests of the general and limited partners. Need for limited partnerships. The development of limited partnerships arose from the need for greater institutional participation in private equity. Few investors had the skills necessary to invest directly in this asset class, and those that did found it difficult to use their skills efficiently. Partnership growth was also fostered by regulatory changes that permitted greater private equity investment by pension funds. The results of these changes are telling. From 1980 to 1995, the amount of capital under management by the private equity market increased from roughly $4.7 billion to over $175 billion. Limited partnerships went from managing less than 50 percent of private equity investments to managing more than 80 percent (Chart 1).1 Most of the remaining private equity Equity Capital Markets—The View from Wall Street 13 Chart 1 PRIVATE EQUITY CAPITAL OUTSTANDING, BY SOURCE OF FUNDS AND TYPE OF INVESTMENT, 1980 AND 1995 Billions of dollars Billions of dollars 200 200 Type of Investment Source of Funds 180 Limited partnership 160 160 Nonventure 143.2 140 180 132 140 120 120 100 100 80 80 Venture 60 Other 40 60 44.3 40 33.2 20 0 20 2 2.7 1980 3 1995 stock is held directly by investors, but even much of this direct investment activity is the result of knowledge that limited partners have gained investing in and alongside partnerships. The expansion of the private equity market has increased access to outside equity capital for both classic start-up companies and established private companies. Venture capital outstanding increased almost fifteenfold from 1980 to 1995, from about $3 billion to just under $45 billion (Chart 1). Nonventure private equity outstanding, meanwhile, grew from less than $2 billion to more than $130 billion. Thus, the growth of the private equity market has made it easier not only for start-up companies to acquire adequate financing through successive stages of growth, but also for middle-market private firms to acquire financing for expansion. 1.7 1980 0 1995 Components of the organized private equity market The organized private equity market has three major players and an assortment of minor players. Figure 1 illustrates how these players interact with each other. The major players are private equity issuers, intermediaries, and investors. Issuers. Issuers in the private equity market vary widely in size and in their motivation for raising capital as well as in other ways. Table 1 illustrates the various types of firms that issue private equity. They do share one common trait, however: because private equity is one of the most expensive forms of finance, issuers generally are firms that cannot raise financing from the debt or public equity markets. 14 Stephen Prowse Figure 1 ORGANIZED PRIVATE EQUITY MARKET INVESTORS INTERMEDIARIES Limited partnership Corporate pension funds Dollars Public pension funds Endowments ISSUERS Limited partnership interest New ventures Early stage Managed by independent partnership organizations Managed by affiliates of Dollars, monitoring consulting financial institutions Later stage Middle-market private companies Expansion Foundations - Capital expenditure - Acquisitions Bank holding companies Wealthy families and Other intermediaries Dollars individuals Insurance companies Equity claim on intermediary Small business investment companies Change in capital Private equity securities (SBICs) structure - Financial restructuring - Financial distress Change in ownership Publicly traded - Retirement of owner investment companies - Corporate divestitures Investment banks Nonfinancial corporations Other investors DIRECT INVESTMENTS (includes direct investments of both BHC-affiliated SMICs and venture capital subsidiaries of nonfinancial companies) Dollars Public companies Management or leveraged buyouts Financial distress Special situations Private equity securities Investment advisers Placement agents Placement agents to investors for partnerships for issuers Evaluate limited partnerships Locate limited partners Manage funds of funds Issuers of traditional venture capital are young firms, most often those developing innovative technologies that are projected to show very high growth rates in the future. They may be early-stage companies, those still in the research and development stage or the earliest stages of commercialization, or later stage companies, those that have several years of sales but are still trying to grow rapidly. Advise issuers Locate equity investors Since the mid-1980s, nonventure private equity investment has outpaced venture investment. Middle-market companies, roughly defined as companies with annual sales of $25 million to $500 million, have become increasingly attractive to private equity investors. Many of these companies are stable, profitable businesses in low-technology manufacturing, distribution, services, and retail industries. Equity Capital Markets—The View from Wall Street They use the private equity market to finance expansion—through new capital expenditures and acquisitions—and to finance changes in capital structure and in ownership. The latter is increasingly the result of private business owners reaching retirement age. Although not the focus of this paper, public companies also are issuers in the private equity market. Public companies that go private issue a combination of debt and private equity to finance their management or leveraged buyout. Indeed, between the mid- and late-1980s such transactions absorbed most new nonventure private equity capital. Public companies also issue private equity to help them through periods of financial distress and to avoid registration costs and public disclosures. Intermediaries. Intermediaries—mainly limited partnerships—manage an estimated 80 percent of private equity investments. Under the partnership arrangement, institutional investors are the limited partners, and a team of professional private equity managers serves as the general partners. In most cases the general partners are associated with a partnership management firm such as the venture capital firm Kleiner, Perkins, Caufield, and Byers or the buyout group Kohlberg, Kravis, and Roberts. Some of the management companies are affiliates of a financial institution, such as an insurance company, bank holding company, or investment bank. The affiliated companies are generally structured and managed no differently than independent partnership management companies. Limited partnerships typically have a ten-year life. During this period, investors forego virtually all control over the management of the partnership, creating potential conflicts between investors and the partnership managers. These conflicts are addressed by two types of inventive mechanisms that align the interests of the 15 general partners with those of the limited partners (Table 2). First, if partnership managers are to raise new partnerships in the future, they must establish favorable track records. Second, they receive a significant amount of their compensation in the form of shares of the partnership’s profits. Partnership managers must solve the incentive and information problems that exist when investing in small, private companies. They do this primarily by using a number of direct control mechanisms: in many cases they gain voting control, and they have substantial means of exercising nonvoting control, including seats on boards of directors, and providing needed capital only in well-defined stages (Table 2). In addition to monitoring the companies, partnership managers assist in matters ranging from designing corporate strategy to locating suppliers. Because being active in management requires a high level of expertise, many partnership managers specialize by investment type, by industry, or by geographic region. Investment companies not organized as limited partnerships—Small Business Investment Companies (SBIC), publicly traded investment companies, and other companies—today play only a marginal role as intermediaries in the private equity market. SBICs, established in 1958 as a means of encouraging investment in private equity, can leverage their private capital with loans from, or guaranteed by, the Small Business Administration. In the 1960s and 1970s they accounted for as much as one-third of private equity investment, but today they account for less than $1 billion of the $175 billion market. Their reduced role has resulted in part from their inability to make long-term equity investments when they themselves are financed with debt. Publicly traded investment companies also played a role in the past, but today fewer than a dozen such companies are active, and 16 Stephen Prowse Table 1 CHARACTERISTICS OF MAJOR ISSUERS IN THE PRIVATE EQUITY MARKET Middle-market Public and private firms private firms Early-stage Later-stage and corporate in financial Characteristic new ventures new ventures divestitures distress Public buyouts public firms Size Revenues between zero and $15 million Revenues between $15 million and $50 million Established with stable cash flows between $25 million and $500 million Any size Any size Any size Financial attributes High growth potential High growth potential Growth prospects vary widely May be overleveraged or have operating problems Underperforming Depend on reasons for seeking private equity To finance a required change in ownership or capital structure To effect a turnaround To finance a change in management or in management incentives Reason(s) for seeking private equity Major source(s) of private equity Extent of access to other financial markets To start operations To expand plant and operations To cash out early-stage investors Angels Early-stage venture partnerships For more mature firms with collateral, limited access to bank loans Later-stage venture partnerships Other High levels of free cash flow To expand by acquiring or purchasing new plant Later-stage venture partnerships To ensure confidentiality To issue a small offering For convenience Because industry is temporarily out of favor with public equity markets Turnaround partnerships Nonventure and mezzanine debt partnerships Nonventure partnerships Very limited access Generally, access to all public and private markets Generally, access to all public and private markets Nonventure partnerships Access to bank loans to finance working capital Access to bank loans For more mature, larger firms, access to private placement market Equity Capital Markets—The View from Wall Street 17 Table 2 MECHANISMS USED TO ALIGN THE INTERESTS OF PARTICIPANTS IN THE PRIVATE EQUITY MARKET (Most important mechanisms are in bold) Partnership - Portfolio Companies Limited Partners - General Partners Direct means of control Direct means of control Voting rights Partnership covenants Board seats Advisory boards Access to capital Performance incentives Performance incentives Managerial ownership Reputation Managerial compensation General partner compensation together they manage less than $300 million. The long-term nature of private equity investing appears not to be compatible with public investors’ shorter term investment horizons. Two other types of private equity organizations are SBICs owned by bank holding companies and venture capital subsidiaries of nonfinancial corporations. Both types were extremely important in the 1960s, and they still manage significant amounts of private equity. However, these organizations invest only their corporate parents’ capital. In this sense, neither is really an intermediary, but rather a conduit for direct investments. Investors. A variety of groups invest in the private equity market. Chart 2 provides information on the relative importance of the different private equity investors at year-end 1995. Public and corporate pension funds are the largest groups, together holding roughly 40 percent of capital outstanding and currently supplying close to 50 percent of all new funds raised by partnerships. Public pension funds are the fastest growing investor group and recently overtook private pension funds in terms of the amount of total private equity held. Pension funds are followed by endowments and foundations, bank holding companies, and wealthy families and individuals, each of which holds about 10 percent of total private equity. Insurance companies, investment banks, nonfinancial corporations, and foreign investors are the remaining major investor groups. Most institutional investors invest in private equity because they expect the risk-adjusted returns on private equity to be higher than those on other investments and because of the potential benefits of diversification. Bank holding companies, investment banks, and nonfinancial corporations may also choose to invest in the private equity market to take advantage of economies of scope between private equity investing and their other activities. 18 Stephen Prowse Chart 2 INVESTORS IN THE PRIVATE EQUITY MARKET, BY HOLDINGS OF OUTSTANDINGS AT YEAR-END 1995 (Billions of dollars) Investment banks $8.60 Other $16.00 Nonfinancial corporations $7.50 Public pension funds $39.50 Insurance companies $12.70 Commercial banks $10.93 Corporate pension funds $34.70 Individuals $10.31 Endowments and foundations $20.00 Operation of the market for angel capital Who are the angels? The market for angel capital—where individuals provide risk capital directly to small, private, often start-up firms—operates in almost total obscurity. Very little is known about the market’s size, scope, the type of firms that raise angel capital, and the types of individuals who provide it. In this section, I report information on the angel market gathered from two sources. The first is my field research that involved interviews with more than a dozen angel investors in the Dallas/Fort Worth area. The second is an empirical study of over 100 firms which attempts to document the importance of angel investors in their financing prior to going public (Fenn, Laing, and Prowse, 1998). An angel investor is a provider of risk capital to small, private firms. By risk capital, I mean equity capital (or near-equity capital such as loans or loan guarantees provided by investors that also have an equity position in the firm). The provider is a wealthy individual, not an intermediary such as an SBIC or a private equity limited partnership. Such individuals are not in the top management of the firm to which they provide capital nor are they employees, nor in the immediate family of a member of management or an employee. Angels are arm’s-length investors in the firm. Indeed, angels are often perceived as the second round of financing a start-up goes through, after the entrepreneur has Equity Capital Markets—The View from Wall Street 19 exhausted all his family and friends’ money, but before he approaches formal venture capital partnerships. Angels often (but not always) have entrepreneurial backgrounds and tend to invest in start-ups and other small, closely held companies. hard data from a recent empirical study George Fenn, Nellie Liang, and I are conducting. It is on the importance of angel investors and some characteristics of their investment patterns in a sample of high-tech firms that went public in the early 1990s. Size of the angel market Diversity of angels. Investors in the market for angel capital appear to be extremely diverse and heterogeneous. This is explained partly by angels’ diverse backgrounds. Some are financially sophisticated, some are not. Some have an entrepreneurial background from which they derived their wealth, while others obtained their wealth through inheritance or other means. It is also explained partly by their motivations for investing in the market. Most are probably investing for return, but some may have altruistic reasons. Some estimates of the size of the angel market suggest that it is many times the size of the formal venture capital market. For example, Freear, Sohl and Wetzel (1996) claim that perhaps between $10 and $20 billion is invested by angels each year into as many as 30,000 firms. However, an estimate from the 1993 National Survey of Small Business Finances (NSSBF) suggests that around 10,000 firms per year receive a total of about $3 billion in equity from angels (Fenn, Liang and Prowse, 1998). The NSSBF number may well be a conservative estimate of the size of the angel market since it samples primarily established small firms that may not be the major seekers of angel capital. There is clearly a great deal of uncertainty about the importance of the angel market in financing small firms. Compare the above numbers with the venture sector of the private equity market where commitments by limited partners totaled $6.6 billion in 1995. Interview observations of angels The following section presents a general description of angels activities gleaned from my interviews with them. Or course these descriptions much be taken with a grain of salt because, as yet, there is little data available with which to confirm what angels tell us in interviews. In addition, the heterogeneity of the angel market means that it is very hard to come up with general statements about how the angel market operates. However, I follow my interview observations on the angel market with some Active and passive angels. Angels also vary in the degree to which they are active investors in firms. By active angels, I mean those who actively monitor the firms they invest in, sit on the board, advise the firm on various matters, and sometimes help the firm overcome particular operating, marketing, or financial problems. Passive angels, on the other hand, provide only money and rarely monitor the firm closely. Passive angels rarely exist independently. They are usually part of an informal network of passive angels led by one or more active angels who find deals, perform the due diligence, informally syndicate the deal among their network of passive angels, and manage the investments. Passive angels often invest simply on the word of a trusted active angel. Active angels on the other hand are most often highly motivated ex-entrepreneurs who are perceived to have a skill at picking good people in whom to invest. These active angels rely heavily on their ability to pick good management teams and good ideas. 20 Active angels share some common characteristics. First, they are typically older ex-business owners who have considerable experience founding and managing companies—often start-ups but occasionally large firms also. Second, they have high incomes or net worth. There is, in fact, a formal definition of an accredited individual or angel in federal and state securities laws and regulations. In general, they are identified as individuals whose net worth is over $1 million and whose income exceeds $200,000 per year. Angels typically do not depend solely on their angel investing for their current income and so their participation in this activity often varies widely depending on their interest and the time they have to devote to it. Many angels do not make more than one investment per year, although there are a few full-time angels who will make as many as four or more per year. It is not uncommon for an active angel to have an informal network of passive angels who will coinvest with him on deals that he finds. Financial sophistication of angels. There is also a marked difference between angels in their degree of financial sophistication. The more sophisticated angels tend to insist on investment contracts that resemble the ones written in the private equity market, which contain lots of incentive and direct control mechanisms to overcome moral hazard problems and protect them in case of poor performance. Unsophisticated angels omit even the most basic protections. In general, even the most sophisticated angels rely less on governance mechanisms in the investment contract versus their gut feel about the potential success of the enterprise and the character of management. Business angels. Having often founded companies themselves, most angels prefer to focus on start-up or infant-stage firms, rather than already established businesses, although some more successful and wealthier angels will also Stephen Prowse participate along with other partnership or institutional investors in middle-market buyouts. Angels’ typical investments in start-up firms can be as low as around $50,000 but may be as high as $1 million. In these large deals, coinvesting with other angels or partnerships is common. Informal and agent deals. Business angels rely primarily for their information on potential deals on a very primitive and informal networking arrangement of friends, family, and other angels and business associates. On occasion they will also rely on formal agents or middlemen such as investment bankers and brokers. Many angel investments are arranged by informal matchmakers, such as lawyers or accountants who only occasionally put deals together and are not full-time agents. Deals brought to the angel by agents are less attractive than deals the angel locates himself or through his informal network. This is because agent-arranged deals involve additional fees for the agent, and also because they tend to get bid up in price by competing investors who are also being shown the deal by the agent. In addition, deals brought by an agent have less credibility in the eyes of the angel because the entrepreneur is not being vouched for by a known associate of the angel. Finally, sophisticated angels, which may require a lot of protections in the investment contract, often find that deals marketed by agents are targeted at those unsophisticated angels on a “take it or leave it” basis. They tend not to be able to insist upon additional changes or protections to the deal as marketed by the agent. On the other hand, some full-time angels do not mind working with agents because it relieves them of some of the burden of due diligence work. Implications of informal angel deals. Reliance on such an informal, inefficient network Equity Capital Markets—The View from Wall Street for gathering information about potential deals has a number of implications. First, most angels invest near to home, consistent with the reach of their networks. There is another reason angels invest close to home, which has to do with the cost of monitoring the firm. Most angels like to be no further than a quick plane trip from the firm in order to keep the time and money costs of regular monitoring visits down. Second, the sharing of information on deals with other active and passive angels generates a lot of coinvestment opportunities. Most angels share information on potential deals both to get coinvestors and with the expectation that the favor will be reciprocated in the future. Third, most angels complain of a shortage of opportunities in which to invest. In particular, they complain about the information channels currently available to find deals. Finding deals appears to be a very hit-or-miss proposition, with a large degree of serendipity in the number and quality of deals that an angel sees. Criteria for choosing angel deals. How do angels screen investment proposals that they are introduced to? Many angels specialize by sector depending on their expertise and background. The primary criterion that angels use to screen proposals is whether the entrepreneur is previously known and trusted by them or by an associate whom they trust. This is very different from limited partnerships that, while they also have trust in management as a key criterion, rarely insist upon previous personal knowledge of the entrepreneur. Of course, most angels also appear to require comprehensive business plans before considering investment, including a history of the firm and its principals, relevant credit reports, a summary statement of the purpose and goals of the enterprise, a clear description of the proposed financing, marketing plans, and a clear description of the technical aspects of the proposed venture. These appear to be given secondary status to a personal knowledge and trust of the principals. 21 Active angels almost always provide more than money. Angels provide assistance by helping companies arrange additional financing, hire top management, and recruit knowledgeable board members. Angels also may become involved in solving major operational problems, evaluating capital expenditures, and developing the company’s long-term strategy. They will often take a formal position as a paid part-time or full-time consultant to the firm. Most angels appear to have an investment horizon of about five years for their investments, though some have horizons that are considerably longer. The most usual method of exit for a successful firm is an IPO or the sale to another company. However, IPOs are rare and considered a home run, reflecting the likelihood that in five years the company will not be at the stage where a public offering is feasible. Data on angel investments in a sample of high-tech IPOs In Fenn, Liang, and Prowse (1998) we collected information from 107 initial public offerings in the period from 1991 to 1993 in two high-tech industries: computer software and medical equipment. For each company, we collected data on the identity of its shareholders just prior to the IPO. Questions included: how many were formal venture capitalists and angel investors; what their equity stakes were in the firm just prior to the IPO; and did they sit on the board of directors or have any other relationship with the firm. In addition we collected data on the firm’s size, location, age, R&D expenditures, and the primary security issued by the company (preferred, common, or debt). The biggest issue we faced was clearly how to identify angels. Our definition of an angel investor is any individual that acquires an equity stake primarily in consideration for capital 22 Stephen Prowse Chart 3 INCIDENCE OF ANGEL AND VENTURE CAPITAL INVESTORS Percent of sample Percent of sample 45 45 40 40 35 35 30 30 25 25 20 20 15 15 10 10 5 5 0 0 Angel Venture capital only Angel and venture capital Note: The sample includes 107 firms in the medical instruments and computer software industries that went public from 1991 to 1993. contributions to the company, excluding past and present employees of the company or their relatives. Our results, in brief, are as follows: 1) Virtually all of the firms in our sample raised external equity capital before going public. Only two were able to “bootstrap” their way to an IPO without raising any equity capital at all. Of the 105 that did raise equity capital, most raised it from either formal venture capitalists or angels. Only four firms did not raise equity from either venture capitalists or angels, but solely from corporate or institutional investors. Thus, 101 out of 107 firms in our sample raised external equity capital from angels or venture capitalists or both. Over 20 percent of the sample (23 firms) raised equity only from angels, while an additional one-third (36 firms) raised equity from angels and venture capitalists (Chart 3). Thus while venture capital is more frequent it appears that angels clearly play an important role in financing the firms in our sample. 2) Angels are much more likely to structure their investments with common stock than with Equity Capital Markets—The View from Wall Street 23 Chart 4 PRIMARY SECURITY ISSUED BY FIRMS (Common, convertible preferred, or debt) Percent Percent 100 100 Debt 90 90 Preferred 80 80 70 70 60 60 50 50 40 40 30 30 20 20 Common 10 10 0 0 Angel only preferred (Chart 4). Angels purchase common in 75 percent of the firms in which they invest, while venture capitalists purchase preferred in 75 percent of the firms in which they invest. 3) Angel-only backed firms are smaller, younger, and less R&D-intensive than firms financed exclusively by venture capitalists (Table 3). These empirical results support the notions that angels are important suppliers of capital to start-up firms, and that they invest at earlier stages than do venture capitalists, confirming some of the issues raised in the interviews. Whether these characteristics extend to startups in other high-tech industries, or, in particular, to start-ups in non-high-tech industries, is an issue we are currently investigating. Venture capital only ISSUES IN THE OPERATION OF THE TWO EQUITY MARKETS In this section I discuss two issues that have been raised with regard to the operation of the private equity and angel markets. First, is there a developing venture capital gap for start-up and seed firms in the private equity market? And second, how should we best address the search problems that firms and angels face in the angel capital market? Is there a venture capital gap for start-up firms? There has been much discussion within the private equity industry about an alleged shift in the flow of funds from start-up and early-stage 24 Stephen Prowse Table 3 FIRM CHARACTERISTICS The sample includes all firms in the computer software and medical instruments industries that went public from 1991 to 1993. Angel only Venture capital only $1.3 million $11.1 million Research and development/ assets 13.0% 27.3% Age at first angel or venture capital investment 1.1 years 1.8 years -.4% 1.3% Total assets Net income/assets investments to later-stage deals. One reason often given for such a shift has to do with the fixed costs of due diligence across all deal sizes and the increasing size of limited partnerships’ investment pools. Thus, the motivation is to want to write bigger checks, and move to laterstage deals. Another reason often given is the increasing presence of large institutional investors that are risk-averse and have short investment horizons. Data available on the venture capital market do not provide a clear answer as to whether this is in fact a serious problem. Venture capital partnerships have been getting bigger over time— the average size of a partnership in 1980 was $28 million, while it was about two and a half times bigger at almost $75 million in 1995. In addition, the average size of a single investment by a venture partnership has risen by about the same multiple (from $1.2 million in 1980 to $3.4 million in 1995). Thus there may have been increasing incentives for partnerships to move to larger deals as they got bigger over this period. However, much of this increase is simply due to inflation. In real terms, the average size of a partnership and the average size of a partnership’s investment have increased by only about 50 percent. In addition, according to the data, there is no clear associated shift in the flow of funds away from early-stage venture deals to later-stage venture deals (Table 4). The share of new venture investments going to early-stage deals was higher in 1995 than it was in 1983. It is true that the nonventure sector has expanded faster than the venture sector over the last 15 years (Table 4). This could in some sense be viewed as a shift in the flow of funds away from the industry’s venture activity. It is important to note that while the nonventure sector has grown the fastest, both nonventure and venture capital have grown extremely fast, especially relative to the growth of other corporate finance markets over the same period. And at least over the last six years, the share of new commitments going to venture versus nonventure capital has remained constant (Table 4). Problems in the market for angel capital Anecdotal evidence from studies on the angel capital market suggests that there is great dissatisfaction with the information channels angels Equity Capital Markets—The View from Wall Street 25 Table 4 TRENDS IN PRIVATE EQUITY Distribution of new venture investments by focus of investment (in percent) Early stage Later stage 35 30 30 38 65 70 70 62 1983 1985 1990 1995 Stock of capital in the organized private equity market ($ billions) Venture 1980 1995 3.0 44.3 Nonventure 1.7 172.6 New commitments to private equity partnerships ($ billions) Venture 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1.4 2.6 2.9 4.2 4.7 6.6 Nonventure 5.6 8.1 9.9 15.2 23.7 25.5 Source: Fenn, Liang, and Prowse (1997). must use to find deals, and that most angels would invest in more deals if they could find them. Putting these two impressions together suggests that a more efficient search process might result in more deals being done. Of course, it might be that the awkwardness of the search process is an illusion. The fact that angels have more capital than investment opportunities could mean that all the positive net present value deals are already being funded. However, the search on both sides is very time consuming and awkward. Matching services. One proposed solution to this problem has been the creation of a number of localized networks of matching services. These are all nonprofit organizations because the economics of providing networking services does not seem to be able to provide an economic return sufficient to provide for profit motivations to start such businesses. They collect information from interested seekers of funds (firms) and providers of funds (angels), and provide a computer matching service to interested parties. They also provide educational services to 26 Stephen Prowse angel investors on how to invest in firms. Recently these local networks have been integrated nationally via the Small Business Administration-sponsored ACE-Net. The effectiveness of such a system in solving the search problems that angels face may unfortunately be impeded by two characteristics of most angel investors. The first is that angels put a very high premium on previous knowledge of the entrepreneur, thus there is a question as to how much value an anonymous matching service will add. Angels also like to be very close geographically to the firms in which they invest. This might also mean that a national network is no more effective at solving the search problem than existing local networks. The most effective efforts to increase the efficiency of the angel market may well lie in the educational efforts that are being undertaken. Many angels are unsophisticated investors and there appears to be a lot of room for them to move up the learning curve in terms of the contracts they write with firms. CONCLUSION Evidence suggests that the organized private equity market and the market for angel capital are important sources of finance for small firms. It is clear that further research into these markets is warranted, as policymakers strive to create conditions whereby small- and mediumsized enterprises find it easier to raise equity capital. ENDNOTES 1 These and other figures in this section are estimates from Fenn, Liang, and Prowse (1997). REFERENCES Fenn, G., N. Liang, and S. Prowse. 1997. The Private Equity Market: An Overview, Financial Markets, Institutions and Instruments. Fenn, G., N. Liang, and S. Prowse. 1998. The Role of Angel Investors in Financing High-Tech Start-Ups, unpublished working paper. Freear, J., S. Sohl, and W. Wetzel. 1996. Creating New Capital Markets for Emerging Ventures, University of New Hampshire, unpublished manuscript. Durham, NH.