* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download old Topic 13: Co-Effects of CC and GHG Mitigation Policies
Climate engineering wikipedia , lookup
Climate-friendly gardening wikipedia , lookup
Climate change, industry and society wikipedia , lookup
German Climate Action Plan 2050 wikipedia , lookup
Solar radiation management wikipedia , lookup
Climate change adaptation wikipedia , lookup
Effects of global warming on human health wikipedia , lookup
Climate change feedback wikipedia , lookup
Effects of global warming on Australia wikipedia , lookup
Decarbonisation measures in proposed UK electricity market reform wikipedia , lookup
Ministry of Environment (South Korea) wikipedia , lookup
Effects of global warming on humans wikipedia , lookup
United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change wikipedia , lookup
Carbon governance in England wikipedia , lookup
Climate change mitigation wikipedia , lookup
Citizens' Climate Lobby wikipedia , lookup
Years of Living Dangerously wikipedia , lookup
Climate change and agriculture wikipedia , lookup
Climate change in Canada wikipedia , lookup
Politics of global warming wikipedia , lookup
Low-carbon economy wikipedia , lookup
Economics of global warming wikipedia , lookup
Mitigation of global warming in Australia wikipedia , lookup
Biosequestration wikipedia , lookup
Climate change and poverty wikipedia , lookup
Business action on climate change wikipedia , lookup
Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme wikipedia , lookup
Co-Effects of CC and GHG Mitigation Policies Bruce McCarl Distinguished and Regents Professor of Agricultural Economics Texas A&M University Presented at Climate Change Segment of Advanced Resources Class College Station, Feb 2011 Discussion Outline What are Co-Effects of CC and GHG mitigation Policies? Do Co-Effects Matter? Ways to Measure and Quantify Co-Effects (EPIC, CENTURY, NWPCAM, Econometric techniques) Case Studies of Co-Effects e.g. water quality, soil erosion, wildlife habitat, and biodiversity Government Intervention Policy Design for Co-Effects CO-Effects of CC and GHG Mitigation: Economic Perspective CC resulting from an increase in atmospheric concentrations of GHGEs is a public externality. “Externality” = Benefits or costs arise from an activity which is created by a person and that person does not take full account of the impacts on the others. Externality is a result of a market failure. A market does not efficiently allocate resources – either too much or too little. GHG mitigation policies can also cause externalities. Example of externalities related to CC policies e.g. a tax on carbon in the energy sector Positive Negative Human health improvement High energy prices Endangered species, etc. Unemployment, etc. AF Strategies for GHG Mitigation 4 CO-Effects of CC Policies: Economic Perspective Example of externalities and other effects related to GHG mitigation policies e.g. a tax on carbon in the agricultural and forestry sectors Positive Negative Water quality improvement High food prices Less erosions, etc. More pesticide use, etc. Many terminologies are used to describe CO-EFFECTS which refers to effects arising from GHG mitigation polices such as co- benefits/costs, income distributional shifts, ancillary benefits/costs, side-benefits, secondary benefits/costs, cleaner water, reduced runoff, increases across GHG accounts etc. Few studies address these issues especially negative co-effects e.g. use of more pesticides or irrigation, effects on other GHGs. Ag CO-Effects of CC Policies Framework Land Use Change CC Effects Social Effects Direct Effects Air Quality Job Creation Public Health Fuel Security Water Quality Life Styles Environ Effects Econ Effects CO-Effects Soil Quality Biodiversity Recreational Impacts Rural Econ Endangered Species Tech Progress ETC. ?? ?? ?? ?? Do Co-Effects Matter? Previous studies indicate that there are significant CO-Effects associated with GHGE mitigation, but most of the studies focus on positive CO-Effects (co-benefits). Figure 8.9: Summary of ancillary benefits estimates in 1996 US$/tC. Source: Climate Change 2001: Working Group III: Mitigation http://www.grida.no/climate/ipcc_tar/wg3/337.htm Do Co-Effects Matter? Inclusion of CO-Effects will affect cost of reductions. Carbon Tax ($/TCE) MC + Externality Benefits MC MC + Externality Costs Tax0 Q1 Q0 Q2 Emission Reduction (tons) Figure 2. Marginal Cost Curve for Carbon Emission Reductions Do Co-Effects Matter? Inclusion of CO-Effects will affect cost of abating of emissions and quantity. At market equilibrium, society would produce Q* at P*. If there are externality benefits, society produces too little energy (Q* < Q1) with too high price (P* > P1). If there are externality costs, society produces too much energy (Q* > Q2) with too little price (P* < P2). SMC = MCprivate + Externality Costs $ MCprivate SMB P2 P* P1 Q2 Q* Q1 Energy Figure 1. Social Marginal Benefit and Marginal Cost Curve for Energy Do Co-Effects Matter? Inclusion of CO-Effects will affect overall mitigation assessment. The social optimal output is at the quantity where SOCIAL BENEFITS = SOCIAL COSTS SOCIAL COSTS = PRIVATE COST - EXTERNALITY BENEFITS/COSTS Problem: how to get the accurate measures of these externalities? These externalities can over- or underestimate social welfare gain under different mitigation policies. Suppose that the social costs for 2 mitigation policies is such that SC1 > SC2 so society favors mitigation 2 But the order of the private costs is reversed PC2 > PC1 so private groups prefer mitigation 1 Numerical Example: SC1 =150 , but PC1 = 50 + Externality = 100 SC2 =100 , but PC2 = 100 + no Externality Co-effects of Emission Reductions by Energy Sector – Coal use releases sulfur dioxide, particulates, chemicals that contribute to air pollution including ozone – $10 per ton carbon tax could result in $3 health benefit from associated NOx reductions (Burtraw, 1999) – Approximate by using marginal costs as social willingness to pay, 15$ per ton of CO2 (EIA, 1995). 11 Measure and Quantify Co-Effects Quantitative Indicators Although some Co-Effects are not monetized, quantitative indicators are useful. Use biophysical simulation or other air/water quality simulation models such as EPIC, CENTURY, SWAT, NWPCAM EPIC Multi-environmental Indicators 100 Nitrogen Subsurface Flow Pollution (%/acre) 90 80 Nitrogen Percolation 70 60 Soil erosion 50 40 Phosphorus loss through sediment 0 50 100 150 200 Carbon price ($/tce) 250 300 Measure and Quantify Co-Effects Monetization Development of methods to quantify Co-Effects in terms of dollar values Econometric techniques such as non-market valuation, ricardian model, etc. Would you be willing to pay __$ on an annual basis for a management program designed to preserve endangered species XX? Note that: If a policy focuses on the environmental quality and in doing so this policy affects the CC, then now the CC effects are considered Co-Effects to this policy. For example, a policy focusing on cutting air pollution also benefits the climate through reduction of GHG emissions. Case Studies of Co-Effects: Water Quality Carbon Prices ASMGHG Reference: Pattanayak et al. 2002 Ag Census NRI State Annual Crop Acreage Regional Crop Mix input use Env loads Regionalizing Model County Crop Mix and percent loads NWPCAM Water Quality Index EPIC Runoff Sim. Run ASMGHG at GHG prices of $25, and $50/tonne CE Link NWPCAM to ASMGHG outputs Run NWPCAM at elevated loadings corresponding to 2 GHG prices ($25 and $50) Estimate WQI at two levels Compute Co- benefits elasticity %WQI %GHG 14 Case Studies of Co-Effects: Water Quality Overall Results: Economic Agricultural production declines (2-4%) and prices increase (3-8%) • CS decreases, PS increases, Export earnings fall (3 – 5%). GHG (not co-effects) • National GHG emissions decline (89 and 156 MMTCE/yr under $25 and $50 /ton CE, respectively). • Agriculture becomes a net sink at high GHG price. • Low C price => Low/no till cropland management • High C price => Biofuel offsets and afforestation Land use • Traditionally cropped lands decline(0.1 – 6%) • Irrigated lands decline(3 – 7 %) • Afforestation increases(5 – 12 million acres) 15 Co-Benefits: Water Quality Changes due to Changes in Cropland Management and Afforestation Preliminary Results, at $25/tC Change in WQI from Baseline -40 to -1 0 161 to 5 6 to 100 Source: Pattanayak et al. 2002 Case Studies of Co-Effects: Water Quality Overall Results: Loadings • N and P decline at low price • All loadings decline at high price • Erosion reductions most dramatic National WQ increased nearly 2% Future Extensions : Co-effects • Monetized • Multiple co-effects – biodiversity Omitted loadings in forestry and livestock 17 Case Studies of Co-Effects: Environmental benefits Empirical Procedure Reference: Plantinga and Wu 2003 Estimate Land Use Landik = fik (net return, population density, land quality ) fik = logistic function using SUR procedure Net return to forest=> + effect on the forest but – on the agriculture Net return to Ag => – effect on the forest but + on the agriculture Get Acres of Afforested Land Five values of subsidies are used to achieve conversion of 5%, 10%, 15%, 20%, and 25% of the baseline ag land. Average costs for afforestation rise from $200 (5% conversion) to $600 per acre (25% conversion). Determine C Seq.& Environ. Characteristics Using Birdsey forest carbon function to estimate additional C seq. through afforestation. Using the Natural Resource Inventory (NRI) and the Soil Interpretation Record System (SOILS5) to predict locations, agricultural land conversion, and environmental characteristics (e.g. soil type, permeability). Estimate Environ. Benefits Using estimation from previous studies to quantify environmental benefits. Under 25% conversion scenario => soil erosion benefits = 32-42% of cost of Cseq. program => wildlife habitat benefits = 25% of cost of Cseq. program => non-consumptive use benefits =25% of cost of Cseq. program Case Studies of Co-Effects: Environmental benefits Remarks: (1). Co-Benefits appear to be substantial. Soil erosion + Wildlife habitat (Use Value) +Non-Use Value Cseq Cost $42 M + $30 M + $31 M $101-132M (under 25% conversion scenario) (2). The number of potential co-benefits and co-costs are not included (e.g. water quality improvement, negative effects on wildlife habitat). (3). Unrealistic fixed prices assumption on timber and agricultural products Case Studies of Co-Effects: Biodiversity Category Maine South Carolina Wisconsin 3.2 Percent Change 2.5 21.8 Farmland Birds -10.8 -12.2 -11.7 Forest & Farmland Birds -2.0 -2.3 -1.1 Forest Birds Reference: Matthews, O’Connor, and Plantinga 2002 Study of land use changes impacts on biodiversity in South Carolina, Maine, and Southern Wisconsin Two types of land use => agricultural and Forestry lands Two types of birds farmland and forest birds (651 species) Using an econometric model to estimate land use changes due to afforestation subsidies Achieving a 10% reduction in agricultural land by giving afforestation subsidies as an incentive Using an estimated land use change to estimate bird abundance => Negative the net Co-benefits (CB) ( PDC PAIC MTC φ *GC CB) Social cost per ton QGHGO*(1 DISC ) Some co-effects are beneficial and can help offset the costs of producing practices from a social perspective – eg: Improving water quality from low tillage – eg.: Enhancing producer incomes from conversion of cropland to grasslands The co-benefits likely to be partially offset by co-costs – Expanded emissions in the energy sector vs. the offsets gained from CS Co-effect are relevant in all sectors of the economy accounting needs to be evenhanded Reference: McCarl.B.A , Tanveer A. B , Man,K. Kim, Cost of Carbon 21 Examples about potential ancillary benefits or costs Particle pollution fossil fuel use Recreational sites reforestation programs Technological efficiency new technologies and unit costs fall Welfare carbon taxation Road-use related mortality public transport Congestion public transport Employment GHG projects with excess supply of labor Higher electricity prices reductions in electricity reduce educational opportunities for children Reduced electrification rates increases in household air pollution Costs associated with ghg projects decreased economic activity decline in employment 22 Co-effects from Agriculture and Forestry Sequestration Watson 2000: co-benefits – soil productivity could be improved through increased capacity to retain water and nutrients – long-lived valuable products (wood) are produced – marginal lands could be improved and riparian ecosystems restored – Erosion reduction Antle 2000 – Reduced erosion, improved land quality, water quality, recreation sites, bio-diversity, farmer income support . 23 AM: Assessed in monetary terms AP: Assessed in physical terms, possibly partly in monetary terms. NA: Not assessed, they may be important. NE: No effect of significance is anticipated. 1. SO2 and NOx include acid deposition impacts. 2. Effects of PM10, NOx and SO2 on amenity arise with respect to visibility. In previous studies these have not been found to be significance in Europe, although they are important in the US. 3. Routine operations generate externalities through mining accidents, transport accidents, power generation accidents, construction and dismantling accidents and occupation health impacts. All these involve mortality and morbidity effects. 4. Water pollution effects include impacts of mining (including solid wastes) on ground and surface water, power plant emissions to water bodies, acid deposition and its impacts on lakes and rivers (partly quantified). 24 Co-effects consider or not? Consideration could speed up implementation – High cost of climate change mitigation might be largely offset by ancillary benefits Policy benefits of incorporating co-effects – Design policy on inclusive set of effects – Support GHG initiatives with broader environmental co-effects (“no regrets”) – Justify interventions in favor of terrestrial activities Safely ignored – If these effects are “small” relative to the other costs or the benefits of reducing GHGs – Simplifies an already complex debate. 25 Co-effects GHGE Mitigation Agricultural Involvement Co-effects Mitigation in Energy Sector Co-effects Co-effects Transportation Co-effects 26 Ag vs Non Ag share of a given amount of emissions control CN All Non-ag CA Q All ag 27 CA is cost of abatement by Ag, CN is cost of abatement by Non Ag, Ag vs Non Ag share of a given amount of emissions control CN CA C’A Ag cobenefits All Non-ag Q Q’ Ag co benefits only and ag share increases All ag 28 Ag vs Non Ag share of a given amount of emissions control CN C’N All Non-ag CA C’A Non Ag cobenefits Q’’ Q Ag cobenefits Q’ All ag Ag and non ag co benefits and share depends on relative size 29 Case Studies of Co-Effects: Environmental benefits Remarks: (1). Co-Benefits appear to be substantial. Soil erosion + Wildlife habitat (Use Value) +Non-Use Value Cseq Cost $42 M + $30 M + $31 M $101-132M (under 25% conversion scenario) (2). The number of potential co-benefits and co-costs are not included (e.g. water quality improvement, negative effects on wildlife habitat). (3). Unrealistic fixed prices assumption on timber and agricultural products 30 Challenge Complexity => multiple co-effects, double count, global vs. local effects, etc. CC Air Quality Human Health Mitigation Water Quality Quantifiability => methodologies Policy Design Distributional effects => Uncertainty CDM Reference Antle J.M., “Economic Feasibility of Using Carbon Sequestration Policies and Markets to Alleviate Poverty and Enhance Sustainability of the World’s Poorest Farmers”, Presened at the Expert Workshop on “Carbon Sequestration, Sustainable Agriculture and Poverty Alleviation, World Meteorological Organization, Geneva Switzerland, August 31, 2000 Antle, J.M. and S. Mooney. 2002. Designing Efficient Policies for Agricultural Soil Carbon Sequestration. Chapter in Agriculture Practices and Policies for Carbon Sequestration in Soil, edited by J. Kimble, CRC Press LLC, Boca Raton, FL, pp. 323-336 Burtraw, D., “Innovation Under the Tradable Sulfur Dioxide Emission Permits Program in the U.S Electricity Sector.” Resources for the Future Discussion Paper No. 00-38, 2000. Burtraw, D. Krupnick, A., Palmer K.,Pul, A., Toman M., Bloyd, C., “Ancillary Benefits of Reduced Air Pollution in the U.S. from Moderate Greenhouse Gas Mitigation Policies in the Electricity Sector”. Resources for the Future. Discussion paper No. 99-51. 1999. Elbakidze, L., and B.A. McCarl, "Sequestration Offsets versus Direct Emission Reductions: Consideration of Environmental Co-effects", Ecological Economics, Volume 60, 564-571, 2007. Energy Information Administration, Electricity Generation and Environmental Externalities: Case Studies, Office of coal nuclear and Alternative Fuels, Coal and Electric Analysis Branch, U.S. Department of Energy, Washington D.C. 20585, 1995. International Panel on Climate Change, “Climate Change 2001: The Scientific Basis”. IPCC Third Assessment Report. 2001. http://www.ipcc.ch/ Matthews, S., O’Connor, R., and A., J., Plantinga. Quantifying the Impacts on Biodiversity of Policies for Carbon Sequestration in Forests. Ecological Economics. 40(1): 71-87. 2002. Krupnick A., Dallas B. and Anil M. “The Ancillary Benefits And Costs Of Climate Change Mitigation: A Conceptual Framework” http://www.airimpacts.org/documents/local/M00007466.pdf 32 McCarl, B.A. and U.Schneider, (2000). “Agriculture's Role in a Greenhouse Gas Emission Mitigation World: An Economic Perspective”. Review of Agricultural Economics 22:134-159. Reference McCarl.B.A , Tanveer A. B , Man,K. Kim “How much would Carbon Cost a Buyer?” Working Paper 2004 McCarl, B. A., B. Murray, and J. Antle, “Agricultural Soil Carbon Sequestration: Economic Issues and Research Needs”. Working Paper #0875, Department of Agricultural Economic, Texas A&M University, College Station, TX Meyer, J. L.,M. J. Sale, P. J. Mulholland,and N. L. Poff, “Impacts of climate change on aquatic ecosystem functioning and health” Journal of the American Water Resources Association, 35(6), pp.1373-1386,1999. National Assessment Synthesis Team “Climate Change Impacts on the United States:The Potential Consequences of Climate Variability and Change” US Global Change Research Program,400 Virginia Avenue,SW Suite 750 Washington DC,20024 www.usgcrp.gov Pattanayak, S.K., B.A. McCarl, A.J. Sommer, B.C. Murray, T. Bondelid, D. Gillig, and B. de Angelo, "Water Quality Co-effects of Greenhouse Gas Mitigation in US Agriculture", Climatic Change, 71, 341-372, 2005. Plantinga, A. J., “Modeling the Impacts of Forest Carbon Sequestration on Biodiversity.” Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Oregon State University. Plantinga A. J., and J. Wu, Co-Benefits from Carbon Sequestration in Forests: Evaluating Reductions in Agricultural Externalities from and Afforestation Policy in Wisconsin. Land Economics, 79(1), 74-85, 2003 Stavins, R.N., "Transaction Costs and Tradable Permits", Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 29:133-148,1995. Watson, R.T., “report to the Sixth Conference of the Parties of the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change”, IPCC, http://www.ipcc.ch/press/speech.htm Nov.13, 2000 Watson, R.T. and the Core Writing Team (Eds.), IPCC Third Assessment Report: Climate Change 2001: Synthesis Report, IPCC, Geneva, Switzerland, September 2001. http://www.ipcc.ch/pub/un/syreng/spm.pdf Wietzman, M., L., “Prices vs. Quantities” Review of Economic Studies. 41 (4): 447-91, 1974 33