* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download The cultural economy
Development theory wikipedia , lookup
American anthropology wikipedia , lookup
Development economics wikipedia , lookup
Economic anthropology wikipedia , lookup
Cultural studies wikipedia , lookup
Steady-state economy wikipedia , lookup
Cultural imperialism wikipedia , lookup
Anthropology of development wikipedia , lookup
Popular culture studies wikipedia , lookup
Dual inheritance theory wikipedia , lookup
Ethnoscience wikipedia , lookup
Third culture kid wikipedia , lookup
Cultural anthropology wikipedia , lookup
Political economy in anthropology wikipedia , lookup
Cross-cultural differences in decision-making wikipedia , lookup
Cultural diplomacy wikipedia , lookup
Postdevelopment theory wikipedia , lookup
Cultural ecology wikipedia , lookup
Cultural Economy Professor Andy Pratt Professor of Culture, Media and Economy Director, Culture, Media and Creative Industries Email [email protected] Tel +44 (0)20 7848 1595 Culture, Media and Creative Industries King’s College London 5C Chesham Building, Strand Campus London, WC2R 2LS This pre-print paper is copyright of the author, but it is free to be used for research purposes as long as it is properly attributed. Permissions for multiple reproductions should be addressed to the author. This paper is intended to circulate work that readers might not otherwise be able to access. If your institution does subscribe to the journal, please access it via that link. Please cite as Pratt, A. C. (2009). Cultural economy. International Encylopedia of Human Geography, Volume 2. R. Kitchen and N. Thrift. Oxford, Elsevier. 2: 407-‐410. ISBN 0080449115 IMPORTANT: When referring to this paper, please check the page numbers in the journal published version and cite these. Pratt, A. C. (2009). Cultural economy. International Encylopedia of Human Geography, Volume 2. R. Kitchen and N. Thrift. Oxford, Elsevier. 2: 407-‐410. ISBN 0080449115 An entry (MS 146) for the International encyclopaedia of human geography (ed Kitchen and Thrift) October 2007 The cultural economy Dr Andy C Pratt, Reader in Urban Cultural Economy, Department of Geography and Environment/Centre for Urban Research, London School of Economics Houghton St London WC2A 2AE [email protected] Keywords Cultural Economy Cultural Industries Creative industries Economic sociology Economic geography Synopsis Discussion about the cultural economy can be differentiated by how the two terms are linked: as an adjective (cultural economy), or, as a compound noun (cultural economy). The notion of a cultural economy refers to the cultural dimensions of economic activity (the design or marketing of any product or service; or, simply, the social dimensions of the organisation of production). The term cultural economy is indicative of a particular subsection of economic activity this is concerned with cultural products and activities (such as music, film, and fine art such as music, film, and fine art) as opposed to say transportation or mining. The structure of this essay reflects this division whilst at the same time cross-cutting, and underpinning, these distinctions with three further ones: a notion of transition, and the concept of commodification, and the production-consumption dualism. The problem with the term ‘cultural’ is that it is used as a general modifier of terms (cultural industries, cultural communication), and, it could be argued that everything is ‘cultural’ in one way or another in the sense that it has a cultural dimension. So, we need to proceed with care in the context of such ambiguous usage. The cultural mode of economic action: The cultural economy Arguably the longest running debate about the cultural economy can be tracked more precisely to its status as a mode of analysis and to debates about the role of economic sociology as a sub-discipline and its position vis a vis economics. In the early variants of classical economics what we now consider the social, cultural and political were an internal part of economic discourse. After this time neo-classical analyses sought to concentrate on atomistic, uniquely economic action, and rational calculation. In effect, this created a ‘boundary dispute’ with respect to the social. In sociologist Talcott Parsons’ influential formulation of economic sociology this divide was concretised (and remained so for 40 years or more). In Parson’s view neo-classical economics was separated from the social: sociology was allocated the task of exploring the social setting for economic action, economics was left with the ‘pure economics’. Thus the social (and cultural) dimensions of the economy were allocated to context. For many years economic sociology, and geography (which drew on the same formulations), maintained this distinction. It is only relatively recently that writers have sought to challenge this dualism; in so doing they have opened up the field for a reconsideration of the explanation of economic action proper and thus challenged neo-classical economics on its own grounds. This is the key to understanding the current reengagement with the cultural economy. At least six lines of current debate about the cultural economy can be identified. First, researchers have sought to show how economics is one rhetoric amongst others; it is a mode of argumentation rather than revealed truth. Second, others have sought to demonstrate how truth claims are sustained in economics (and science) via a web of correspondences. Third, in a quasi- anthropological turn some have sought to examine the practices by which economic life are carried on. In other words to see how economic life is ‘done’. We can note the contrast with economists who argue about how economic life should be done. Fourth, we can point to anthropologists of material culture who have rendered the economic field into the familiar language of kinship. Fifth, alongside these has been a Deleuzian influenced debate about performativity and affect which has on one hand highlighted the role of the ‘passions’ in economic life (reference to another entry?), and on the other hand, sought to recast the economic field within a post-representational mode. Whilst these lines of theory are in essence economic sociology, they have also shaded into economic anthropology, and more generally come to encompass the cultural turn in the social sciences; hence cultural analyses of the economy. In so doing, the cultural turn has been strongly articulated as a methodological critique against quantitative and in favour of qualitative approaches. Sixth, and finally, we can identify a dimension of debate that has sought to explore the moral dimension of social and economic life for some writers this has been aligned to a critical take on the ‘cultural turn’ (reference to another entry?). Much of the theoretical debate about the ‘cultural turn’ in the discipline of Geography has been positioned against Marxist structuralism and production. Whilst theoretical debates about postmodernism and post-structuralism highlighted the play of images. In the practice of advertising, filmmaking and similar forms, it was used to frame the consumption experience. Although not a necessary consequence of such an approach, more often than not the object of interest has been consumption. There are a lack of new cultural studies, economic geographies or cultural geographies that apply their attention to production, let alone production and consumption. In economic geography the ‘cultural turn’ was in part figured as a reaction to the economically reductivist, or productivist, focus. Such a shift can be evidenced by the renewed interest in business organisation; some researchers have examined the unusual forms of economic organisation, namely ‘project working’ (reference to another entry?), that are commonly found in the cultural economy. In parallel, there has been a growth in management literatures concerning the cultures of management, and the particular innovative practices that constitute the creative/cultural industries. The instrumental focus of this knowledge seeks to achieve competitive advantages through innovation or product design. A common dualistic couplet deployed in the analysis of the cultural economy is that of culturalisation –economistation. As a dualism this is, on one hand, presented as economic activities being increasingly inflected with cultural topes and performance etc. rather than simple differentiation of value. This has been taken as an account for the deployment of culture to increase market segmentation and develop niche markets in a circumstance of oversupply, or market saturation. Some writers make a link with flexible specialisation and what they term a reflexive turn, that is indexed to growing demand from consumers for an ever differentiated product market (by design) and the organisational and productive means to satisfy it (flexible specialisation). Hence, it is argued, culturalisation is endemic in late capitalism. Economisation is commonly overlain with a moral sentiment. This is the classic formulation of Adorno writing in the late 1930s that rejected commodification as separating art from its aura. It is from this perspective that Adorno labelled (and defined) the culture industries in such negative terms. At one and the same time he sought to legislate what was culture, and to equate this with the market. Thus creating an unhelpful market/non market equation with art and commerce. Later work by political economists – common in Media and Communications studies- has carried on the Adorno’s moral baggage and added its own critique of power and control. Returning to the foundational provision of cultural goods, cultural policy, has been based upon market failure associated by inadequate price signals. Thus ‘creeping economisation’ is feared to morally ‘devalue’ culture; hence, the necessity of public intervention to counter these ‘incorrect’ market signals. Other binaries such as highlow culture, or public-private, for profit-not for profit have served to reinforce the notion that commercial/ mass culture/private/for profit are aesthetically inferior, despite the fact that the arguments (on one hand Adorno’s Aura, and on the other, market failure) are different. The Cultural Studies tradition has also argued that the high-low culture distinction is a false, but from a different discursive point of view. It is argued that there is a case, albeit not in such clear terms, to promote forms of culture that are non-, and not, commercial in order to promote diversity or representation. There is a long history of the analytical elision of high culture with higher social classes. Against this the value of the Cultural Studies tradition has been to recognise that culture is ‘classed’ (and ‘spaced’); that is, it is associated with, and the product of, particular class fractions. Thus, the insight that in favouring one particular aesthetic, one serves to support and legitimate that particular class (or regional) position and worldview. Increasingly culture is being used in instrumental ways to promote cities – for example, by creating distinctive modern art galleries. The argument here is that cultural differentiation is a way of marking place-rooted uniqueness (inherent or created). A line of argument in continental Europe has been the discussion of local food cultures, or food products that differentiate place and markets, and are supported by ‘regional branding’. A different, commercial, articulation is the increasing use of the ‘experience economy’ to promote a ‘feel good experience’ that helps to sell (otherwise similar) goods and places: from people dressing up and performing service, to street theatre and animateurs. Ethnographic research has highlighted the ‘hidden’ or emotional labour in such practices.. The latest version of this is the use of cities to attract what has been termed the ‘creative class’ because this group of workers whom work in hit-tech are attractive to new high tech companies whom are draw to labour pools. The key point that detracts from this work, for the purposes of this essay, is that it is focused on cultural consumption, not production; and, that culture is being deployed in an instrumental manner. The economy of cultural products and service: the cultural economy If we turn our attention to the part of the economy dealing with the production of cultural goods and services, the cultural economy, then we are immediately faced with two problems. First, what are its boundaries and definitions; and second, why has it grown? Empirically, these two problems are inter-linked as the taxonomies used for empirical data collection on economic activities are based upon historically determined conceptions of the economy which re themselves constructed around concepts of a normal (old) industrial economy and are intrinsically ill-prepared to identify ‘newness’. This is a problem associated not only with culture, but one with new technology based industries, and the service sector more generally. The first section of this essay has already differentiated the ‘cultural economy’ from the ‘cultural economy’, the latter would include the cultural dimensions of the whole economy. Adorno, when he coined the term ‘culture industry’, was seeking to point to those parts of the economy that were mass producing what he identified as inferior culture. A radical transposition of the notion was developed by French media and communications scholars in the 1980s; they sought to take this economy seriously, and to recognise that the culture industry was legitimate expression of culture and that its production was ‘plural’ and various: the cultural industries. This notion has been discussed in the UK (and much copied elsewhere), and underpins the policies of the 1980s for cultural regeneration pursued by UK metropolitan authorities. Conceptually two lines of emphasis have emerged from this root: first those that stress the textuality of the cultural industries and have a closer theoretical lineage to media and communications studies; and, those that stress the production system of cultural products and services that have a closer alliance with economic geography. Yet another term has recently become popular with policy makers: the creative industries, although there are critical differences in the interpretation of this term in practice usage overlaps. The cultural production system approach has been proven important for policy makers; it seeks to join both questions of the ‘breath’ of culture (which activities should be included: film, television, books computer games, theatre, music, etc.), and the ‘depth’ of cultural production (which activities are required to produce cultural outputs: manufacturing, distribution and consumption). Some analyses have concentrated on the former and operationalised this through counting numbers involved in artistic occupations, other analyses have explored cultural trade. The cultural production system approach argues that occupation – as used by Florida – offers partial analyses, as well as failing to capture the social reproduction of labour and knowledge in the cultural industries. Andy Pratt has developed a statistical framework that seeks to both define and operationalise both the breath and depth definitions which focus on ‘industry’ rather than ‘occupation’ as a fundamental unit of analysis; it is an approach that has been subsequently taken up by national governments and UNESCO in the production of so-called ‘mapping documents’. One outcome of such studies has been the fact that the creative/cultural industries/ economy constitute around 10% of some economies; indeed they are the 3rd major industry in London. Overlain on this political driven discourse has been a further confusion concerning the terms the creative industries, or the cultural industries; moreover the cultural economy and creative economy. Alongside enumerating and defining the cultural economy has been a debate concerning its spatiality. The cultural economy has a distinctive geography, one that is strongly, although not exclusively, articulated to urban areas in the developed world. A particular policy driven debate has concerned the agglomeration of cultural industries, so called ‘clusters’. Whilst policy makers have, as with other industries, sought to promote clusters; these is currently a poor understanding of the process of interaction at the local scale, empirical work on the cultural economy points to the role of knowledge, reputation and un-traded dependencies; moreover, that these are both localised and face-to face, and internationalised through in such nodes. This articulation of place and globalisation in the cultural economy is taken up in the debate about cultural industry commodity chains. Once we have accepted that the cultural economy does exist, and that it has grown very rapidly from a relatively insignificant economic and cultural low point, we must consider the question ‘why?’ This is an area of ongoing research. There are two lines of debate. First, without doubt, arguments concerning the growth of income, leisure time and the proportion of disposable income spent on culture account for one part of the ‘demand’. However, to this we need to add the creation of demand through the development of various means of persuasion (advertising) and the social transformation wrought by the extension of full time education, and increase participation in tertiary education. This latter process is linked to the creation of a cohort of young people with few responsibilities and a considerable amount of money and time. Added to this economic potential is the creation, from the mid-1950s onwards, of the social identity of ‘teenager’ that has been heavily inflected with advertising. Finally, the cultural explosion and liberal forms of artistic expression that developed in the 1960s. There is not space to explore these linkages, although it goes without saying that their inter-relationships need care in interpretation. A second theme of accounts of the emergence and growth of the cultural economy is via an extension of the work on the post-industrial/ modernisation of society (ref to post industrial society entry?). Researchers have proposed that there are the information, knowledge, and creative sectors of the economy constitute the ‘quinary sector’, succeeding the service sector as the ‘highest stage’ of growth. This line of argument has been criticised arguing that the linkage to production is empirically evident (and important) rather than absent, as implied in the post-industrial conceptualisation. Beyond these disputes about the long term development of economies and the role of the cultural economy in such a transformation are a number of important empirical changes that research is highlighting. First, as noted above, the realisation that the cultural economy is becoming an important aspect of some developed economies, in terms of turnover, employment, exports, as well as meaning. Second, as also noted above, is the fact that the cultural economy does seem to have some particular patterns and processes of location, practice and organisation. Third, that the nature of work and employment in these industries is distinctive. Whilst there has been much discussion about the rise of flexible work and self-employment, the concentration of freelancing, and casualisation of labour, plus the degree of serial contracting and project working, found in the cultural economy is distinctive. Researchers are increasingly exploring these processes, and their variance across both the creative economy, plus the extent to which they are found in the rest of the economy. Finally, work on production and commodity chains has highlighted the importance of the recursive linkages between production and consumption processes and places. If we add this increasing fragmentation of production processes with the other characteristic highlighted by traditional media and communications scholars, namely the degree of media (structural) concentration, and mix in the diverse and unique spatial clusters explored by geographers, it is clear that the cultural economy will keep researchers busy for many years to come. References ADORNO, T. and HORKHEIMER, M. (1977) The culture industry: enlightenment as mass deception, in CURRAN, J., M GUREVITCH, M. and WOOLLACOTT, J. (Eds) Mass communications and society, pp. 349-383. London: Arnold. AMIN, A. and THRIFT, N. (Eds) (2004) The Blackwell Cultural Economy Reader. Oxford: Blackwell. BATHELT, H., MALMBERG, A. and MASKELL, P. (2004) Clusters and Knowledge: Local Buzz, Global Pipelines and the Process of Knowledge Creation, Progress in Human Geography 28, pp. 31-56. BELL, D. (1973) The coming of post-industrial society. New York: Basic Books. BLAIR, H. and RAINNE, A. (2000) Flexible firms, Media Culture & Society 22, pp. 187-204. CALLON, M. (1998) The laws of the markets / edited by Michel Callon. Oxford ; Malden, MA: Blackwell Publishers/Sociological Review. COE, N. M. (2001) A hybrid agglomeration? The development of a satelliteMarshallian industrial district in Vancouver's film industry, Urban Studies 38, pp. 1753-1775. CRANG, P. (1994) It's showtime: on the workplace grographies of display in a restuarant in Southeast England, Environment & Planning D: Society and Space 12, pp. 675-704. CREWE, L. (1996) Material culture: Embedded firms, organizational networks and the local economic development of a fashion quarter, Regional Studies 30, pp. 257-272. CREWE, L. and BEAVERSTOCK, J. (1998) Fashioning the city: Cultures of consumption in contemporary urban spaces, Geoforum 29, pp. 287-308. DCMS (1998) Creative industries mapping document. Department of Culture, Media and Sport, UK, London. FERGUSON, M. and GOLDING, P. (1997) Cultural studies in question. London: SAGE. FLORIDA, R. L. (2002) The rise of the creative class : and how it's transforming work, leisure, community and everyday life. New York, NY: Basic Books. GARNHAM, N. (1987) Concepts of culture – public policy and the cultural industries, Cultural studies 1, pp. GARNHAM, N. (2005) From cultural to creative industries: An analysis of the implications of the 'creative industries' approach to arts and media policy making in the United Kingdom, International Journal of Cultural Policy 11, pp. 15-30. GLA_ECONOMICS (2004) Measuring creativity: 2004 update of the GLA's creative industry economic data. Greater London Authority, London. GRABHER, G. (2002) The project ecology of advertising: Tasks, talents and teams, Regional Studies 36, pp. 245-262. HANNIGAN, J. (1998) Fantasy City: pleasure and profit in the postmodern metropolis. London: Routledge. HESMONDHALGH, D. (2002) The cultural industries. London: SAGE. HESMONDHALGH, D. and PRATT, A. C. (2005) Cultural industries and cultural policy, International Journal of Cultural Policy 11, pp. 1-14. HOCHSCHILD, A. R. (1983) The managed heart : commercialization of human feeling. Berkeley: University of California Press. LAW, J. (1991) A Sociology of monsters : essays on power, technology and domination. London: Routledge. MARKUSEN, A. (2006) Urban development and the politics of a creative class: evidence from the study of artist, Environment and Planning A. (forthcoming), pp. MCCLOSKEY, D. N. (1986) The rhetoric of economics. Brighton: Wheatsheaf. MIEGE, B. (1987) The logics at work in the new cultural industries, Media Culture Society 9, pp. 273-289. MILLER, D. (1997) Capitalism: an ethnographic approach. Oxford: Berg. MOLOTCH, H. L. (1996) LA as design product: how art works in a regional economy, in SCOTT, A. J. and SOJA, E. (Eds) The city: Los Angeles and urban theory at the end of the twentieth century, pp. 225-275. Berkeley: Unversity of California Press. PALLADINO, G. (1996) Teenagers : an American history. New York: BasicBooks. PARSONS, T. (1961) The structure of social action : a study in social theory with special reference to a group of recent European writers. New York: Free Press of Glencoe. PINE II, J. P. and GILMORE, J. H. (1999) The Experience Economy: Work Is Theatre & Every Business a Stage. Harvard: Harvard Business School. PRATT, A. C. (1997a) The cultural industries production system: a case study of employment change in Britain, 1984-91, Environment and Planning A 29, pp. 1953-1974. PRATT, A. C. (1997b) Production values: from cultural industries to the governance of culture, Environment and Planning A 29, pp. 1911-1917. PRATT, A. C. (2000) New media, the new economy and new spaces, Geoforum 31, pp. 425-436. PRATT, A. C. (2004b) The cultural economy: a call for spatialized 'production of culture' perspectives, International Journal of Cultural Studies 7, pp. 117-128. PRATT, A. C. (2005) Cultural industries and public policy: An oxymoron?, International Journal of Cultural Policy 11, pp. 31-44. SAYER, A. (2003) Valuing Culture and Economy. Department of Sociology, Lancaster University, Lancaster, Lancaster. SCOTT, A. J. (2000) The cultural economy of cities : essays on the geography of image-producing industries. London: Sage. THRIFT, N. J. (2005) Knowing capitalism. London, UK ; Thousand Oaks,CA: Sage Publications. THROSBY, D. (2001) Economics and culture. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. WARHURST, C., NICKSON, D., WITZ, A. and CULLEN, A. M. (2000) Aesthetic labour in interactive service work: some case study evidence from the ‘new’ Glasgow, Service Industries Journal 20, pp. 1-18.