Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
The Plan for Day Two Practice and pitfalls (1) Natural experiments as interesting sources of instrumental variables (2) The consequences of “weak” instruments for causal inference (3) Some useful IV diagnostics (4) Walk through an empirical application Goal = provide concrete examples of instrumental variables methods Instrumental Variables and Natural Experiments What is a natural experiment? – “situations where the forces of nature or government policy have conspired to produce an environment somewhat akin to a randomized experiment” Angrist and Krueger (2001, p. 73) Natural experiments can provide a useful source of exogenous variation in problematic regressors – But they require detailed institutional knowledge Instrumental Variables and Natural Experiments Some natural experiments in economics – Existing policy differences, or changes that affect some jurisdictions (or groups) but not others – Minimum wage rate Excise taxes on consumer goods Unemployment insurance, workers’ compensation Unexpected “shocks” to the local economy Coal prices and the Middle East oil embargo (1973) Agricultural production and adverse weather events Instrumental Variables and Natural Experiments Some potential pitfalls – Not all policy differences/changes are exogenous – Generalizability of causal effect estimates – Political factors and past realizations of the response variable can affect existing policies or policy changes Results may not generalize beyond the units under study Heterogeneity in causal effects Results may be sensitive to the natural experiment chosen in a specific study (L.A.T.E.) Instrumental Variables and Natural Experiments Some natural experiments of criminological interest – – – Levitt (1996) = prison population → crime rate Levitt (1997) = police hiring → crime rate Apel et al. (2008) = youth employment → delinquency Some natural experiments not of criminological interest, but interesting nonetheless – Angrist and Evans (1998) = fertility → labor supply Levitt (1996), Q.J.E. Large decline in crime did not accompany the large increase in prison population (1971-1993) – But...increased prison use could mask what would have been a greater increase in crime – Prima fascia evidence of prison ineffectiveness Underlying determinants of crime probably worsened And...prison population probably responded to crime increase Levitt (1996), Q.J.E. Prison overcrowding legislation – – Population caps, prohibition of “double celling” In 12 states, the entire prison system came under court control AL, AK, AR, DE, FL, MS, NM, OK, RI, SC, TN, TX Relationship between legislation and prisons – – Prior to filing, prison growth outpaced national average by 2.3 percent After filing, prison growth was 5.1 percent slower Levitt (1996), Q.J.E. Prisons Under Court Control – Prison Population Growth – Crime Rate Growth Logic of the instrumental variable in this study – – Court rulings concerning prison capacity cannot be correlated with the unobserved determinants of crime rate changes Or...the only reason court rulings are related to crime is because they limit prison population growth Levitt (1996), Q.J.E. 2SLS model yields a “prison effect” on crime at least four times as high as the LS model – Violent crime rate – Property crime rate – bLS = –.099 (s.e. = .033) bIV = –.424 (s.e. = .201) bLS = –.071 (s.e. = .019) bIV = –.321 (s.e. = .138) A 10% increase in prison size produces a 4.2% decrease in violent crime and a 3.2% decrease in property crime Levitt (1996), Q.J.E. L.A.T.E. = effect of prison growth on crime among states under court order to slow growth Some relevant observations – Generalizability = predominately Southern states – Large prison populations, unusually fast prison growth T.E. heterogeneity = (slowed) prison growth due to court-ordered prison reductions may be differentially related to crime rates Other IV’s could lead to different causal effect estimates Levitt (1997), A.E.R. Breaking the simultaneity in the police-crime connection – – When more police are hired, crime should decline But...more police may be hired during crime waves Election cycles and police hiring – – Increases in size of police force disproportionately concentrated in election years Growth is 2.1% in mayoral election years, 2.0% in gubernatorial election years, and 0.0% in nonelection years Levitt (1997), A.E.R. However...can election cycles affect crime rates through other spending channels? – – Ex., education, welfare, unemployment benefits If so, all of these other indirect channels must be netted out Election Year + Growth in Police Manpower – Growth in Crime Rate Levitt (1997), A.E.R. Reduced-form coefficients First-stage coefficients Levitt (1997), A.E.R. Comparative estimates of the effect of police manpower on city crime rates – Violent crime rate – Levels: bLS = +.28 (s.e. = .05) Changes: bLS = –.27 (s.e. = .06) Changes: bIV = –1.39 (s.e. = .55) Property crime rate Levels: bLS = +.21 (s.e. = .05) Changes: bLS = –.23 (s.e. = .09) Changes: bIV = –.38 (s.e. = .83) Levitt (1997), A.E.R. Follow-up instrumental variables studies of the police-crime relationship in the U.S. – – – Levitt (2002) = Number of firefighters Klick and Tabarrok (2005) = Washington, DC, terrorism alert levels post-9/11 Evans and Owens (2007) = Grants from the federal Office of C.O.P.S. These findings basically replicated those from Levitt’s (1997) original study Apel et al. (2008), J.Q.C. What effect does working have on adolescent behavior? – – Prior research suggests the consequences of work are uniformly negative Focus on “work intensity” rather than work per se Youth Worker Protection Act Problem of non-random selection into youth labor market – Especially pronounced for high-intensity workers Apel et al. (2008), J.Q.C. Something interesting happens at age 16 – Youth work is no longer governed by the federal Fair Labor Standards Act (F.L.S.A.) Apel et al. (2008), J.Q.C. F.L.S.A. governs employment of all 15 year olds during the school year – – No work past 7:00 pm Maximum 3 hours/day and 18 hours/week But, F.L.S.A. expires for 16 year olds – – And...every state has its own law governing 16year-old employment Thus, youth age into less restrictive regimes that vary across jurisdictions Apel et al. (2008), J.Q.C. Change in work intensity at 15-16 transition among 15-year-old non-workers Magnitude of change is an increasing function of the number of hours allowed at age 16 Apel et al. (2008), J.Q.C. State Child Labor Law Hours per Week No Limit Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 0.32 (.05)*** 11.43 (1.6)*** Hours per Weekday 1.19 (.19)*** No Limit 9.37 (1.3)*** Work Curfew 2.19 (.27)*** No Limit 23.83 (2.7)*** R-square .400 .401 .409 ΔR-square with IV’s .014 .015 .023 Partial R-square for IV’s .023 .025 .037 F-test for IV’s 26.2 28.3 41.9 Approx. relative bias .000 .000 .000 Apel et al. (2008), J.Q.C. A 20-hour increase in the number of hours worked per week reduces the “variety” of delinquent behavior by 0.47 (–.023320) Angrist and Krueger (1991), J.L.E. Returns to education (Y = wages) – Years of schooling vary by quarter of birth – – Problem of omitted “ability bias” Compulsory schooling laws, age-at-entry rules Someone born in Q1 is a little older and will be able to drop out sooner than someone born in Q4 Q.O.B. can be treated as a useful source of exogeneity in schooling Angrist and Krueger (1991), J.L.E. People born in Q1 do obtain less schooling – – But pay close attention to the scale of the y-axis Mean difference between Q1 and Q4 is only 0.124, or 1.5 months So...need large N since R2X,Z will be very small – A&K had over 300k for the 1930-39 cohort Source: Angrist and Krueger (1991), Figure I Angrist and Krueger (1991), J.L.E. Final 2SLS model interacted QOB with year of birth (30), state of birth (150) – – OLS: b = .0628 (s.e. = .0003) 2SLS: b = .0811 (s.e. = .0109) Least squares estimate does not appear to be badly biased by omitted variables – But...replication effort identified some pitfalls in this analysis that are instructive Bound, Jaeger, and Baker (1995), J.A.S.A. Potential problems with QOB as an IV – Correlation between QOB and schooling is weak – QOB may not be completely exogenous Small Cov(X,Z) introduces finite-sample bias, which will be exacerbated with the inclusion of many IV’s Even small Cov(Z,e) will cause inconsistency, and this will be exacerbated when Cov(X,Z) is small QOB qualifies as a weak instrument that may be correlated with unobserved determinants of wages (e.g., family income) Bound, Jaeger, and Baker (1995), J.A.S.A. Even if the instrument is “good,” matters can be made far worse with IV as opposed to LS – Weak correlation between IV and endogenous regressor can pose severe finite-sample bias And…really large samples won’t help, especially if there is even weak endogeneity between IV and error First-stage diagnostics provide a sense of how good an IV is in a given setting – F-test and partial-R2 on IV’s Useful Diagnostic Tools for IV Models Tests of instrument relevance – Tests of instrument exogeneity – Weak IV’s → Large variance of bIV as well as potentially severe finite-sample bias Endogenous IV’s → Inconsistency of bIV that makes it no better (and probably worse) than bLS Durbin-Wu-Hausman test – Endogeneity of the problem regressor(s) Tests of Instrument Relevance Diagnostics based on the F-test for the joint significance of the IV’s – – Partial R-square for the IV’s – Nelson and Startz (1990); Staiger and Stock (1997) Bound, Jaeger, and Baker (1995) Shea (1997) There is a growing econometric literature on the “weak instrument” problem Tests of Instrument Exogeneity Model must be overidentified, i.e., more IV’s than endogenous X’s – H0: All IV’s uncorrelated with structural error Overidentification test: 1. Estimate structural model 2. Regress IV residuals on all exogenous variables 3. Compute NR2 and compare to chi-square df = # IV’s – # endogenous X’s Durbin-Wu-Hausman (DWH) Test Balances the consistency of IV against the efficiency of LS – – H0: IV and LS both consistent, but LS is efficient H1: Only IV is consistent DWH test for a single endogenous regressor: – DWH = (bIV – bLS) / √(s2bIV – s2bLS) ~ N(0,1) If |DWH| > 1.96, then X is endogenous and IV is the preferred estimator despite its inefficiency Durbin-Wu-Hausman (DWH) Test A roughly equivalent procedure for DWH: 1. Estimate the first-stage model 2. Include the first-stage residual in the structural model along with the endogenous X 3. Test for significance of the coefficient on residual Note: Coefficient on endogenous X in this model is bIV (standard error is smaller, though) – First-stage residual is a “generated regressor” Software Considerations I have a strong preference for Stata – – – Classic routine (-ivreg-) as well as a user-written one with a lot more diagnostic capability (-ivreg2-) Non-linear models: -ivprobit- and -ivtobitPanel models: -xtivreg- and -xtivreg2- Useful post-estimation routines – – – Overidentification: -overidEndogeneity of X in LS model: -ivendogHeteroscedasticity: -ivhettest- Software Considerations Basic model specification in Stata ivreg y (x = z) w [weight = wtvar], options y = dependent variable x = endogenous variable z = instrumental variable w = control variable(s) – Useful options: first, ffirst, robust, cluster(varname) Software Considerations For SAS users: Proc Syslin (SAS/ETS) – Basic command: proc syslin data=dataset 2sls options1; endogenous x; instruments z w; model y = x w / options2; weight wtvar; run; – – Useful “options1”: first Useful “options2”: overid Software Considerations For SPSS users: 2SLS – Basic command: 2sls y with x w / instruments z w / constant. – For point-and-click aficionados Analyze → Regression → Two-Stage Least Squares DEPENDENT, EXPLANATORY, and INSTRUMENTAL Software Considerations For Limdep users: 2SLS – Basic command: 2SLS ; Lhs = y ; Rhs = one, x, w ; Inst = one, z, w ; Wts = wtvar ; Dfc $ Application: Adolescent Work and Delinquent Behavior Prior research shows a positive correlation between teenage work and delinquency – Reasons to suspect serious endogeneity bias 2nd wave of the NLSY97 (N = 8,368) – – – – Y = 1 if committed delinquent act (31.9%) X = 1 if worked in a formal job (52.6%) Z1 = 1 if child labor law allows 40+ hours (14.2%) Z2 = 1 if no child labor restriction in place (39.6%) Regression Model Ignoring Endogeneity . reg pcrime work if nomiss==1 & wave==2 Source | SS df MS -------------+-----------------------------Model | 1.37395379 1 1.37395379 Residual | 1815.97786 8366 .217066443 -------------+-----------------------------Total | 1817.35182 8367 .217204711 Number of obs F( 1, 8366) Prob > F R-squared Adj R-squared Root MSE = = = = = = 8368 6.33 0.0119 0.0008 0.0006 .4659 -----------------------------------------------------------------------------pcrime | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------work | .0256633 .0102005 2.52 0.012 .0056677 .0456588 _cons | .3053242 .0074009 41.26 0.000 .2908167 .3198318 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ Teenage workers significantly more delinquent – Modest effect but consistent with prior research First-Stage Model . reg work law40 nolaw if nomiss==1 & wave==2 Source | SS df MS -------------+-----------------------------Model | 271.829722 2 135.914861 Residual | 1814.33364 8365 .216895832 -------------+-----------------------------Total | 2086.16336 8367 .249332301 Number of obs F( 2, 8365) Prob > F R-squared Adj R-squared Root MSE = = = = = = 8368 626.64 0.0000 0.1303 0.1301 .46572 -----------------------------------------------------------------------------work | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------law40 | .0688902 .0154383 4.46 0.000 .0386274 .099153 nolaw | .3818684 .0110273 34.63 0.000 .3602521 .4034847 _cons | .3655636 .0074883 48.82 0.000 .3508847 .3802425 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ State child labor laws affect probability of work – This is a really strong first stage (F, R2) Two-Stage Least Squares Model . ivreg pcrime (work = law40 nolaw) if nomiss==1 & wave==2 Instrumental variables (2SLS) regression Source | SS df MS -------------+-----------------------------Model | -19.5287923 1 -19.5287923 Residual | 1836.88061 8366 .219564978 -------------+-----------------------------Total | 1817.35182 8367 .217204711 Number of obs F( 1, 8366) Prob > F R-squared Adj R-squared Root MSE = = = = = = 8368 6.86 0.0088 . . .46858 -----------------------------------------------------------------------------pcrime | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------work | -.0744352 .0284206 -2.62 0.009 -.1301466 -.0187238 _cons | .3580171 .0158135 22.64 0.000 .3270187 .3890155 -----------------------------------------------------------------------------Instrumented: work Instruments: law40 nolaw ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ What Do the Models Suggest Thus Far? Completely different conclusions! – OLS = Teenage work is criminogenic (b = +.026) – 2SLS = Teenage work is prophylactic (b = –.074) Delinquency risk increases by 8.5 percent (base = .305) Delinquency risk decreases by 20.7 percent (base = .358) Which model should we believe? – We still have some additional diagnostic work to do to evaluate the 2SLS model Overidentification test, Hausman test RegressionBased Overidentification Test . reg IVresid law40 nolaw if nomiss==1 & wave==2 Source | SS df MS -------------+-----------------------------Model | .111648085 2 .055824043 Residual | 1836.76895 8365 .219577878 -------------+-----------------------------Total | 1836.8806 8367 .219538735 Number of obs F( 2, 8365) Prob > F R-squared Adj R-squared Root MSE = 8368 = 0.25 = 0.7755 = 0.0001 = -0.0002 = .46859 -----------------------------------------------------------------------------IVresid | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------law40 | .010988 .0155334 0.71 0.479 -.0194613 .0414374 nolaw | .0016436 .0110953 0.15 0.882 -.020106 .0233931 _cons | -.0022127 .0075344 -0.29 0.769 -.0169821 .0125567 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ Overidentification test = 8,368 × .0001 = .8368 ~ χ2(1) Overidentification Test from the Software . overid Tests of overidentifying restrictions: Sargan N*R-sq test 0.509 Chi-sq(1) Basmann test 0.508 Chi-sq(1) P-value = 0.4757 P-value = 0.4758 IV’s jointly pass the exogeneity requirement – Notice that -overid- provides a global test, whereas the regression-based approach allows you to test the IV’s jointly as well as individually Durbin-Wu-Hausman (DWH) Test Estimated by Hand Summary coefficients – – – OLS model: b = +.026, s.e. = .010 2SLS model: b = –.074, s.e. = .028 Notice the size of the 2SLS standard error DWH = (–.074 – .026) / √(.0282 – .0102) ≈ –3.82 CONCLUSION: Least squares estimate of the “work effect” is biased and inconsistent – The 2SLS estimate is preferred Regression-Based DWH Test . reg pcrime work FSresid if nomiss==1 & wave==2 Source | SS df MS -------------+-----------------------------Model | 4.50567523 2 2.25283761 Residual | 1812.84614 8365 .216718009 -------------+-----------------------------Total | 1817.35182 8367 .217204711 Number of obs F( 2, 8365) Prob > F R-squared Adj R-squared Root MSE = = = = = = 8368 10.40 0.0000 0.0025 0.0022 .46553 -----------------------------------------------------------------------------pcrime | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------work | -.0744352 .0282357 -2.64 0.008 -.1297842 -.0190862 FSresid | .1150956 .0302771 3.80 0.000 .0557449 .1744462 _cons | .3580171 .0157106 22.79 0.000 .3272204 .3888139 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ Coeff. on work is bIV, while t-test on FSresid is DWH – Standard error for work is underestimated, though Or Just Let the Software Give You the DWH Test . ivendog Tests of endogeneity of: work H0: Regressor is exogenous Wu-Hausman F test: Durbin-Wu-Hausman chi-sq test: 14.45067 14.43093 F(1,8365) Chi-sq(1) P-value = 0.00014 P-value = 0.00015 Notice that -ivendog- provides a chi-square test for DWH, but the z-test that we computed by hand is easily recovered – √(χ2) = z √(14.43) = 3.80 Alternative Specifications for the Work-Delinquency Association IV probit model – – Continuous work hours – – Without IV’s: b = +.072 (s.e. = .029) With IV’s: b = –.207 (s.e. = .078) Without IV’s: b = +.0015 (s.e. = .0003) With IV’s: b = –.0024 (s.e. = .0009) Indicator for “intensive” work (>20 hours) – – Without IV’s: b = +.043 (s.e. = .012) With IV’s: b = –.095 (s.e. = .036) Alternative Specifications for the Work-Delinquency Association Control variables = gender, race, child, dropout, family structure, family size, urbanicity, dwelling, school suspension, unemployment rate, mobility – Binary work status – Continuous work hours – Without IV’s: b = +.013 (s.e. = .010) With IV’s: b = –.061 (s.e. = .029) Without IV’s: b = +.0007 (s.e. = .0003) With IV’s: b = –.0023 (s.e. = .0010) Intensive work indicator Without IV’s: b = +.020 (s.e. = .012) With IV’s: b = –.085 (s.e. = .040) So Where Do We Stand with the Work-Delinquency Question? Are child labor laws correlated with work? – Are child labor laws good IV’s? – YES = overidentification test is not rejected Is teenage work endogenous? – YES = first-stage F is large YES = Hausman test is rejected Prior research findings that teenage work is criminogenic are selection artifacts Stata Commands for the Foregoing Example Regression model ignoring endogeneity: reg y x w First-stage regression model: – reg x z1 z2 w With controls and multiple IV’s, test relevance: test z1 z2 2SLS regression model: ivreg y (x = z1 z2) w Stata Commands for the Foregoing Example Manual post hoc commands – Get residuals for regression-based overid. test: – Get residuals for regression-based DWH test: After 2SLS model: predict IVresid if e(sample), resid Then: reg IVresid z1 z2 After first-stage model: predict FSresid if e(sample), resid Then: reg y x w FSresid “Canned” post hoc commands – After 2SLS model: overid and ivendog Now…What Happens if I Throw in a Potentially Bogus Instrument? Now there are three instrumental variables – – – Z1 = 1 if child labor law allows 40+ hours (14.2%) Z2 = 1 if no child labor restriction in place (39.6%) Z3 = 1 if high unemployment rate in county (20.1%) A little more difficult to tell a convincing story that the unemployment rate is only related to delinquency through work experience – But let’s see what happens First-Stage Model . reg work law40 nolaw highun if nomiss==1 & wave==2 Source | SS df MS -------------+-----------------------------Model | 277.229696 3 92.4098987 Residual | 1808.93366 8364 .216276144 -------------+-----------------------------Total | 2086.16336 8367 .249332301 Number of obs F( 3, 8364) Prob > F R-squared Adj R-squared Root MSE = = = = = = 8368 427.28 0.0000 0.1329 0.1326 .46505 -----------------------------------------------------------------------------work | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------law40 | .0636421 .0154519 4.12 0.000 .0333525 .0939317 nolaw | .3775975 .0110447 34.19 0.000 .3559472 .3992479 highun | -.0636009 .0127283 -5.00 0.000 -.0885517 -.0386502 _cons | .3808061 .0080759 47.15 0.000 .3649754 .3966368 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ So far so good and consistent with expectation Two-Stage Least Squares Model . ivreg pcrime (work = law40 nolaw highun) if nomiss==1 & wave==2 Instrumental variables (2SLS) regression Source | SS df MS -------------+-----------------------------Model | -16.0635514 1 -16.0635514 Residual | 1833.41537 8366 .219150773 -------------+-----------------------------Total | 1817.35182 8367 .217204711 Number of obs F( 1, 8366) Prob > F R-squared Adj R-squared Root MSE = = = = = = 8368 5.47 0.0194 . . .46814 -----------------------------------------------------------------------------pcrime | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------work | -.0657624 .0281159 -2.34 0.019 -.1208765 -.0106483 _cons | .3534516 .0156602 22.57 0.000 .3227537 .3841496 -----------------------------------------------------------------------------Instrumented: work Instruments: law40 nolaw highun ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ Post-Hoc Diagnostics . overid Tests of overidentifying restrictions: Sargan N*R-sq test 5.301 Chi-sq(2) Basmann test 5.301 Chi-sq(2) P-value = 0.0706 P-value = 0.0706 . ivendog Tests of endogeneity of: work H0: Regressor is exogenous Wu-Hausman F test: Durbin-Wu-Hausman chi-sq test: 12.32811 12.31438 F(1,8365) Chi-sq(1) P-value = 0.00045 P-value = 0.00045 Overidentification gives cause for concern – The p-value shouldn’t be anywhere near 0.05 Follow-Up Overidentification Test . reg IVresid law40 nolaw highun Source | SS df MS -------------+-----------------------------Model | 1.1613555 3 .387118499 Residual | 1832.25406 8364 .21906433 -------------+-----------------------------Total | 1833.41541 8367 .219124586 Number of obs F( 3, 8364) Prob > F R-squared Adj R-squared Root MSE = = = = = = 8368 1.77 0.1511 0.0006 0.0003 .46804 -----------------------------------------------------------------------------IVresid | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------law40 | .0080993 .0155512 0.52 0.603 -.0223849 .0385836 nolaw | -.0035329 .0111156 -0.32 0.751 -.0253223 .0182565 highun | -.0277671 .0128101 -2.17 0.030 -.0528781 -.0026561 _cons | .0058369 .0081277 0.72 0.473 -.0100955 .0217693 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ Okay…unemployment rate is problematic as IV Conclusion from Diagnostic Tests 2SLS “work effect” is similar – – Without unemployment, b = –.074 (s.e. = .028) With unemployment, b = –.066 (s.e. = .028) But…the second model is invalidated because the unemployment rate is not exogenous – If affects criminality through other channels We need to control for all other indirect pathways, or… It should not be used as an IV at all Closing Comments about Instrumental Variables Studies In general, a lagged value of the endogenous regressor is not a good instrument – Traditional structural equation model uses lagged values of X and Y as instruments to break the simultaneity between the current values of X and Y X1 X2 Y1 Y2 These models impose the awfully strong assumption that lagged values of X and Y only affect the outcomes through current values Closing Comments about Instrumental Variables Studies Good IV models are generally interesting in their own right, and should not be treated as “tack on” analyses – Practice varies widely across disciplines Some researchers write papers about their discovery and application of a “clever” IV for some problem Other researchers “tack on” IV models at the end of their analysis, often poorly, as a way to convince readers that their results are robust Rules for Good Practice with Instrumental Variables Models IV models can be very informative, but it’s your job to convince your audience – Show the first-stage model diagnostics – Report test(s) of overidentifying restrictions – Even the most clever IV might not be sufficiently strongly related to X to be a useful source of identification An invalid IV is often worse than no IV at all Report LS endogeneity (DWH) test Rules for Good Practice with Instrumental Variables Models Most importantly, TELL A STORY about why a particular IV is a “good instrument” Something to consider when thinking about whether a particular IV is “good” – Does the IV, for all intents and purposes, randomize the endogenous regressor? Other Interesting IV Topics I Just Don’t Have Time to Cover 2SLS with a continuous “treatment” Instrumental variables for sample selectivity Generalized method of moments (IV-GMM) Non-linear two-stage least squares (N2SLS) Two-sample instrumental variables (TSIV) Fixed-effects instrumental variables (FEIV) Dynamic panel data estimators References Angrist. (2006). Instrumental variables methods in experimental criminology research: What, why and how. Journal of Experimental Criminology, 2, 23-44. Angrist & Evans. (1998). Children and their parents’ labor supply: Evidence from exogenous variation in family size. American Economic Review, 88, 450-477. Angrist & Krueger. (1991). Does compulsory school attendance affect schooling and earnings. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 979-1014. Angrist & Krueger. (2001). Instrumental variables and the search for identification: From supply and demand to natural experiments. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15, 69-85. Apel, Bushway, Paternoster, Brame & Sweeten. (2008). Using state child labor laws to identify the causal effect of youth employment on deviant behavior and academic achievement. Journal of Quantitative Criminology, 24, 337-362. References Bound, Jaeger & Baker. (1995). Problems with instrumental variables estimation when the correlation between the instruments and the endogenous explanatory variables is weak. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 90, 443-450. Evans & Owens. (2007). COPS and crime. Journal of Public Economics, 91, 181-201. Imbens & Angrist. (1994). Identification and estimation of local average treatment effects. Econometrica, 62, 467-475. Kelejian. (1971). Two-stage least squares and econometric systems linear in parameters but nonlinear in the endogenous variable. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 66, 373-374. Klick & Tabarrok. (2005). Using terror alert levels to estimate the effect of police on crime. Journal of Law & Economics, 48, 267-279. Levitt. (1996). The effect of prison population size on crime rates: Evidence from prison overcrowding litigation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111, 319-351. Levitt. (1997). Using electoral cycles in police hiring to estimate the effect of police on crime. American Economic Review, 87, 270-290. References Levitt. (2002). Using electoral cycles in police hiring to estimate the effect of police on crime: Reply. American Economic Review, 92, 1244-1250. Nelson and Startz. (1990). The distribution of the instrumental variables estimator and its t-ratio when the instrument is a poor one. Journal of Business, 63, S125-S140. Permutt & Hebel. (1989). Simultaneous-equation estimation in a clinical trial of the effect of smoking on birth weight. Biometrics, 45, 619-622. Sexton & Hebel. (1984). A clinical trial of change in maternal smoking and its effect on birth weight. Journal of the American Medical Association, 251, 911-915. Shea. (1997). Instrument relevance in multivariate linear models: A simple measure. Review of Economics and Statistics, 79, 348-352. Sherman & Berk. (1984). The specific deterrent effect of arrest for domestic assault. American Sociological Review, 49, 261-272. Staiger and Stock. (1997). Instrumental variables regression with weak instruments. Econometrica, 65, 557-586.