* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Lender of last resort
United States housing bubble wikipedia , lookup
Peer-to-peer lending wikipedia , lookup
Financialization wikipedia , lookup
Credit rationing wikipedia , lookup
Securitization wikipedia , lookup
Interest rate ceiling wikipedia , lookup
History of the Federal Reserve System wikipedia , lookup
Money supply wikipedia , lookup
Fractional-reserve banking wikipedia , lookup
Shadow banking system wikipedia , lookup
Lender of last resort wray Lesson 1-4-2015 Bagehot’s principles • lending to only solvent banks, against good collateral, and at “high” or penalty rates. Criticsm of mehrling • A bank that knows an asset is bad and sells it at an inflated value to a lender of last resort will have to come up with the difference in value in the future or the bank will fail. This is a strong disincentive to passing bad assets, particularly in 19th c. financial systems where bankers’ personal assets’ were on the line. • It is precisely this disincentive to passing bad assets off on the central bank that the authors apparently wish to eliminate by establishing a dealer of last resort – and that they claim is a policy that Bagehot would have supported. • The distinctions between the 19th c. environment and the modern environment are very important, and are neither addressed – nor indeed even acknowledged – by Bagehot was a Shadow Banker. • The Bank of England determined which assets were worthy of being discounted in an environment where almost no bad assets circulated: the assets eligible for discount were of high quality, not only because they had very short maturities.., but also because the bankers who circulated the assets put their personal wealth at risk by accepting them and then discounting them. Sissiko criticism • Note that Figure 2 also errs in indicating that bills discounted at the Bank of England were accompanied only by the guarantee of the acceptor. In fact, the discounter also guaranteed payment on the bill. Thus, every bill held by the Bank was supported by the credit of at least three parties, the issuer, the acceptor, and the discounter. Each of these parties was liable for the full value of the bill. sissiko • The authors describe the private bill market of Bagehot’s time as “a market in short-term private debt, typically collateralized by tradable goods.” (at 5) The private bills that circulated in Bagehot’s era were not collateralized. thornton • Suppose that A sells one hundred pounds worth of goods to B at six months credit, and takes a bill at six months for it; and that B, within a month after sells the same goods, at a like credit, to C, taking a like bill; and again that C, after another month, sells them to D, taking a like bill, and so on. Bills Not collateralized • In short, the whole point of the 19th c. system of private bills in Britain is that they were not collateralized, instead they were typically generated as part of the process of trade (that is, even under the acceptance credit system, goods were regularly transferred, there was just no requirement that every bill be created in the process of such a transfer). • There may then, at the end of six months, be six bills of £100 each existing at the same time; and every one of these may possibly have been discounted. Of all these bills, then, one only represents any actual property.” • The authors of Bagehot was a Shadow Banker define shadow banking as “money market funding of capital market lending” and describe it as “the centrally important channel of credit for our times” (at 2). • Capital market lending generally refers to lending with a maturity in excess of one year, and contrasts with lending on money markets for terms of one year or less. • Funding long-term assets with short-term liabilities creates funding risk, that is, the risk that you can’t pay the maturing paper by rolling it over into new short-term debt, and relies on bank guarantees in the form of liquidity facilities or tri-party clearing bank guarantees to address this risk. Funding longterm assets with short-term liabilities also creates market risk, the danger that the value of the assets drops significantly below the • Funding long-term assets with short-term liabilities also creates market risk, the danger that the value of the assets drops significantly below the value of the short-term liabilities before they are refinanced. • Another important characteristic almost certainly differentiates 19th c. money market assets from those of modern markets: the personal liability of the issuers and the guarantors. Unlimited liability • By contrast in 19th c. Britain, issuers and bankers faced unlimited liability – or capital calls if they were stockholders – on their obligations. Because of the personal stake that the bankers and the owners of banks had in the success of their business, the general credit quality of both assets and acceptances in 19th c. Britain was almost certainly higher than that of the underlying assets or CDS of modern markets. Cds issued by modern corporation • Thus, another important distinction between a CDS and an acceptance is the fact that a CDS is issued by a modern corporation whereas an acceptance was issued by either an unincorporated firm or a 19th c. British joint stock firm. • Not only were the bank guarantees in 19th c. Britain of higher credit quality than those issued by modern corporations, but the underlying assets were most likely of higher credit quality too. • D. Shadow Banking is Not “Market-Based” Lending • The “market-based” credit system is often contrasted with the “bank-based” credit system to distinguish environments where firms raise funds by issuing securities on markets from those where firms raise funds by borrowing from banks.31 • When it comes to money markets, however, the line between market-based and bank- • When it comes to money markets, however, the line between market-based and bankbased systems cannot be clearly drawn, because the so-called market-based systems rely heavily on guarantees provided by the banking system. In commercial paper markets non-financial companies, including ABCP conduits, can only borrow on these markets if they have liquidity support, usually in the form of a liquidity facility, repo or swap provided by a bank. Bank-guaranteed credit system • second, it was also backstopped by guarantees provided by the tri-party clearing banks, which bore the credit risk of the dealer banks during the day. In short, in the money markets the “market-based” credit system might as well be called the “bank-guaranteed” credit system. • Repo liabilities commercial paper have no big secondary markets. • 19° century instead • Active secondary market for the bills • It is misleading to describe the shadow banking system that exists today as “money market funding of capital market lending” and to focus on it as a means of financing assets, because at present by far the most important use of shadow banking instruments is to provide wholesale funding for investment banks and through them indirect financing of assets that sit on their balance sheets. • If unsecured credit falls into disuse, it is not clear that the money supply will be able to grow with the needs of the economy. Whereas traditional money markets supported economic growth through the issue of high-quality unsecured debt, modern collateralized money markets – to the degree that they fund private sector assets at all – fund instruments that trade actively and have meaningful market prices, although they may Failure of collateralized markets • To the degree that modern money markets are no longer able to expand the money supply to meet the needs of individuals and small businesses, but instead are constrained to rely on collateral issued by governments and large companies, they may fail to meet the needs of the economy and to support economic growth. • In short, it is not clear that collateralized money market instruments can play the same role in expanding the money supply and in economic growth as that played by unsecured money market instruments. • To summarize, modern collateralized money markets are likely to face more sudden demands for liquidity than traditional unsecured money markets because (i) margin calls are made on a daily basis, not when the debt matures; (ii) the leverage inherent in collateralized borrowing can force borrowers to sell collateral in order to pay off loans aggravating the price decline; • and (iii) the reliance of the market upon collateral means that when price falls all lenders make margin calls simultaneously. • Unlike traditional unsecured money markets where it took many individual decisions by independent lenders to create a panic, liquidity crises in collateralized markets are an almost mechanical function of declines in the price of collateral – that are exacerbated by the market’s reaction to the decline in price. • This action can be distinguished from the traditional lender of last resort action because: • (i) The lending took the form, not of wrapped sales, but of collateralized loans, where the lender has the right to demand additional collateral on a daily basis. • (ii) The central bank did not lend only against high-quality assets, but on many days accepted tens of billions of dollars of equities, junk and unrated securities from each of a variety of primary dealer borrowers.139 • (iii) In collateralized money markets the temporary provision of cash is not sufficient to quell a crisis. Wray on llr Fed’s lending rates • We provide a detailed analysis of the Fed’s lending rates and reveal that it did not follow • Bagehot’s classical doctrine of charging penalty rates on loans against good collateral. • Further, the lending continued over very long periods, raising suspicions about the solvency of the institutions. Others, however, have criticized the Fed as being anything but classical not only in exceeding traditional bounds in the magnitude of its balance sheet expansion but also for rescuing unsound institutions rather than limiting its assistance to solvent but illiquid firms, for accepting worthless collateral in security for its loans, for charging subsidy rather than penalty loan interest rates, and for channeling aid to privileged borrowers rather than impartially to the market in general. Llr policy classicals viewed LLR policy as part and parcel of the central bank’s broader responsibility to protect the stock of bank-created money from contraction (and to expand it to compensate for falls in its circulation velocity). Money protection function The central bank fulfills its money protection function by pre-committing to expanding reserves without limit to accommodate panicinduced increases in the demand for money. Avoid to dump assets By creating new reserves on demand for sound but temporarily illiquid banks, the LLR makes it unnecessary for those banks, in desperate attempts to raise cash, to dump assets at firesale prices that might render the banks insolvent and would reduce the outstanding supply of bank money (as loans are called in and deposits are debited.) llr Thornton especially, but Bagehot too, understood that the central bank’s distinguishing feature as an LLR consists of its monopoly power to create unlimited amounts of high-powered money in the form of its own notes and deposits, items whose legal tender status and universal acceptance mark them as money of ultimate redemption and the equivalent of gold coin. Special responsibility Unlike the bank, whose duties extend only to its stockholders and customers, the LLR’s responsibilities extend to the entire macroeconomy. This special responsibility dictates that the LLR behave precisely the opposite of the banker in times of stress, expanding its note and deposit issue and its loans at the very time the bank is contracting. Money view It follows that the LLR must draw a sharp distinction between the asset,or credit (loans and discounts) side, and the liability, or money (notes and deposits) side of bank balance sheets. Although the two aggregates, bank credit and bank money, tend to move together, it is panic-induced falls in the latter rather than the former that render damage to the real economy. money Because money forms the transaction medium of final settlement, it follows that its contraction— rather than credit crunches and collapses—is the root cause of lapses in real activity. Central bank To prevent this sequence of events, the LLR must stand ready to accommodate all panicinduced increases in the demand for highpowered money, demands that it can readily satisfy by virtue of its open-ended capacity to create base money in the form of its own notes and deposits. • Most recently, in the financial crisis of 2008– 09, the Fed adhered to some classical • principles, while it departed from others.18 C Evaluation of policy Consistent with the classical model, it provided reserves to the banking system, albeit with some delay and in a rather haphazard manner (as detailed in our 2012 report). These injections were sufficient to resolve the crisis (but insufficient to prevent the recession or to boost the weak recovery even after several rounds of quantitative easing). Quality of collateral • What was inconsistent with Bagehot’s advice, however, was that much of this collateral was complex, opaque, hard-to-value, illiquid, difficult to buy and sell, risky, and liable to default—hardly good security. The Fed also purchased outright from banks and other financial institutions assets such as commercial paper, securities backed by credit cards, student loans, auto loans, and other assets, and mortgage-backed securities and debts of GSEs. Finally, it guaranteed debt of Citigroup, and extended loans to insurance giant AIG, both of them insolvent firms deemed too big and too interconnected to fail. departures • • • • • • • Emphasis on Credit Instead of Money Taking Junk Collateral. Charging Subsidy Rates Rescuing Unsound Firms Too Big to Fail. Extension of Loan Repayment Schedules No Pre-announced Commitment No Clear Exit Strategy Excess reserves The excess arose originally from the Fed’s emergency lending activities after August 008, increasing from less than $2 billion in August to $767 billion by year-end 2008. Quantitative easing Afterward, throughout 2009 and until mid-year 2010, the Fed engaged in the first major quantitative easing program of purchases of government agency debt and agency guaranteed mortgage-backed securities. The Fed’s purchases reached a cumulative total of $1.285 trillion, and excess reserves reached nearly $1 trillion. Reserves use the new reserves provided by the purchases program enabled the banking system to fund the repayment of about $1 trillion of various forms of advances to financial institutions under the emergency lending program. The emergency lending program ended, but quantitative easing replaced it. Second round QE In early 2011, the Fed began its second round of quantitative easing, aimed at purchasing about $600 billion of longer-term Treasury securities. When the program ended in June 2011, $581 billion had been added to excess reserves, with the peak amount reached in July 2011, $1.618 trillion. The peak amount of monetary base that same month was $2.681 trillion. No increase in bank credit The Fed should have learned from the experience of the quantitative easing programs that its purchases of securities did little or nothing to increase the quantity of bank credit actually supplied to the general economy. QE3 • This past September the Fed announced a full-speedahead procession with QE3. This time, the Fed promised to buy $40 billion worth of mortgage-backed securities (MBSs) everymonth through the end of the year, and to keep what is essentially a zero interest-rate policy (ZIRP) in place through mid-2015. The Fed also announced that it will purchase other long-maturity assets to bring the total monthly purchases up to $85 billion, with the bias toward the long end expected to put downward pressure on long-term interest rates. The Fed made clear that QE3 is open-ended, to continue as long as necessary to stimulate to a robust economic recovery. graph How the fed pays for assets • When the Fed buys assets, it purchases them by crediting banks with reserves. The result of QE is that the Fed’s balance sheet grows rapidly—to, literally, trillions of dollars. At the same time, banks exchange the assets they are selling (the Treasuries and MBSs that the Fed is buying) for credits to their reserves held at the Fed. Normally, banks try to minimize reserve holdings—to what they need to cover payments clearing (banks clear accounts with one another using reserves) as well as Fed-imposed required reserve ratios. With QE, the banks accumulate large quantities of excess reserves. Lend out reserves • A lot of people—including policymakers—exhort the banks to “lend out the reserves” on the notion that this would “get the economy going.” There are two problems with that thinking. First, banks can lend reserves only to other banks—and all the other banks have exactly the same problem: too many reserves. A bank cannot lend reserves to households or firms because they do not have accounts at the Fed; indeed, there is no operational maneuver that would allow anyone but a bank to borrow the reserves (when a bank lends reserves to another bank, the Fed debits the lending bank’s reserves and credits the borrowing bank’s reserves). … • The second problem with the argument is that banks do not need reserves in order to lend. • What they need is good, willing, and creditworthy borrowers. qe What QE comes down to, really, is a substitution of reserve deposits at the Fed in place of Treasuries and MBSs on the asset side of banks. In the case of Fed purchases of Treasuries, this reduces bank interest income—making them less profitable. Effectively, the banks are moving losers off their balance sheets in order to get safe reserves that earn next to nothing. That is a good trade! But, again, it does not induce banks to make more loans, does little to stimulate Main Street, and creates moral hazard in the financial system as it teaches banks an invaluable lesson: too dumb to fail. Rates for top 8 borrowers continues • The Fed lent huge volumes of reserves at low interest rates over a very long period. There are two ways of perceiving this. First, it could be seen as an interest rate subsidy to (largely) big banks and to credit markets more generally—a gift provided by the Fed to purportedly solvent institutions. The second possibility is that these institutions were suffering from insolvency, not liquidity problems. They could not borrow at reasonable interest rates in markets, and so the Fed had to lend to them for extended periods to try to restore solvency. Subsidy to insolvent banks • Lending at low rates to insolvent banks for a sustained period of time (with an average of almost two years) can have the effect of increasing bank profitability. It is of little wonder that the crisis was mitigated after the Fed bought $1.25 trillion in possibly toxic assets. undemocratic • By doing so, it not only circumvented the normal functioning of financial markets but it also circumvented the democratic process. Lending at or below market rates, allowing banks to negotiate these rates through auctions, and rescuing insolvent banks has validated not only unstable banking instruments and practices but also has perhaps set the stage for an even greater crisis. No liquidity crisis In addition, the extraordinary extension of the terms of the facilities is not consistent with a liquidity crisis.