Download Abstract - International Association for Energy Economics

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

German Climate Action Plan 2050 wikipedia , lookup

Climate change feedback wikipedia , lookup

Climate change and poverty wikipedia , lookup

Economics of climate change mitigation wikipedia , lookup

Climate change mitigation wikipedia , lookup

Climate-friendly gardening wikipedia , lookup

Energiewende in Germany wikipedia , lookup

IPCC Fourth Assessment Report wikipedia , lookup

Citizens' Climate Lobby wikipedia , lookup

Decarbonisation measures in proposed UK electricity market reform wikipedia , lookup

Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme wikipedia , lookup

Carbon pricing in Australia wikipedia , lookup

Politics of global warming wikipedia , lookup

Biosequestration wikipedia , lookup

Carbon capture and storage (timeline) wikipedia , lookup

Low-carbon economy wikipedia , lookup

Mitigation of global warming in Australia wikipedia , lookup

Business action on climate change wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Impacts of Energy Policies on China’s Energy Demand and Carbon Emissions: A Study using
DEMETER-China Model
Ying Fan*, Center for Energy and Environmental Policy research, Institute of Policy and Management, Chinese
Academy of Sciences, Beijing 100190, China, [email protected]
Ming-Lei Liu, Center for Energy and Environmental Policy research, Institute of Policy and Management, Chinese
Academy of Sciences, Beijing 100190, China, [email protected]
Lei Zhu, Center for Energy and Environmental Policy research, Institute of Policy and Management, Chinese
Academy of Sciences, Beijing 100190, China, [email protected]
* Corresponding author
Overview
Great attention has been paid to climate change worldwide. On the one hand the international community is
trying to reach a consensus on GHG emission reduction; on the other hand many nations have issued their selfreduction goals to promote domestic emission reductions. Along with the remarkable economic growth, a rapid
increase has emerged in China’s energy consumption, in which fossil fuels, especially high-carbon fuels such as coal,
account for a dominating proportion. In 2008, fossil fuels account for 91.1% with coal accounting for 68.7% of total
primary energy consumption in China equivalent to 2850 Mtce (Million tons of coal equivalent), with GHG
emissions arising from fossil fuel consumption containing approximately 1.8 billion tons of carbon, according to the
estimation of IEA. In this case, the national plan has been proclaimed by the Chinese government to reduce the
carbon emission intensity in 2020 by 40%~45% compared with the level of 2005 and to increase the proportion of
non-fossil energy in the total primary energy consumption to 15% by 2020. Therefore, it is great efforts that China is
obliged to make in developing non-fossil energy as well as improving energy efficiency. Chinese government will
use many policy tools, especially economic tools such as carbon tax. Referring to this issue, a well-established
DEMETER-China model is employed in this study to exhibit the analysis of the impacts of carbon tax on future
economic output, energy consumption and portfolio, and carbon emissions in China.
Methods
As a top-down macro-economic model on China’s energy and climate policies, the DEMETER-China model is
developed on basis of DEMETER model (van der Zwaan et al. 2002; Gerlagh and van der Zwaan 2003, 2006;
Gerlagh et al. 2004) with emphasis on China’s energy and climate issues in this study. Such features of DEMETER
as the inclusion of two competing energy technologies (fossil and new energy) as well as niche markets and learningby-doing, the distinguishment of old capital from new, are mainly retained in the newly-developed DEMETERChina model, which has been proposed according to China’s real situations. 1) The labor productivity (measured in
efficiency unit) in representative of potential GDP growth is introduced to modify the production function of the
final goods sector, so that the future economic growth is in line with the basic assumptions. 2) The target function of
the representative consumer in original DEMETER is partially substituted by total consumption utility. 3) A policy
module is supplemented to model the present energy and climate policy framework in China.
The scenario analysis method is used to analyze the impact of different carbon tax levels on China’s carbon
emissions and macroeconomy with a consideration of endogenous technological change. In the business-as-usual
(BAU), we assume that the economy does not internalize climate change through carbon tax and that the returns from
technology learning are not captured. Further, four carbon tax cases and two technological change cases are
combined to form six policy scenarios. The parameters of DEMETER-China are calibrated according to relative
statistics and those of other models (e.g. China MARKAL-MACRO). The model is soved for 20 periods (5 years per
period) representing the interval 2005-2105. Rsults are presented for the time interval 2010-2070.
Results
Under BAU, carbon emissions would increase at an average rate of 3% by 2030 (after 2030 the increase rate
gradually declines), and reach its peak with 3890 million tons of carbon in 2040 after which carbon emissions start to
decrease. Under endogenous technological change, the higher the carbon tax level, the greater the carbon reductions.
Under the low carbon tax case with 100 yuan/tC, carbon emissions would not exceed 3600 million tons of carbon per
year while under the middle carbon tax case with 300 yuan/tC, the peak year of carbon emissions would be brought
ahead to 2030 with a lower value of 2700 million tons of carbon. Under the same carbon tax level, carbon emissions
under exogenous technological change are greater than under endogenous technological change.
Two options are available for realizing the carbon emission mitigation. First, it is possible to reduce energy
consumption by the substitution of capital and labor for energy. After around 2035 (when the lowest energy demand
is reached, compared to BAU), energy savings become less important in all policy scenarios, the origin of which is
that, as a result of increased learning, the price of the new energy technology has substantially decreased. It becomes
then more attractive to switch between the energy technologies, than to reduce total energy consumption. Indeed, the
economy has a second option to reduce emissions: a transition towards the use of the new energy. In the BAU
scenario the share of the new energy technology increases slowly, and reaches 24% in 2050. In addition, Carbon tax
would promote the development of the new energy technology. The higher the carbon tax level is, the greater the
share is. Moreover, the share under endogenous technical change is greater than under exogenous technical change
when the carbon tax level is set equally.
Under BAU scenario, investments in the new energy capcacity, as a percentage of GDP remains at about 0.4%.
When carbon tax is levied, more investments are required to increase the new energy capacity because more new
energy is needed to replace fossil-fuel energy. So the intial investments under exogenous technical change is lower
than under endogenous technical change. Carbon taxed cause the initial decline of GDP, the higher the carbon tax
level, the greater the decline, while endogenous technical change could ease the negative impact of carbon tax. When
there is learning-by-doing, the production cost of the new energy technology decreases. So the impact of carbon tax
on GDP also become weak when plenty of new energy could be acquired at a lower cost in the future. Under
exogenous technical change, however, the negative impact of carbon tax would last for a longer time.
Conclusions
1. The carbon emissions reach the peak value in about 2040 under BAU while carbon tax could reduce carbon
emisions and bring the peak year ahead. Under BAU, carbon emission firstly increase quickly with the rate levelling
off, then reach the peak year of 2040 after which emissions start to decrease. The higher the carbon tax level, the
greater the carbon reductions.
2. Carbon taxes reduce energy consumption under both endogenous and exogenous technological change. The
other scenarios present similar figures. After around 2035 (when the lowest energy demand is reached, compared to
BAU), energy savings become less important in all policy scenarios. It becomes then more attractive to switch
between the energy technologies, than to reduce total energy consumption.
3.When carbon tax is levied, more investments are required to increase the new energy capacity because more
new energy is needed to replace fossil-fuel energy. So the intial investments under exogenous technical change is
lower than under endogenous technical change. Carbon taxed cause the initial decline of GDP, the higher the carbon
tax level, the greater the decline, while endogenous technical change could ease the negative impact of carbon tax.
When there is learning-by-doing, the production cost of the new energy technology decreases. So the impact of
carbon tax on GDP also become weak when plenty of new energy could be acquired at a lower cost in the future.
References
Gerlagh, R., van der Zwaan, B., 2003. Gross world product and consumption in a global warming model with
endogenous technological change. Resource and Energy Economics 25, 35-57.
Gerlagh, R., van der Zwaan, B., 2004. A sensitivity analysis of timing and costs of greenhouse gas emission
reductions. Climate Change 65, 39-71.
Gerlagh, R., van der Zwaan, B., 2006. Options and instruments for a deep cut in CO2 emissions: carbon dioxide
capture or renewables, taxes or subsidies? The Energy Journal 27 (3), 25-48.
Gerlagh, R., van der Zwaan, B., Hofkes, M.W., et al., 2004. Impacts of CO2-Taxes in an economy with niche
markets and learning-by-doing. Environment and Resource Economics 28, 367-394.
Van der Zwaan, B., Gerlagh, R., Klaassen, G., Schrattenholzer, L., 2002. Endogeous technological change in climate
change modelling. Energy Economics 24, 1-19.