* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Web Note 7.1: Mean Reversion
Algorithmic trading wikipedia , lookup
Internal rate of return wikipedia , lookup
Mark-to-market accounting wikipedia , lookup
Private equity in the 2000s wikipedia , lookup
Private equity in the 1980s wikipedia , lookup
Private equity secondary market wikipedia , lookup
Rate of return wikipedia , lookup
Hedge (finance) wikipedia , lookup
Web Note 7.1: Mean Reversion A. The Concept Just as the name implies, a mean reverting economic time series is one that periodically returns to its long run mean value. It is the idea that although the time series may stochastically exceed its mean value for a prolonged period of time, or similarly fall short of it, it eventually and repeatedly returns to its mean value.1 In the finance literature, this concept is most typically applied to equity rate of return series. When authors speak of mean reversion in stock prices, it is typically in the context of a “normalized” price series such as the price-earnings (P/E) ratio. Equity price series are not level-stationary (as the economy grows, there is no upper bound to the value the aggregate stock market index can assume), and thus the “long run mean value” is not defined.2 Our discussion will focus exclusively on mean reversion as regards equity return series. In order to make this notion a bit more intuitive, let us consider two (stationary) models of equity return evolution which display this property: 1. rt 1 Er rt Er t 1 (1) where Er is the long term, unconditional mean return, σ is the return volatility and t is a sequence of i.i.d. N(0, 1) random variables. The parameter ρ is understood to satisfy 0 < ρ < 1. With ρ < 1, if rt Er , then in period t + 1, there is the tendency for rt+1 to exceed Er by a lesser amount, thereby pulling the return series back towards its mean; if rt Er , the like tendency is for rt 1 Er by a lesser amount. 2. rt 1 rt Er rt 1 t , 0 1 (2) where the notation is the same as in our first example. A return process governed by (2) is referred to as a “random walk with mean reversion,” and it suggests an even stronger quality of mean reversion: if rt 1 Er -- the series is above its unconditional means – then rt 1 relative to rt By the expression “returns to its mean value” we do not intend to suggest that the process exactly assumes its long run mean value, but that it assumes values in a small neighborhood of it. 2 Within the class of theoretical models we consider in Chapter 10 and Web Chapter A, there are good theoretical reasons to argue that the (P/E) ratio follows a stationary stochastic that is mean reverting. 1 1 will be the sum of a mean zero random component t and a negative term, the latter tending to reduce the extent that period rt 1 ’s return exceeds rt and thus also its mean, and vice versa. The classic AR-1 processes (those of the form rt 0 1rt 1 t are both stationary and mean reverting provided 1 0 . A stationary process, however, is not guaranteed to be mean reverting, with an i.i.d. process being a case in point. So far our discussion of “mean reversion” has been in the context of specific return processes, but, as yet, we have no “specific process free,” abstract definition. In fact, the literature offers three distinct definitions (we phrase them in the language of rate of return series): (i) A rate of return series rt is said to be mean reverting if and only if: corr rt , rt 1 0 ; (ii) A rate of return series rt is said to be mean reverting if and only if var rt rt 1 . . . rt k k var rt for any k 1 . This definition was first proposed in Poterba and Summers (1988), and employed by, e.g., Mukherji (2011). It stands in specific contrast to the property of a random walk where var rt rt 1 . . . rt k k var rt . (iii) A rate of return series rt is mean reverting if and only if cov rv ru , rx rw 0 for 0 u v w x . This definition appears to be applied in the insurance industry writings (see Exley et al. (2004)). In general, there does not appear to be any model-free direct relationships between these definitions. Not surprisingly, definition (i) appears to be the most widespread in the finance literature. What is the empirical evidence as regards mean reversion? It is first important to specify the time horizon over which mean reversion is alleged to be observed. If we speak of mean reversion over days (a topic of interest to traders) or weeks, the discussion is more fruitfully undertaken in the general context of momentum phenomena which we consider in Chapter 14. 2 For the case of long-term mean reversion, the principal case for its existence was made in two papers, both of which were published in 1988: Poterba and Summers (1988), and Fama and French (1988). Each paper models mean reversion slightly differently but ends up with the same conclusion: between 1926 – 1985, long term mean reversion in (aggregate) stock market returns was present at 3 – 5 year frequencies. In particular, three year lagged returns displayed a correlation of around .25, with 5 year returns displaying a lagged correlation of .4. Without getting into the precise statistical issues involved, suffice it to say that these results have been questioned even by Fama and French themselves (1988), and subsequently Fama (1991). Basically, there are not enough independent statistical observations for the relevant tests to be robust. Furthermore, if the stock returns for the period 1926 – 1940 are excluded from the data set, then any statistical evidence for mean reversion disappears. Using simulations, Richardson (1993) further argues that large autocorrelations for the 3 – 5 year horizon do not, in and of themselves, disprove the random walk hypothesis because within this range of horizons, autocorrelations are subject to large sampling variation. Evidence against mean reversion from an alternative perspective is found in Kim et al. (1991). See Mayost (2012) for an excellent literature review. In summary, it is probably fair to say that the empirical evidence for long term mean reversion in equity returns is modest at best. The same can be said of mean reversion as regards equity prices.3 This (tentative) conclusion is a welcome one for efficient markets theory. In particular, mean reversion at 3 – 5 year frequencies suggests predictability (see Chapter 10, footnote 14) at these same frequencies which is a violation of weak form efficient market theory. B. Mean Reversion and Long-Run Portfolio Risk. As discussed in Chapter 7, Pastor and Stambaugh (2012) provide one perspective on the ability of mean reversion to reduce long run portfolio risk. Spierdijk and Bikker (2012) provide another in a somewhat simpler and less stylized context. Rather than including issues of mean estimation, they assume the relevant mean returns are precisely estimated and try to measure the 3 In general, negative autocorrelation in equity prices (defn. (i) for mean reversion) implies the same for returns, but the converse is not true (see Spierdijk and Bikker (2012) for an illustration). 3 effects solely of mean reversion on long run portfolio composition and risk. We give some details of their underlying model of portfolio return evolution and their results in what follows. The model they employ is taken from Summers (1986) and Fama and French (1988). Let qte represent the price of the equity security or portfolio and qˆte its rational expectations price.4 Their model presumes that the actual equity price experiences random deviations from the rational expectations price and that these deviations are mean reverting: ln qte ln qˆte zt where (1) zt zt 1 nt , and (2) ln qˆte ln qˆte1 t . (3) In the above system equations, nt is i.i.d. N(0, σ2) and t is i.i.d. N 0, 2 ; nt and t are also independent of one another. Substituting (1) into (2) yields ln qte ln qˆte zt 1 nt . If we note that ln qte (4) ln qˆte ln qˆte and ln qˆte , expression (4) can be rewritten as 1 1 1 1 ln qˆte ln qˆte zt 1 nt . 1 1 1 1 Accordingly, ln qte can be reviewed as mean reverting around (5) ln qˆte . Spierdijk and 1 1 Bikker (2012) parameterized this model as follows (means and standard deviations being measured in terms of monthly returns): .9%, .975, 3.2%, 3.2% , these latter two values yielding a monthly standard deviation of 4.5%, the average for the U.S. aggregate stock market index from 1.1.1982 through 8.31.2010. For the bond return they assume Erb = .7% and 4 ds where E denotes the expectation conditional on all information, s t t t s t 1 1 r e In this setting, qˆt E available to the market in time period t, Ωt . 4 rb = 1.4% as reflecting the Citibank U.S. Overall Bond Investment Grade Total Return Index for the same historical period, with no mean reversion in bond returns. They further assume corr rte , rtb .2 , which is the historical contemporaneous correlation between the aforementioned stock and bond indices, and corr rte, t 1 , rtb, t 1 .18 , corr rte, t 5 , rtb, t 5 .17 , corr rte, t 10 , rtb, t 10 .17 , and corr rte, t 20 , rtb, t 20 .17 . Note that the two risky assets in this exercise are the equity market portfolio and a risky bond portfolio. With this information, the authors compute the mean and variance of the minimum risk portfolio and the mean variance efficient tangency portfolio for the indicated four investment horizons, as well as the associated portfolio proportions.5 In the latter case the assumed risk free rate is the average over the investment horizon from which the data was taken. The exercise was repeated for various variance ratios, where in their model, this quantity is defined by 2 2 for .975 , a ratio that signifies the relative risk contributions of the 2 / 2 2 permanent and transitory components, respectively. The results of this exercise are presented in Table 1 below (Table 1 of Spierdijk and Bikker (2012)). 5 Recalling the discussion in Chapter 6, the portfolios of interest are the ones presented below. 5 Table 1: Optimal Portfolio Weights (in Percentage) With and Without Mean Reversion in Stock Prices (1) This table reports the optimal portfolio weights for the global minimum variance portfolio (GMVP) and the tangency portfolio (TP). The investment categories are stocks (Datastream U.S. Aggregate Stock Market Index) and bonds (Citigroup U.S. Overall Bond Investment Grade Total Return Index) for different values of the variance ratio. The variance ratio is defined as the return variance of the permanent price component divided by the return variance of the transitory component. The risk-free rate is based on the nominal interest rate term structure as compiled by the Dutch Central Bank. The last two columns in each panel display the expected portfolio return p and the portfolio volatility p (1) Table 1 in Spierdijk and Bikker (2012). In the above table, the absence of mean reversion requires 0 , and the relevant comparison concerns a comparison of the like entry in the top and bottom halves of the table 6 (e.g., for a variance ratio of 1:1, and a time horizon of 20 years, we compare p 21.34% (a 20 year monthly standard deviation) versus p 21.47% ). A quick survey of the table suggests that for the indicated parameterizations neither portfolio returns and variances nor portfolio proportions are much affected by the presence or absence of mean reversion for this datamotivated parameterization. References Exley, J., Mehta, S., and Smith, A. (2004), “Mean Reversion,” Finance and Investment Conference, Brussels, mimeo. Fama, E., and French, K. (1988), “Dividend Yields and Expected Stock Returns,” Journal of Financial Economics, 22, 3-25. Kim, M., Nelson, C., and Startz, R. (1991), “Mean Reversion in Stock Prices? A Reappraisal of the Empirical Evidence,” Review of Economic Studies, 58, 515-528. Mayost, D (2012), “Evidence of Mean Reversion in Equity Prices,” OSFI-BSIF Canada mimeo. Mukherji, S. (2011), “Are Stock Returns Mean Reverting?”, Review of Financial Economics, 20, 22-27. Poterba, J., and Summers, L. (1988), “Mean Reversion in Stock Prices,” Journal of Financial Economics, 22, 27-59 Richardson, M. (1993), “Temporary Components of Stock Prices: A Skeptic’s View,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 11, 199-207. Spierdijk, L., and Bikker, J. (2012), “Mean Reversion in Stock Prices: Implications for LongTerm Investors,” De Nederlandsche Bank NV Working Paper #343. Summers, L. (1986), “Does the Stock Market Rationally Reflect Fundamental Values?”, The Journal of Finance, 41, 591-601. 7