* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Capital structure and volatility of risk
Investment management wikipedia , lookup
Securitization wikipedia , lookup
Debt settlement wikipedia , lookup
Debt collection wikipedia , lookup
Financialization wikipedia , lookup
Private equity secondary market wikipedia , lookup
Business valuation wikipedia , lookup
Private equity wikipedia , lookup
Debtors Anonymous wikipedia , lookup
First Report on the Public Credit wikipedia , lookup
Beta (finance) wikipedia , lookup
Private equity in the 2000s wikipedia , lookup
Systemic risk wikipedia , lookup
Household debt wikipedia , lookup
Early history of private equity wikipedia , lookup
Government debt wikipedia , lookup
Global saving glut wikipedia , lookup
Private equity in the 1980s wikipedia , lookup
Greeks (finance) wikipedia , lookup
Capital structure and volatility of risk ∗ Nikolay Halov UCSD Rady School of Management [email protected] Florian Heider European Central Bank [email protected] Kose John NYU Stern School of Business [email protected] Abstract In this paper we show that the volatility of risk is an important factor in explaining capital structure choices of firms. This effect is over and above the traditional determinants of capital structure such as the current level of risk, size, market-to-book ratio, tangibility of assets and profitability. We show that both (1) the fraction of debt in total new external financing raised by the firm, and (2) the long term debt as a fraction of the assets of the firm, are decreasing in the volatility of risk of the firm. Moreover this negative relationship is significantly stronger for firms that do not have a credit rating. These results are consistent with the theoretical reasons that we provide to explain the negative relationship between leverage and volatility of risk. PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Current Draft June, 2009 ∗ We thank Jennifer Carpenter, Stephen Figlewski, Allan Timmermann, Dalida Kadyrzhanova and Ross Valkanov for helpful comments and suggestions. Usual disclaimer applies. 0 Introduction It has been long recognized that volatility is not constant through time and could evolve stochastically through time. We also know that the dynamics of the underlying asset values would be an important factor in the pricing of debt claims of the firm. In this paper we examine the effect of the volatility of the firm cash flow variance on the leverage choices made by the firm. We hypothesize that the firm’s optimal leverage choices would be decreasing in the volatility of the firm cash flow variance, holding constant other determinants of its leverage such as its level of cash flow volatility, size, market-to-book ratio, tangibility of assets and profitability. Our hypothesis regarding the negative relationship between the volatility of the firm cash flow variance also extends to the leverage composition of any external financing undertaken by the firm. There are three arguments that form the basis of our hypothesized relationship. The first argument follows from a simple adaptation of the static trade-off theory in which the firm’s volatility is stochastic and the costs of adjusting leverage are large. Compare two firms with identical average cash flows, one with a known level of standard deviation of cash flows, say σ, and a second firm whose cash flow standard deviation is stochastic and drawn from a distribution with mean equal to σ and variance ε. Even though both firms have the same mean standard deviation of firm cash flows, the second firm would use less leverage optimally (according to its static trade-off optimization) if the net costs of debt are asymmetric in σ. 1 For example, a bankruptcy cost structure that is convex in the degree of default would give rise to optimal debt choices that are lower for the firm with stochastic volatility, and declining in ε (the volatility of volatility). To see this assume that debt related benefits are linear in the face value of debt, (Corporate tax shield could be argued to be approximately linear). If the volatility is higher than the expected value σ, say (σ + ε), the incremental expected bankruptcy costs would be larger than the savings in incremental bankruptcy costs from a volatility realization (σ – ε). This means that the optimal leverage trade-off for the stochastic volatility firm will occur at lower values than that for a firm with constant volatility of σ. Its leverage choices would be correspondingly conservative, i.e., the higher its ε, the lower the leverage chosen. Firms with asset types (e.g., intangible assets or firm-specific assets) that are associated with high bankruptcy costs are all the more prone to be conservative in their leverage choices in response to the volatility of their volatility. The sensitivity of leverage to its volatility of volatility would be increasing in the extent of intangible/specific assets in the firm’s balance sheet. Our reasoning here made use of the fact that large costs of adjustment of leverage in response to changing volatility lead firms to make conservative leverage choices based on the higher variance of the unconditional distribution for the firm with stochastic volatility. Similar results obtain even if the adjustment costs are smaller, but asymmetric, i.e., reducing leverage is more costly than increasing leverage (see for example van Binsbergen et al. (2008), Byoun (2008) and Flannery and Rangan (2003) for some evidence suggesting that such an asymmetry may exist). 2 A second reason for conservative leverage choices by firms with high volatility of volatility may be that corporate insiders may have private information regarding their own earnings volatility and this is more likely in firms with stochastic volatility. In firms where volatility is not stochastic the market can learn from history about firm volatility. On the other hand, in firms with high volatility of volatility, it is harder for the market to learn, and often the insiders have a better read on its current volatility. In such a setting of asymmetric information about firm volatility, there is a lemons problem in pricing debt claims and the firms are better off issuing equity securities. Issuing levered equity (with call option features) can be justified as a defensive measure or as a signal of low volatility. Here the volatility of volatility may serve as a proxy for the degree of asymmetric information that exists in the market regarding the variance of firm cash flows. (Volatility of volatility can serve as a proxy of the range of the support of the volatility distribution from the perspective of the less informed market). Interestingly, issuing debt serves as a defensive strategy to solve the lemons problem associated with issuing equity, when there is asymmetric information about the mean of the cash flows, issuing equity-like securities may be a solution when the lemons problem arises from asymmetric information about the volatility of firm cash flows (although not analyzed explicitly, this possibility is in fact discussed in Myers and Majluf (1984)). A third reason for conservative leverage choices by firms with high volatility of volatility may be to pre-commit not to risk-shift (switch into high variance, lower net-present-value projects) in the future. If the market believes that firms with a high volatility of volatility are also those with a large menu of risky projects that they can adopt after the external financing is in 3 place, it would be important to precommit not to do so by issuing levered equity or convertible debt to outsiders. As Green (1984) has shown, such mechanisms as a well-designed convertible, are optimal in that they reassure the market that the firm does not gain by adopting risk-shifting strategies with such securities outstanding. We argue that the firm would precommit not to riskshift by raising a larger component of their external finance as equity. Again the volatility of volatility of a firm may be a good proxy for the importance of making such a precommitment through conservative leverage choices. We construct two measures of volatility of volatility (VOV). First, we calculate the volatility of assets in the 12 preceding calendar months and then take the annual standard deviation of the monthly volatilities. This is our measure of volatility of realized volatility (VRV). Second we obtain daily series of volatilities implied from option prices for each day in the previous calendar year. The standard deviation of these IVs provides our second measure called volatility of implied volatility (VIV). All our results are implemented both of these measures of volatility of volatility. We rank firms in deciles according to our volatility of volatility measures (both VRV and VIV) and we find that the firms in the higher deciles issue monotonically smaller component of debt in their external financing. In this paper we show that the volatility of risk is an important factor in explaining capital structure choices of firms over and above the traditional determinants of capital structure such as the level of risk, size, market-to-book ratio, tangibility of assets and profitability. We show that the volatility of risk explains 1) the fraction of debt in total new external financing raised by the firm, 2) the long term debt as a fraction of the assets of the firm. 4 The organization of the paper is as follows. Section 1 develops our empirical strategy. Section 2 describes the sample and presents some descriptive statistics. Section 3 contains the main empirical results. Possible alternative explanations are analyzed in section 4. Section 5 provides a discussion on factors that affect volatility of volatility and its effect on capital structure. Section 6 concludes. 1. Empirical strategy Our empirical strategy builds upon the tests of the standard pecking order by ShyamSunder and Myers (1999) and Frank and Goyal (2003) and the vast empirical literature testing trade-off models of capital structure (see among others Rajan and Zingales (1995)). Focusing on cash-flows Shyam-Sunder and Myers (1999) propose a test of the original pecking order based on how firms finance their need for external capital. The starting point is the following accounting identity of cash flows: DEF = I + DIV + ∆W-C = ∆D + ∆E (1) A firm’s financing deficit DEF, i.e. the difference between uses of funds (dividends DIV, investment I and changes in net working capital ∆W) and internal sources of funds (the internal cash-flow C), must be balanced by external sources of funds, i.e. either the issuance of debt ∆D 5 or equity ∆E (we follow the definitions of Frank and Goyal (2003); see also Helwege and Liang (1996), Shyam-Sunder and Myers (1999), and Chang and Dasgupta (2003)). Shyam-Sunder and Myers (1999) and Frank and Goyal (2003) are interested in the proportion of debt relative to equity that is issued to finance the deficit. They want to test whether the standard pecking order holds in which debt dominates equity, i.e. DEF = ∆D, and therefore run the following pooled panel regression: ∆D it = a + bDEF + ε it (2) Debt dominates equity issuance fully if b is large as b, roughly speaking, represents the average proportion of debt in total external financing. Moreover, a close to zero indicates that there are no other factors unrelated to the financing needs of a company that drive debt issuance. We employ (2) conditionally by ranking firms into deciles, n =1, 2…10, according to measures of volatility of volatility (we discuss these measures in the next section), and then run regression (2) separately in each decile n: ∆D = a + b D DEF + ε it n n it (3) We expect the estimated coefficients on the financing deficit to be ranked monotonically: ) ) ) b D > b D > ... > b D . Firms in higher volatility of volatility deciles issue more equity and less 1 2 10 debt to finance their deficit. In addition to (3), we also test the extent to which equity is issued to finance the deficit in each decile n: 6 ∆E it = a + b E DEF + ε n n it (4) Since (1) is an accounting identity, checking that the estimated coefficients on the deficit from ) ) (3) and (4) add up to one in each decile, b D + b E = 1 for all n, is a useful test of the accuracy of n n our cash-flow data. Measures of the level of recent asset volatility We construct two measures of asset volatility. The first one consists of unlevering the volatility of equity. Unlevering is needed since the volatility of equity mechanically increases with leverage ceteris paribus. We compute the standard deviation of the daily return on the market value of a firm. The market value of assets is defined as in Fama and French (2002) (see also the Appendix).1 If there are less than 90 days of stock price data, the firm/year observation is deleted from the sample. The second measure recognizes that equity is a call option on the value of firm assets with the exercise price being the value of the debt (Merton (1974)). From Ito’s lemma, we have σ where σ E E =σ V ∂E t t V E ∂V t t (5) is the instantaneous variance of the rate of return on equity (the standard deviation of daily stock returns from CRSP), σ V is the instantaneous variance of the rate of return on the 1 We also try the definition of Baker and Wurgler (2001), which excludes convertible debt, and also try using just total liabilities. The results are not affected. 7 firm (to be solved for), Vt is the market value of the firm and Et is the market value of equity (both calculated as above).2 The derivative of the market value of equity with respect to the market value of the firm in the Merton model is: 1 ln (V /B ) + (r + σ 2 )T t t f 2 V t =Φ ∂V σV T t ∂E (6) where Φ is the cumulative distribution function of the standardized normal distribution )(0,1), T is the time to maturity of the debt (we try both 10 and 20 years) and rf is the risk free rate (from Kenneth French’s website). The Spearman rank correlation between the two measures of asset risk in our sample is 0.95. The rank correlation is the appropriate measure since we use asset risk only to rank firms into deciles. Given that both measures give virtually identical rankings, we continue using the simpler first measure (see also Welch (2004); and Jones et al. (1984) for a comparison of these two measures of asset volatility). To ensure that there is no contemporaneous interplay between the issue decision and asset volatility, we use last year’s asset volatility. Using longer lags would weaken the link between the role of risk in the adverse selection problem and the current capital structure decision.3 2 An advantage of the Merton method is that we can use the CRSP return series that is adjusted for stock splits and dividends. 3 There is an issue concerning the overlap or gap between the calendar year used for stock price data and the fiscal year used for financial data. This overlap or gap exists for 48% of all firms. We check the robustness of our results by using only firms whose fiscal year is the calendar year. The results are unchanged. 8 Measures of the volatility of volatility (VOV): VRV and VIV We construct two proxies for the volatility of volatility of each firm. One is based on expectations of outsiders about the future volatility of the firm as shown in the prices of the stock options of the firm and the second is based on the recent variation of realized asset volatility of the firm. For our first proxy we calculate the variation in firm specific implied volatility form option prices (VIV). We use end-of-day option prices, option open interest and implied volatility estimates from the Ivy DB database provided by OptionMetrics. The sample is from January 1996 to December 2001. To filter out misrecorded data and very illiquid contracts, we exclude days/contracts that have zero open interest or have a bid-ask spread larger than 50% of the option price at midpoint. To alleviate potential endogeneity problems we use data from the previous calendar year. The sample includes at-the-money call options with maturity closest to but higher than 182 days. Ideally, we would use longer maturity contracts, e.g. LEAPS, to include the whole year during which we study the financing decision and get closer to longer investment horizon of outsiders but these contracts are quite illiquid so that our sample would be considerably reduced. Our raw option data sample has 13,418,700 day-firm implied volatility estimates. Following Welch (2004) we unlever these equity volatility estimates by scaling by Et/(Et+Dt), where Et is the market value of firms equity as of the end of the fiscal year and Dt is the book value of debt. We then calculated the standard deviation of these implied asset 9 volatilities for each firm over the previous calendar year. If there are less than 90 trading days the firm-year is excluded from the sample. This measure has several advantages. It is a forward looking measure; it does not suffer from problems common to accounting variables and it represent all information available to outside investors that concerns the volatility of the firm. It does however reduce our sample significantly as cross sectional option pricing data is available only from 1996 to 2001. Second we look at the volatility of realized asset volatility (VRV). In particular we calculate the equity volatility of the firm in each month of the previous calendar year, unlever it to account for the capital structure of the firm in that year by scaling by Et/(Et+Dt), where Et is the market value of firms equity as of the end of the fiscal year and Dt is the book value of debt, and use the standard deviation of the monthly volatility estimates as another proxy for volatility of volatility that we argue is positively related to asymmetric information about risk. Controlling for other determinants of debt issuance The empirical methodology employed in (1)-(4) using cash-flow data and examines the extent of debt issuance. Alternatively, one can examine the level of debt using balance and income sheet data. This second approach is found mostly in cross -sectional empirical research on capital structure that is usually rooted in the trade-off theory. The basic trade-off theory states that the level of leverage is determined by trading off the tax benefit of debt against the cost of financial distress (see for example the account given by Myers (1984)). Hence, firms with a high present value of tax benefits and/or a low present value of distress costs should have higher 10 levels of debt (see also the classification in the survey by Harris and Raviv (1991)). Rajan and Zingales (1995) narrow the list of conventional determinants down to four main variables: profits, size, tangibility of assets and the market-to-book ratio. More tangible assets support debt because it means that firms can collateralize the debt which reduces bankruptcy costs. The market-to-book ratio is usually seen as a proxy for growth opportunities that should be negatively related to leverage. The argument is that leverage exposes firms to the “debt overhang” problem (Myers 1977). A recent alternative explanation for a negative relationship is market timing. Firms with a high market-to-book ratio are overvalued and hence issue equity to take advantage of it (Baker and Wurgler (2001)). Sales are usually positively associated with leverage. There is no clear theoretical foundation but one normally argues that larger firms have a higher reputation or are safer so they can borrow more. Profits show up regularly as a negative determinant of leverage. Traditionally this has been seen as the strongest empirical challenge for conventional trade-off models of leverage. They predict that more profitable firms should issue more debt since more profitable firms have a smaller risk of bankruptcy and have more taxable income to shield (see Titman and Wessels (1988) and Fama and French (2002)). We follow Faulkender and Petersen (2004) among others and add interaction terms of the financing deficit with the conventional determinants to (3). This allows a nesting of the conventional determinants of leverage from the trade-off theory within a framework to examine debt issuance. The set of decile regressions (3) then becomes (where LoV is the level of risk): 11 ∆D = a + b DEF + bVoV DEF *VoV + b LoV DEF * LoV + bTA)G DEF * TA)G it n n it n it it − 1 n it it − 1 n it it + b MTB DEF * MTB + b PROF DEF * PROF + b LOGSALES DEF * LOGSALES n it it n it it n it it + CO)TROLS + ε (7) We expect a negative sign on the coefficient of interaction term of financing deficit with our volatility of volatility (VOV) measures once we add the conventional determinants of leverage. Following the vast empirical literature we also model empirically the level of leverage as measured by the long term debt of the firm scaled by its total book assets. In particular we run the following specification: D = a + bVoV VoV + b LoV LoV + bTA)GTA)G + b MTB MTB it − 1 n it − 1 it n n it − 1 n it − 1 n PROF LOGSALES +b PROF +b LOGSALES + CO)TROLS + ε n it − 1 n it − 1 (8) 2. Data Sample construction We study a large, unbalanced panel of all firms from the merged CRSP-Compustat (CCM) database from 1971 to 2001. Our sample only starts in 1971 since we require cash flow data. We make the following standard adjustments. We exclude financial firms (SIC codes 60006999), regulated utilities (SIC codes 4900-4999), and firms involved in major mergers and acquisitions (Compustat footnote code AB). Furthermore, we exclude firm/year observations that report cash flows data using format code (item 318) 4 or 6 (both undefined by Compustat) and 5 (for the Canadian file) or if the format code is missing. 12 To be able to link Compustat reliably to CRSP data we use only records with link type ‘LC', 'LN', 'LO', 'LS', 'LU' or ’LX’. A small number of CRSP securities that link into more than one Compustat firm have also been deleted. In order to remove outliers and misrecorded data, we remove observations for certain variables that have missing values or are in the extreme 0.5 % left or right tail of the distribution (see the Appendix for the list of variables that have been treated this way). To ensure that the sample does not contain equity issues due to IPOs, we exclude observations for the year in which a firm’s stock price becomes first available in the CRSP database. The maximum number of observations in our sample then is 103,351 firm-years. Descriptive statistics Table 1 shows balance sheets, cash flows and other descriptive statistics at the beginning and at the end of our sample period, 1971 and 2001, as well as for two intermediate dates, 1980 and 1990. Panel A presents average balance sheets and panel B shows the average of the cash flows in the accounting identity (1). The central observation is that equity plays an important role in financing the deficit. It contradicts the argument that most external financing uses debt (see also Frank and Goyal (2003)).4 Note also the difference between the mean and the median of net debt and equity issues. The median is zero for both. A typical firm appears to stay out of the market for external finance 4 The table confirms that dividends are a disappearing use of corporate cash flows (see Fama and French (2001) and also Baker and Wurgler (2003)). A comparison of the average and the median dividend indicates that typical firms stop paying dividends and that those who continue paying them, nevertheless reduce the amount paid. 13 most of the time, but if it does seek external finance, the magnitude of the market intervention is large relative to firm size. Table 2, Panel A.1 gives the summary statics for the level of volatility (risk) and for the volatility of realized volatility (VRV). Panel A.2 shows that there is positive and moderate correlation between the level of risk and VRV. Riskier firms also tend to experience more changes in risk. Panels B.1 and B.2 show summary statistics for the volatility of implied volatility (VIV). 3. Main empirical result The central results of the paper relate the capital structure of a firm to the volatility of volatility (realized or implied). We find that in the lowest decile based on VRV a one standard deviation change in the financing deficit from the mean produces 0.871 standard deviations change in the net debt issued. In the highest decile based on VRV, one standard deviation change of the financing deficit from its mean produces 0.153 standard deviations change in the net debt issues. At an intuitive level the debt component in the external financing raised is roughly 87% in the lowest decile of VRV and it is roughly 15 % in the highest decile. Using VIV measure the ratio of the debt component in external financing goes from 85.7% in the lowest decile to 17.7% in the highest decile. Therefore volatility of volatility is an important determinant of the debtequity mix of new external financing. Table 3 and 4 report results from specification (3) using VIV and VRV. 14 Alternatively, looking at leverage as measured by the proportion of long term debt in total assets we find that the leverage ratio is 31.7% in the lowest decile of VRV (31.7% when using VIV), monotonically decreases as VOV increases, reaching a value of 9.5% (10.4 using VIV) in the highest decile of VRV. Based on these univariate results VOV seems to be an important determinant of leverage ratio. To examine further the determinants of leverage, we use a multivariate regression that included VOV as well as the traditional determinants such as size tangibility market-to-bookratio and profitability. In this regression we want to ensure that VOV is not proxing for the role of asset volatility in determining the leverage ratio. Therefore we include level of asset volatility as an additional control variable. In the following discussion we examine the role of these variables in determining as before the debt component of external financing as well as leverage. Based on the multivariate regression we find that the relation between the debt component in external financing and VOV (both VRV and VIV measures) is negative and significant. This relation holds even after we introduce the level of asset volatility as an additional control variable. We find that the debt component in external financing is negatively related to both the VOV and the level of asset volatility. In fact the VOV continues to be at least as significant the level of asset volatility. Even when introduce as control variables the usual capital structure determinants, the significance of VOV continues to hold. These results suggest that VOV is an important determinant of capital structure in addition to the previously known determinants of capital structure. Results from empirical model (8) are in Table 5 and 6. 15 Next we explore how this negative relation between volatility of volatility and debt as a proportion of external financing varies with the existence of a credit rating. 4. Reasons why the cost of debt financing to the firms is increasing in the volatility of risk of its assets. (Motivation and hypotheses) In this section, we explore the theoretical reasons why (1) the optimal leverage choice of firms should be negatively related to its volatility of volatility (in addition to its current level of volatility, and (2) the optimal debt component in any new external financing undertaken would be negatively related to its volatility of volatility (in addition to its current level of volatility).We provide three different frameworks in which such a relationship may obtain. The first framework is that of symmetric information static trade-off reasoning that is augmented to allow for stochastic volatility and some nonlinear cost of bankruptcy or adjustment costs of changing leverage. The second framework is that of asymmetric information in which the corporate insiders are better informed about the volatility of the firm compared to the market and they face a lemons cost of issuing debt securities. A third framework is that of private action regarding risk-choices in which issuing debt securities would give rise to severe risk-shifting incentives for firms with high volatility of volatility. All of the three frameworks yield the results (1) and (2) mentioned above. First take the case of a firm with stochastic volatility, where the volatility is drawn from a distribution with mean σ and variance ε. (Volatility is the standard deviation of the cash flow realizations of the firm). Compare it to a firm of constant volatility σ. Also assume that the costs of changing leverage are very high. If the net debt related costs are convex in σ, it can be shown 16 that the firm with stochastic volatility would make optimal choices of leverage that are lower than that of the firm with constant volatility, and the leverage would be decreasing in ε. For example, if the costs of reducing long term debt are higher than taking on additional debt, a stochastic volatility firm would take on lower levels of debt defensively given the asymmetric structure of adjustment costs. (see for example van Binsbergen et al. (2008), Byoun (2008) and Flannery and Rangan (2003) for some evidence suggesting that such an asymmetry may exist). A bankruptcy cost structure that are convex in the degree of default would also give rise to optimal debt choices that are lower for the firm with stochastic volatility, and declining in ε (the volatility of volatility). To see this assume that debt related benefits are linear in the face value of debt, (Corporate tax shield could be argued to be approximately linear). If the volatility is higher than the expected value σ, say (σ + ε), the incremental expected bankruptcy costs would be larger than the savings in incremental bankruptcy costs from a volatility realization (σ – ε). This means that the optimal leverage trade-off for the stochastic volatility firm will occur at lower values than that for a firm with constant volatility of σ.5 Moreover, the optimal leverage of such a firm would be declining in its volatility of volatility, ε. Another framework in which the volatility of volatility may affect the optimal leverage choices (and that of optimal debt component in external financing) is one in which the corporate insiders have private information about the current volatility of the firm. The informational 5 More generally it is true that if volatility of volatility contributes to the deadweight cost born by the firm, the tradeoff with debt related benefits is going to yield an optimum that can be mapped back to a simpler model where the volatility of the cash flows is a higher number. However in general this inverse mapping may be complex. 17 advantage of the insiders may be larger with a higher ε. A firm with private information about risk suffers a lemons problem in issuing debt securities. For such a firm, issuing levered equity or convertible securities with embedded options may be an optimal strategy either to get around the lemons costs or the right security to issue in the signaling equilibrium. The cost of placing equity securities with outsiders is lower for a firm whose true volatility is lower. In the separating equilibrium, the gains from tilting towards equity would be increasing in the degree of asymmetric information, proxied here by ε, the volatility of volatility. ε can be thought of as the range of the support of the private information attribute σ in the market. A third frameworks in which firms with high volatility of volatility tilt away from high leverage would be one of moral hazard in which leverage induces risk-shifting incentives. If firms with stochastic volatility are plausibly less able to contractually precommit to specific levels of volatility, debt holders would anticipate higher levels of risk-shifting from these firms and incorporate that in the pricing of debt securities issued by these firms. These firms therefore would optimally go for lower leverage or issue equity or convertible debt (with embedded options). As Green (1984) showed, precommitting not to risk-shift through well-designed optionembedded securities would be optimal for these firms. Again, higher the ε, the volatility of volatility of a firm, higher the importance of making such a precommitment through conservative leverage choices. 5. Discussion 5.1. Factors that ameliorate or accentuate the effect of volatility of volatility 18 Depending on which one of the explanations drive our empirical results, the effect of volatility of risk on capital structure may be weakened or strengthened by certain firm characteristics. If volatility of risk captures the asymmetry of information about risk between corporate insiders and creditors, it is possible that the following factors ameliorate the effects of volatility of volatility. As the creditor becomes more and more familiar with the operations of the borrowing firm it is possible that the volatility of volatility becomes less important. Some examples would be 1) the availability of a credit rating for the firm, 2) The number of analysts following the firm 3) the age of the firm 4) Longer banking relationship the borrower and the creditor. 5.2. Factors that affect volatility of volatility Income smoothing by managers can possibly affect volatility of volatility. What are some of the ways that managers volatility of volatility. For example if managers pursue different degrees of income smoothing they might increase the volatility of volatility of reported income even though the volatility of volatility of the underlying operations of the firm may not have changed. Another example is pursuing different risk management policies. Here the volatility of volatility of overall profits might increase even though the volatility of volatility of the operating profits may be smaller. One scenario consistent with such changes in income smoothing or risk management procedures could come from a turnover of CEOs/CFOs. A more fundamental reason for changing volatility may be changes in the product line, changes in the technology of operations, changes in the degree of competitiveness in the 19 industry. Empirically it is possible that changes in the degree of concentration in the industry would be related to volatility of volatility. Consider a firm whose volatility currently is low and its volatility of volatility is also low. The firm is switching its operations into an activity with higher volatility as well as volatility of volatility. Doing aggressive income smoothing may enable the firm to maintain a low volatility of volatility for an additional time period. However, it is possible that volatility of volatility is more difficult to manipulate than simple cash flows or level of volatility. The objective of this paper will be 1) to provide examples of changes in volatility and 2) possibly to argue that volatility of volatility is probably less directly subject to manipulation by mangers than level of volatility. Volatility of risk could lead to higher bankruptcy cost, especially for long term debt issues. 6. Conclusion In addition to volatility of the assets (risk), the variability of risk is an important determinant of capital structure. In this paper we show that the volatility of risk is an important factor in explaining capital structure choices of firms over and above the traditional determinants of capital structure such as the level of risk, size, market-to-book ratio, tangibility of assets and profitability. We show that the volatility of risk explains 1) the fraction of debt in total new external financing raised by the firm, 2) the long term debt as a fraction of the assets of the firm. 20 Table 1: Balance sheets, cash flows and other descriptive statistics over time The table reports average balance sheets for the sample. Financial firms, utilities and companies that could not be matched properly with CRSP are excluded. Unless labeled as median, each item in Panel A and Panel B is calculated as a percentage of the book value of total assets and then averaged across all firms of our sample in that year. Definitions of variables follow Frank and Goyal (2003) and Fama and French (2002). See text and Appendix 2 for details. Year Number of observations Panel A: Balance sheet items Assets: +Cash (#162) +Short term investments (#193) +Receivables-total (#2) +Inventories (#3) +Current assets-other (#68) +Current assets-total (#4) +Net property plant and equipment (#8) +Investments and advances - equity method (#31) +Investments and advances - other (#32) +Intangibles (#33) +Assets - other (#69) =Total assets (#6) Liabilities +Debt in current liabilities (#34) +Account payable (#70) +Income taxes payable (#71) +Current liabilities - other (#72) =Current liabilities - total (#5) +Long-term debt - total (#9) +Liabilities - other (#75) +Deferred taxes and ITC (#35) +Minority interest (#38) =Liabilities - total (#181) +Preferred stock - carrying value (#130) +Common equity - total (#60) =Stockholders' equity total (#216)=(#130)+(#60) =Total liabilities and stockholders' equity Panel B: Corporate cash flows +Cash Dividends (#127) +Change in net working capital -Internal cash flow +Investments =Financial deficit (Mean) Financial deficit (Median) Net debt issues (#111-#114) Mean 1971 1518 1980 2925 1990 3481 2001 3810 0.040 0.035 0.194 0.247 0.014 0.539 0.356 0.030 0.045 0.217 0.245 0.020 0.575 0.349 0.085 0.031 0.205 0.186 0.029 0.544 0.320 0.127 0.056 0.154 0.126 0.037 0.501 0.276 0.020 0.025 0.036 0.024 1.000 0.014 0.026 0.020 0.023 1.000 0.010 0.025 0.049 0.054 1.000 0.010 0.020 0.128 0.064 1.000 0.068 0.090 0.020 0.061 0.239 0.199 0.012 0.020 0.005 0.476 0.011 0.513 0.066 0.114 0.018 0.087 0.286 0.200 0.015 0.026 0.003 0.529 0.009 0.461 0.094 0.111 0.008 0.097 0.312 0.192 0.034 0.020 0.006 0.564 0.015 0.422 0.063 0.086 0.006 0.118 0.274 0.184 0.045 0.016 0.005 0.524 0.021 0.456 0.524 0.471 0.437 0.476 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 0.018 0.022 0.099 0.082 0.023 0.001 0.012 0.015 0.024 0.106 0.102 0.034 0.003 0.017 0.009 -0.011 0.044 0.071 0.025 -0.001 0.004 0.005 -0.022 0.000 0.058 0.041 0.002 0.001 21 Net debt issues (Median) Net equity issues (#108-#115) (Mean) Net equity issues (Median) Panel C: Other descriptive statistics Age (years since first appearance CRSP) Market value of assets (in millions dollars) Book value of assets (#6) (in millions dollars) Tangibility (#8/#6) Log sales (log(#12)) Market-to-book ratio Profitability=Operating income(#13) Assets(/#6) 0.000 0.011 0.000 0.000 0.017 0.000 -0.001 0.021 0.000 0.000 0.040 0.001 7 11 12 13 503.233 464.232 966.102 2943.950 436.892 0.356 4.73 1.52 514.434 0.349 4.74 1.40 858.079 0.320 4.45 1.54 1550.136 0.276 5.25 1.90 0.128 0.144 0.065 0.014 in of of / 22 Table 2: Measures of volatility and volatility of volatility This table reports descriptive statistics and correlation matrix of the alternative measures of risk and volatility of risk. The monthly standard deviation of asset volatility is the standard deviation of the 12 monthly asset volatility estimates from the previous calendar year. All correlation coefficients are significant at the 1% level. Panel A. 1971-2001 A1. Descriptive statistics Variable Std. dev. of monthly asset volatility Level of asset volatility Number of observations 101291 103210 Mean 0.007 0.022 Std. Dev. Of Monthly Asset Vol 1.000 0.246 Level of Asset Vol 0.246 1.000 Number of observations 5758 5787 5777 Mean 0.009 0.028 0.045 Std Dev 0.007 0.021 0.042 Std. Dev. Of Monthly Asset Vol 1.000 0.593 0.423 Level of Asset Vol 0.593 1.000 0.504 Std Dev of Implied Vol 0.423 0.504 1.000 Std Dev 0.009 0.043 A2. Correlation matrix Std. dev. of monthly asset volatility Level of asset volatility Panel B. Option data, 1996-2001 B1. Descriptive statistics Variable Std. dev. of monthly asset volatility Level of Asset Volatility Std dev of implied volatility B2. Correlation matrix Std. dev. of monthly asset volatility Level of asset volatility Std. dev of implied volatility 23 0.828 579 0.857 0.016 0.541 0.759 Adjusted R squared Number of observations Financial deficit 0.117 579 0.143 0.016 0.299 578 0.269 0.017 0.463 579 0.461 0.021 3 -0.014 0.002 579 0.539 0.021 3 0.014 0.002 578 0.731 0.017 Panel B: Dependent variable - net equity issued Decile 1 (Low) 2 Intercept -0.010 -0.014 0.002 0.002 Adjusted R squared Number of observations Financial deficit Panel A: Dependent variable - )et debt issued Decile 1 (Low) 2 Intercept 0.010 0.014 0.002 0.002 0.325 578 0.312 0.019 4 -0.008 0.002 0.702 578 0.688 0.019 4 0.008 0.002 24 0.482 575 0.471 0.020 5 -0.007 0.003 0.538 575 0.528 0.020 5 0.007 0.003 0.400 579 0.425 0.022 6 -0.001 0.003 0.548 579 0.574 0.022 6 0.001 0.003 0.585 578 0.605 0.021 7 0.002 0.003 0.376 578 0.395 0.021 7 -0.002 0.003 0.631 579 0.644 0.021 8 0.002 0.004 0.342 579 0.355 0.021 8 -0.002 0.004 0.185 574 0.177 0.016 0.752 578 0.735 0.018 0.831 574 0.823 0.016 9 10 (High) 0.003 0.007 0.004 0.004 0.281 578 0.265 0.018 9 10 (High) -0.003 -0.007 0.004 0.004 , ∆Eit = a + bnE DEFit + ε it . Ranking based on the daily standard deviation of the implied volatility of the long term stock options of the firm during the previous calendar year. Firms with rank 10 have highest standard deviation. Standard errors are reported below the coefficients, in italics. All coefficients on financial deficit are significant at the 1 % level. ∆Dit = a + bnD DEFit + ε it Pooled panel OLS regressions of net debt issues ∆D and net equity issues ∆E on the financing deficit DEF are estimated for each decile n=1,…10: Table 3: Financing the deficit across deciles of volatility of volatility (implied volatility) Figure 1: Financing the deficit across deciles of volatility of volatility (implied volatility) Pooled panel OLS regressions of net debt issues ∆D and net equity issues ∆E on the financing deficit DEF are estimated for each decile n=1,…10: ∆Dit = a + bnD DEFit + ε it , ∆Eit = a + bnE DEFit + ε it . Ranking based on the daily standard deviation of the implied volatility of the long term stock options of the firm during the previous calendar year. The figure plots coefficients on financial deficit and adjusted R-squared for each decile. Net equity issued: coefficient on financing deficit Net equity issued: adjusted R-squared Net debt issued: coefficient on financing deficit Net debt issued: adjusted R-squared 0.900 0.800 0.700 0.600 0.500 0.400 0.300 0.200 0.100 0.000 Std. Dev. of Implied Volatility 25 0.876 Adjusted R squared 0.825 10125 0.825 0.004 10141 0.131 Adjusted R squared 0.126 0.003 Number of observations Financial deficit 10131 0.177 0.174 0.183 0.004 3 0.000 0.000 0.809 10132 0.814 0.004 3 0.000 0.000 10124 0.174 0.004 Panel B: Dependent variable - net equity issued Decile 1 (Low) 2 Intercept 0.000 -0.002 0.000 0.000 10142 0.871 0.003 Number of observations Financial deficit Panel A: Dependent variable - net debt issued Decile 1 (Low) 2 Intercept -0.001 0.002 0.000 0.000 E 0.241 10128 0.247 0.004 4 0.000 0.001 0.744 10129 0.751 0.004 4 0.000 0.001 26 0.313 10120 0.332 0.005 5 0.003 0.001 0.649 10122 0.668 0.005 5 -0.003 0.001 0.444 10134 0.467 0.005 6 0.004 0.001 0.508 10134 0.532 0.005 6 -0.004 0.001 0.599 10128 0.615 0.005 7 0.006 0.001 0.369 10130 0.385 0.005 7 -0.006 0.001 0.686 10130 0.709 0.005 8 0.007 0.001 0.269 10130 0.290 0.005 8 -0.007 0.001 0.139 10113 0.153 0.004 0.771 10124 0.782 0.004 0.833 10112 0.847 0.004 9 10 (High) 0.009 0.014 0.001 0.001 0.206 10126 0.217 0.004 9 10 (High) -0.009 -0.014 0.001 0.001 , ∆Eit = a + bn DEFit + ε it . Ranking based on the annual standard deviation of the monthly standard deviations of the stock returns during the 12 months of the previous calendar year. Firms with rank 10 have highest standard deviation. Standard errors are reported below the coefficients, in italics. All coefficients on financial deficit are significant at the 1 % level. ∆Dit = a + bnD DEFit + ε it Pooled panel OLS regressions of net debt issues ∆D and net equity issues ∆E on the financing deficit DEF are estimated for each decile n=1,…10: Table 4: Financing the deficit across deciles of volatility of volatility (realized monthly volatility) Figure 2: Financing the deficit across deciles of volatility of volatility (realized monthly volatility) Pooled panel OLS regressions of net debt issues ∆D and net equity issues ∆E on the financing deficit DEF are estimated for each decile n=1,…10: ∆Dit = a + bnD DEFit + ε it , ∆Eit = a + bnE DEFit + ε it . Ranking based on the annual standard deviation of the monthly standard deviations of the stock returns during the 12 months of the previous calendar year. The figure plots coefficients on financial deficit and adjusted R-squared for each decile. Net equity issued: coefficient on financing deficit Net equity issued: adjusted R - squared Net debt issued: coefficient on financing deficit Net debt issued: adjusted R-squared 1.000 0.900 0.800 0.700 0.600 0.500 0.400 0.300 0.200 0.100 0.000 1 (Low) 2 3 4 5 6 7 Std. Dev. of Monthly Volatility 27 8 9 10(High) Table 5: Relation between net debt issued and standard deviation of monthly realized volatility The table reports estimates from pooled panel regressions of net debt issued on financing deficit, the standard deviation of monthly realized asset volatility, level of realized asset volatility and conventional leverage variables. Pooled OLS standard errors reported under the coefficients in italics. Intercept 0.000 -0.003 -0.010 0.000 0.000 0.001 Financing deficit(DEF) DEF*(St. dev. of monthly asset volatility) 0.522 0.002 0.614 0.002 0.331 0.004 -9.519 0.101 -6.551 0.106 -2.426 0.101 -3.441 0.045 -1.263 0.044 DEF*level of asset volatiltity DEF*Log(Sales) 0.047 0.001 DEF*Tangibility 0.429 0.006 DEF*Market-to-book ratio -0.015 0.000 DEF*Profitability 0.071 0.003 St. dev of monthly asset volatility -0.528 0.027 Level of asset volatility -0.804 0.027 -0.358 0.027 0.235 0.006 0.106 0.006 Log(Sales) 0.002 0.000 Tangibility -0.006 0.001 Market-to-book ratio -0.003 0.000 Profitability 0.02037 0.0013 Adjusted R-squared 0.4294 0.461 0.5788 Number of observations 101283 101283 100676 28 Table 6: Relation between net debt issued and standard deviation of implied volatility The table reports estimates from pooled panel regressions of net debt issued on financing deficit, the standard deviation of implied volatility of long term stock options of the firm, level of realized asset volatility and conventional leverage variables. Pooled OLS standard errors reported under the coefficients in italics. Intercept 0.011 0.001 0.011 0.002 -0.016 0.006 Financing deficit(DEF) 0.574 0.009 0.707 0.012 0.215 0.028 -2.518 0.099 -1.641 0.110 -0.543 0.111 -4.601 0.270 -1.768 0.285 DEF*(St. dev. of implied volatility) DEF*Level of asset volatiltity DEF*Log(Sales) 0.060 0.003 DEF*Tangibility 0.287 0.030 DEF*Market-to-book ratio -0.001 0.002 DEF*Profitability 0.005 0.014 St.dev of implied volatility -0.158 0.023 Level of asset volatility -0.143 0.026 -0.087 0.025 -0.020 0.056 0.012 0.062 Log(Sales) 0.004 0.001 Tangibility -0.002 0.004 Market-to-book ratio -0.001 0.000 Profitability 0.020 0.006 Adjusted R-squared 0.456 0.488 0.566 Number of observations 5777 5777 5726 29 0.126 0.004 0.109 Financial deficit Adjusted R squared 1 (Low) 0.004 0.000 0.849 Adjusted R squared Decile Intercept 0.868 0.004 1 (Low) -0.004 0.000 Financial deficit Decile Intercept E 0.157 0.175 0.004 2 0.001 0.000 0.802 0.822 0.004 2 -0.001 0.000 0.457 0.005 0.326 0.005 0.173 0.192 0.004 0.203 0.235 0.005 30 0.251 0.291 0.005 0.402 0.430 0.005 0.504 0.542 0.005 0.638 0.673 0.005 8 0.003 0.001 0.542 0.570 0.005 Panel B: Dependent variable - )et equity issued 3 4 5 6 7 0.001 0.001 0.003 0.004 0.005 0.000 0.000 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.665 0.708 0.005 0.293 0.728 0.764 0.005 8 -0.003 0.001 0.419 0.787 0.807 0.004 Panel A: Dependent variable - )et debt issued 3 4 5 6 7 -0.001 -0.001 -0.003 -0.004 -0.005 0.000 0.000 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.747 0.770 0.004 9 0.003 0.001 0.209 0.230 0.004 9 -0.002 0.001 0.832 0.853 0.004 10 (High) 0.001 0.001 0.129 0.147 0.004 10 (High) -0.001 0.001 , ∆Eit = a + bn DEFit + ε it . Ranking based on the daily standard deviation of the return on market value of assets during the previous calendar year. Firms with rank 10 have highest standard deviation. Standard errors are reported below the coefficients, in italics. All coefficients on financial deficit are significant at the 1 % level. ∆Dit = a + bnD DEFit + ε it Pooled panel OLS regressions of net debt issues ∆D and net equity issues ∆E on the financing deficit DEF are estimated for each decile n=1,…10: Table 7: Financing the deficit across deciles based on the level of asset volatility 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Asset volatility decile 31 Net equity issued: adj. Rsquared Net equity issued: coefficient on financial deficit Net debt issued: adj. R-squared 0.6 0.5 Net debt issued: coefficient on financial deficit 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 Pooled panel OLS regressions of net debt issues ∆D and net equity issues ∆E on the financing deficit DEF are estimated for each decile n=1,…10: ∆Dit = a + bnD DEFit + ε it , ∆Eit = a + bnE DEFit + ε it .The figure plots coefficients on financial deficit and adjusted R-squared for each decile. Figure 3: Financing the deficit across deciles based on the level of asset volatility 0.31654 10143 0.31717 579 VRV VIV Ranking variable 1(low VOV) 0.28507 578 0.26898 10126 2 0.26254 579 0.23777 10132 3 4 0.23835 578 0.21566 10129 Decile 32 0.20408 575 0.19148 10122 5 Table 8: Leverage (long term debt scaled by total assets) by decile of VOV 0.19479 579 0.1682 10136 6 0.1556 578 0.14614 10130 7 0.14931 579 0.12735 10131 8 0.12062 578 0.11269 10127 9 0.10429 574 0.09527 10115 10(High VOV) Table 9: Multivariate relation between the level of leverage VOV and control variables Panel OLS regression, t-stats in parentheses Variable VRV Book leverage -3.452 (-50.517) VIV Level of vol. Log(Sales) Tangibility Market-toBook Profitability Adj. Rsquared Observations Book leverage -0.237 (-18.576) 0.006 (21.790) 0.242 (96.797) -0.302 (-4.234) -2.822 (-17.631) 0.004 (2.242) 0.206 (17.335) -0.008 (-22.028) -0.121 (-38.598) -0.005 (-3.893) -0.299 (-19.215) 0.155 100682 0.206 5725 33 non rated rated firms 2.000 0.816 0.844 1.000 0.857 0.893 0.823 3.000 0.811 0.780 Decile based on VRV 4.000 0.744 34 0.741 5.000 0.654 0.756 6.000 0.505 0.743 7.000 0.365 0.667 8.000 0.277 0.600 9.000 0.210 0.609 10.000 0.151 . Ranking based on the annual standard deviation of the monthly standard deviations of the stock returns during the 12 months of the previous calendar year. Firms with rank 10 have highest standard deviation. Standard errors are reported below the coefficients, in italics. All coefficients on financial deficit are significant at the 1 % level. The table reports coefficients on the financing deficit (beta). ∆Eit = a + bnE DEFit + ε it D Pooled panel OLS regressions of net debt issues ∆D on the financing deficit DEF are estimated for each decile n=1,…10: ∆Dit = a + bn DEFit + ε it , Table 10: Financing the deficit across deciles of volatility of volatility (realized monthly volatility): Rated vs non rated firms Figure 4: Financing the deficit across deciles of volatility of volatility (realized monthly volatility): Rated vs non rated firms Pooled panel OLS regressions of net debt issues ∆D on the financing deficit DEF are estimated for each decile n=1,…10: ∆Dit = a + bn DEFit + ε it , ∆Eit = a + bn DEFit + ε it . Ranking based on the annual standard deviation of the monthly standard deviations of the stock returns during the 12 months of the previous calendar year. Firms with rank 10 have highest standard deviation. Standard errors are reported below the coefficients, in italics. All coefficients on financial deficit are significant at the 1 % level. The table reports coefficients on the financing deficit (beta). D E 1.000 0.900 0.800 0.700 0.600 Rated 0.500 0.400 0.300 0.200 Non rated 0.100 0.000 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 35 8 9 10 non rated rated 0.88835 0.84841 1 0.52488 0.77854 2 0.23361 0.71643 3 0.65183 0.72609 4 36 0.42971 0.71921 5 0.42876 0.75921 6 0.31126 0.63279 7 0.23668 0.86201 8 0.22136 0.50089 9 0.14902 0.61162 10 . Ranking based on the annual standard deviation of the monthly standard deviations of the stock returns during the 12 months of the previous calendar year. Firms with rank 10 have highest standard deviation. Standard errors are reported below the coefficients, in italics. All coefficients on financial deficit are significant at the 1 % level. The table reports coefficients on the financing deficit (beta). ∆Eit = a + bnE DEFit + ε it D Pooled panel OLS regressions of net debt issues ∆D on the financing deficit DEF are estimated for each decile n=1,…10: ∆Dit = a + bn DEFit + ε it , Table 11: Financing the deficit across deciles of volatility of volatility (implied volatility): Rated vs non rated firms Figure 5: Financing the deficit across deciles of volatility of volatility (implied volatility): Rated vs non rated firms Pooled panel OLS regressions of net debt issues ∆D on the financing deficit DEF are estimated for each decile n=1,…10: ∆Dit = a + bn DEFit + ε it , ∆Eit = a + bn DEFit + ε it . Ranking based on the annual standard deviation of the monthly standard deviations of the stock returns during the 12 months of the previous calendar year. Firms with rank 10 have highest standard deviation. Standard errors are reported below the coefficients, in italics. All coefficients on financial deficit are significant at the 1 % level. The table reports coefficients on the financing deficit (beta). D E 1 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 non rated 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 rated 0.1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 37 8 9 10 Appendix Using a Merton model to compute asset volatility From Ito’s lemma, we have Error! Objects cannot be created from editing field codes. where σ E is the instantaneous variance of the rate of return on equity (the standard deviation of daily stock returns from CRSP), σ V is the instantaneous variance of the rate of return on the firm (to be solved for), Vt is the market value of the firm and Et is the market value of equity (both calculated as described below). The derivative of the market value of equity with respect to the market value of the firm in the Merton model is: ln(Vt / Bt ) + ( rf + 12 σ V2 )T ∂Et =Φ ∂Vt σV T where Φ is the cumulative distribution function of the standardized normal distribution )(0,1), T is the time to maturity of the debt (we try both 10 and 20 years) and rf is the risk free rate (from Kenneth French’s website). Variable definitions Investments: For firms reporting under formats 1 to 3, it equals Compustat item #128 + #113 + #129 + #219 - #107 - #109. For firms reporting under format 7, investments equal #128 + #113 + #129 - #107 - #109 - #309 - #310. Change in net working capital: For firms reporting under format 1, it equals Compustat item #274 - #236 - #301. For firms reporting under format 2and 3, it equals #274 + #236 - #301, and 38 for firms reporting under format 7, it equals - #302 - #303 - #304 - #305 - #307 + #274 - #312 #301. Internal cash flows: For firms reporting under formats 1 to 3, it equals Compustat item #123 + #124 + #125 + #126 + #106 + #213 + #217 + #218. For firms reporting under format 7, internal cash flows equal #123 + #124 + #125 + #126 + #106 + #213 + #217 + #314. Market value of a firm: Book value of debt = #181 + #10 (or #56 or #130 depending on availability and in that order) + market value of equity = number of common shares outstanding times the closing share price (from CRSP) Variables that are trimmed In order to remove outliers and misrecorded data, observations that are in the extreme 0.5 % left or right tail of the distribution or have missing values are removed. This trimming has been applied to the following variables: current assets (Compustat item #4), current liabilities (#5), cash dividends (#127), investments (defined above), internal cash flows (defined above), change in net working capital (defined above), financial deficit, net debt issued (#111-#114), net equity issued (#108-#115), all as a percentage of total assets, as well as tangibility (#8/#6), market-tobook ratio, profitability (#13/#6), and log(sales) (natural logarithm of #12). Calculating the variation in firm specific implied volatility from option prices We use end-of-day option prices, option open interest and implied volatility estimates from the Ivy DB database provided by OptionMetrics. The sample is from January 1996 to December 2001. To filter out misrecorded data and very illiquid contracts, we exclude days/contracts that have zero open interest or have a bid-ask spread larger than 50% of the option price at midpoint. 39 The sample includes at-the-money call options with maturity closest to but higher than 182 days. Ideally, we would use longer maturity contracts, e.g. LEAPS, but these contracts are quite illiquid so that our sample would be considerably reduced. The sample has 13,418,700 day-firm implied volatility estimates. We then calculated the standard deviation of the implied volatility per firm over the previous calendar year. If there are less than 90 trading days the firm-year is excluded from the sample. 40 References Akerlof, G., 1970. The market for lemons. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84, 488-500. Baker, M. and J. Wurgler, 2002. Market timing and capital structure, Journal of Finance 57, 132. Barclay, M.J. and C.W. Smith, 1999. The capital structure puzzle: Another look at the evidence. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 12, 8-20. Bradley, M. G.A. Jarrell and E.H. Kim, 1984. On the existence of an optimal capital structure: theory and evidence. Journal of Finance, 39, 857-877. Brealey, R. and S. Myers, 2000. Principles of Corporate Finance, 6th edition. McGraw-Hill. Brennan, M. and A. Kraus, 1987, Efficient financing under asymmetric information, Journal of Finance, 42, 1225-1243. Byoun, S., 2008, How and When Do Firms Adjust Their Capital Structures toward Targets?, Journal of Finance, forthcoming. Cadsby, C.B., Frank, M. and V. Maksimovic, 1990. Pooling, separating and semi-separating equilibria in financial markets: Some experimental evidence. Review of Financial Studies. 3, 315-342 41 Chang, X. and S. Dasgupta, 2003. Financing the deficit: Debt capacity, information asymmetry, and the debt-equity choice, Working paper, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology. Chirinko, R.S. and A.R. Singha, 2000. Testing static tradeoff against pecking order models of capital structure: a critical comment. Journal of Financial Economics, 58, 417-425. Daniel, K. and S. Titman, 1995. Financing investment under asymmetric information. In Jarrow, R., Maksimovic, V. and Ziemba, W. (eds), Handbook in Operations Research and Management Science. Finance (Vol. 9), ch. 23. Elsevier. Fama, E.F., and K.R. French, 2002. Testing tradeoff and pecking order predictions about dividends and debt. Review of Financial Studies, 15, 1-33. Faulkender, M. and M. Petersen, 2005. Does the source of capital affect capital structure?, Review of Financial Studies, forthcoming. Fischer, E.O., R. Heinkel and J. Zechner, 1989. Dynamic capital structure choice: Theory and tests, Journal of Finance, 44, 19-40. Flannery, M.J. and K. Rangan, 2003. Partial adjustment towards target capital structures, Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming. Frank, M.Z. and V.K. Goyal, 2003. Testing pecking order theory of capital structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 67, 217-248. 42 Frank, M.Z. and V.K. Goyal, 2005.Trade-off and Pecking Order theories of debt. Unpublished working paper, University of British Columbia and Hong Kong University of Science and Technology (to appear in E. Eckbo (ed), Handbook of Corporate Finance: Empirical Corporate Finance, Elsevier, 2005.) Graham, J.R., and C.R. Harvey, 2001. The theory and practice of corporate finance: Evidence from the field. Journal of Financial Economics, 60, 187-243. Green, R., 1984, Investment incentives, debt and warrants, Journal of Financial Economics, 13, 115-136. Harris, M. and A. Raviv, 1991. The theory of capital structure. Journal of Finance, 46, 297-356. Helwege, J. and N. Liang 1996. Is there a pecking order? Evidence from a panel of IPO firms. Journal of Financial Economics, 40, 429-458. Hennessy, C.A. and T.M. Whited, 2004. Debt dynamics, Unpublished working paper, University of California at Berkeley and University of Wisconsin, Madison. Hovakimian, A, T. Opler and S. Titman, 2001. The debt-equity choice. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 36, 1-24 Hovakimian, A., G. Hovakimian and H. Theranian, 2004. Determinanats of target capital structure: the case of dual debt and equity issues. Journal of Financial Economics, 71. Kayhan, A. and S. Titman, 2003. Firms’ histories and their capital structures, Unpublished working paper, University of Texas (Austin). 43 Leary, M.T and M.R. Roberts, 2004a. Financial slack and tests of the Pecking Order’s financing hierarchy, Unpublished working paper, Duke University. Leary, M.T and M.R. Roberts, 2004b. Do firms rebalance their capital structures. Journal of Finance, forthcoming. Lemmon, M.L. and J. Zender, 2002. Debt capacity and test of capital structure theories, Unpublished working paper. University of Colorado and University of Utah. MacKie-Mason, J.K., 1990. Do firms care who provides their financing? Journal of Finance, 45, 1471-1495. Mayer, C. and O. Sussman, 2002. A new test of capital structure. Unpublished working paper. University of Oxford. Merton, R. C., 1974. On the pricing of corporate debt: The risk structure of interest rates. Journal of Finance 29, 449-470. Myers, S.C., 1977. Determinants of corporate borrowing, Journal of Financial Economics, 5, 147-175. Myers, S.C., 1984. The capital structure puzzle. Journal of Finance, 39, 575-592. Myers, S.C. and N.S. Majluf, 1984. Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics, 13, 187-221. 44 Nachman, D. and T.H. Noe, 1994. Optimal design of securities under asymmetric information. Review of Financial Studies, 7, 1-44. Rajan, R.G. and L. Zingales, 1995. What do we know about capital structure? Some evidence from international data. Journal of Finance, 50, 1421-1460. Shyam-Sunder, L. and S.C. Myers, 1999. Testing static tradeoff against pecking order models of capital structure, . Journal of Financial Economics, 51, 219-244. Stein, J.C. 2003. Agency, Information and Corporate Investment. In: Handbook of the Economics of Finance, edited by G. Constantinides, Milt Harris and Rene Stulz, Elsevier, 111-165. Stiglitz, J. and Weiss, 1981. Credit Rationing in markets with imperfect information. American Economic Review, 71, 393-410. Strebulaev, I.A., 2004. Do tests of capital structure theory mean what they say?, Unpublished working paper, London Business School. Titman, S. and R. Wessels, 1988. The determinants of capital structure choice. Journal of Finance, 43, 1-19. Van Binsbergen, J., J.R. Graham and J. Yang, 2008, The Cost of Debt, Unpublished working paper, Duke University. Welch, I, 2004, Stock returns and capital structure. Journal of Political Economy, 112, 106-131. 45 46