Download Capital Inflows and Balance of Payments Pressures

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Currency War of 2009–11 wikipedia , lookup

Fixed exchange-rate system wikipedia , lookup

Bretton Woods system wikipedia , lookup

Exchange rate wikipedia , lookup

Foreign-exchange reserves wikipedia , lookup

Capital control wikipedia , lookup

Currency intervention wikipedia , lookup

International monetary systems wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
PDP/08/2
Capital Inflows and Balance of Payments
Pressures—Tailoring Policy Responses in
Emerging Market Economies
Atish Ghosh, Manuela Goretti, Bikas Joshi,
Uma Ramakrishnan, Alun Thomas, and
Juan Zalduendo
© 2008 International Monetary Fund
PDP/08/2
IMF Policy Discussion Paper
Policy Development and Review Department and Research Department
Capital Inflows and Balance of Payments
Pressures—Tailoring Policy Responses in EMEs
Prepared by Atish Ghosh, Manuela Goretti, Bikas Joshi, Uma Ramakrishnan,
Alun Thomas, and Juan Zalduendo*
June 2008
Abstract
This Policy Discussion Paper should not be reported as representing the views of the IMF.
The views expressed in this Policy Discussion Paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily
represent those of the IMF or IMF policy. Policy Discussion Papers describe research in progress by the
author(s) and are published to elicit comments and to further debate.
Although capital inflows are generally beneficial to recipient countries, they also pose a
challenge for the conduct of economic policy. This paper proposes a conceptual taxonomy to
guide the design of policy responses in the face of capital flows. We explore how responses
to capital surges should be differentiated based on the source of balance of payments
pressures. We also examine whether the policy choices in emerging market countries
conform to the taxonomy’s predictions and find some correspondence, especially during
periods of high global liquidity.
JEL Classification Numbers: F32, F21, F41
Keywords: capital flows, policy responses
Author’s E-Mail Address: [email protected]; [email protected]
*
The authors wish to thank Swati Ghosh, members of the Crisis Resolution Division of PDR, other IMF
colleagues, and participants at the Conference on Capital Inflows (March 2008) organized by the National
Institute of Public Finance and Policy (New Delhi, India) for many helpful comments.
-2Contents
Page
I. Introduction ............................................................................................................................3
II. Recent Capital Flows in Emerging Market Economies—Stylized Facts..............................4
III. Capital Flows and Balance of Payments Pressures—A Taxonomy ....................................6
A. Expected Policy Responses.......................................................................................9
B. Observed Policy Responses and Outcomes: What is the Evidence? ......................11
IV. Conclusions........................................................................................................................16
References................................................................................................................................19
Table
1. Descriptive Statistics, 1989–2007........................................................................................8
Figures
1. Regional Capital Flows in Emerging Market Countries......................................................5
2. Taxonomy Based on Total Capital Flows and Current Account Balances..........................7
3. Policy Responses—Flow Approach ..................................................................................10
4. Tailoring Policy Responses to Country-Specific and Global Factors ...............................15
Appendix I ...............................................................................................................................18
-3I. INTRODUCTION
While capital inflows are generally beneficial to recipient countries, they can also complicate
macroeconomic management by overheating the economy, deteriorating the external balance,
and increasing the country’s vulnerability to a change in market sentiment. Such challenges
are especially important during periods of growing global liquidity. Between early 2003 and
mid-2007, for instance, not only was there abundant global liquidity,1 but also many
emerging market economies (EMEs) ran current account surpluses, further contributing to
positive balance of payments (BOP) pressures. Moreover, despite the recent turmoil in
financial markets, many EMEs continue to face positive capital flows and balance of
payments pressures.
Recognizing the importance of policy responses to capital inflows, the International
Monetary and Finance Committee has called for work on the Fund's policy advice to
emerging market economies in the design of policy responses (IMFC Communiqué, October
2007). The IMF’s Executive Board has also called for additional research to provide
guidance on policy choices.2 Against this background, the October 2007 WEO examines the
impact of different policy measures based on a large sample of developing, emerging
markets, and advanced economies during surges in flows and concludes that nominal
exchange rate appreciation and fiscal restraint are advisable during periods of large inflows
as they limit real currency appreciation and foster better growth outcomes. Likewise, the
October 2007 GFSR looked at the relationship between capital flows, market depth, and
liquidity.3
This paper builds on the insights of the recent WEO and GFSR chapters to consider how the
specific circumstances facing the country help refine the general policy prescriptions. A first
question is whether policy should try to respond to the capital inflows or BOP pressures (i.e.,
a tendency for the nominal exchange rate to appreciate or reserves to accumulate). A country
with a floating exchange rate regime would simply allow its exchange rate to appreciate in
the face of positive BOP pressures. In practice, however, few central banks are truly
indifferent to the level of their exchange rate, because of inflationary pressures, balance sheet
exposures, or concerns about competitiveness. Moreover, even under a flexible regime, the
country may wish to respond with fiscal policy.
Whether the country would want to respond depends, in part, on the nature of the capital
flows (official versus private; FDI versus portfolio flows; fixed income versus equity), their
expected duration (temporary versus persistent), and their impact on domestic balance sheets
(such as the risk of exacerbating mismatches). It also depends on the country’s net external
asset (or debt) dynamics and the cyclical position of the economy. Thus capital-poor
developing and EMEs may welcome capital inflows as long as debt sustainability and
1
Periods of high global liquidity are identified based on the indicators in World Economic Outlook (April
2007).
2
3
The Chair’s Concluding Remarks on “Globalization, Financial Markets, and Fiscal Policy.”
Earlier studies of the policy response to capital flows include Schadler and others (1993) and Ul Haque and
others (1997).
-4financial system soundness are not jeopardized; conversely, a country may wish to build up
savings abroad because its population is aging or because its exports depend on
nonrenewable resources.
This paper proposes a conceptual taxonomy that can guide policy responses, while
recognizing the need to account of country-specific factors in any policy recommendation.
While the latter cannot be incorporated in a general framework, the taxonomy nevertheless
serves to nuance—not overturn—the general recommendations of allowing the exchange rate
to appreciate and to tighten fiscal policy in the face of capital inflows. The paper seeks to
answer three questions:
•
How should the policy response to capital surges in most EMEs be differentiated
according to the source and magnitude of the BOP pressures?
•
Do EMEs respond to capital inflows as the taxonomy would suggest?
•
What is the effect of policy responses on the behavior of the real exchange rate?
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section II discusses some stylized facts
on recent capital flows to EMEs. Section III presents a conceptual taxonomy based on the
differences in the nature and source of BOP pressures and discusses the policy responses for
each category. This section also examines the evidence on whether the observed policy
choices are consistent with the taxonomy’s predictions. Section IV concludes.
II. RECENT CAPITAL FLOWS IN EMERGING MARKET ECONOMIES—STYLIZED FACTS
Over the past couple of decades, capital flows to emerging markets have followed several
cycles, with a generally rising trend until end-2007.4 More precisely, as discussed in the
October 2007 WEO chapter, there have been two episodes of large inflows in the past couple
of decades; namely, the period in the early 1990s, which peaked prior to the 1997 East Asian
crisis, and the period that has been building up since early 2002. For instance, annual net
capital inflows to EMEs averaged slightly over 4 percent of GDP during 2004–06. These
increases are a notch below the net capital inflows that preceded the East Asian crisis. It is
worth noting, however, that the recent surge differs from previous ones in four respects. First,
it is occurring against a backdrop of current account surpluses—not deficits. Second, private
capital is playing a dominant role. Third, FDI accounts for a larger share of the total. Finally,
the macroeconomic situation in most recipient EMEs is stronger—public sector deficits are
smaller, exchange rate regimes are more flexible, inflation is lower, and foreign exchange
reserves are larger.5
Among EMEs, however, there are important regional differences. The largest increase in
reserves is in the Middle East (8 percent of GDP), followed by Asia (4 percent of GDP),
4
The discussion is based on simple averages for 50 “market access” EMEs; see Appendix I for the list of
countries.
5
See World Economic Outlook (October 2007) for more details.
-5Central and South America (2 percent of GDP), and Europe (1 percent of GDP); see Figure
1. Moreover, while most regions experienced real exchange rate appreciation, in Asia, the
Middle East, and Central and South America this took the form of higher inflation. In
Europe, by contrast, reserve accumulation has been slow and inflation differentials have been
small.
Figure 1. Regional Capital Flows in Emerging Market Countries (In percent of GDP)
Asia
12
9
Europe 1/
12
FDI
Private excl. FDI
Official
Current Account
9
6
6
3
3
0
0
-3
-3
-6
-6
-9
FDI
Private excl. FDI
Official
Current Account
-9
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006
Middle East
Western Hemisphere
12
12
9
9
FDI
Private excl. FDI
Official
Current Account
6
3
6
0
3
-3
-6
0
-9
-3
-12
-15
-18
FDI
Private excl. FDI
Official
Current Account
-21
-6
-9
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006
Sources: International Monetary Fund; WEO database, and IMF staff estimates
1/ Turkey only until 1994. Includes transition economies from 1995 onwards.
Breaking down the sample of EMEs by region also suggests differences in the characteristics
of capital flows (of course, these averages also mask important differences across countries).
In Asia, the 1997–98 financial crisis marked a sharp turning point for the current account
balance: from deficits of about 3 percent of GDP to surpluses of the same magnitude
(Figure 1). With the exception of FDI, private capital flows have been negative, as have
official flows with the repayment of official financing provided during the crisis. European
countries, by contrast, have large current account deficits. These deficits were financed by
-6FDI until 2001; since then, non-FDI flows have grown in importance and now account for
about one half of total external financing. In the Western Hemisphere and the Middle East,
current account balances have improved—though, on average, still in deficit—and most
inflows are in the form of FDI.
The consequence of this surge of capital flows is positive balance of payments pressures on
the economy. On average, CPI-based real exchange rates have appreciated by 7 percent over
the period 2002–07, and reserves have increased from about 18 percent of GDP at end-2002
to 22 percent of GDP by end-2007. While economic activity has remained above potential in
many EMEs, inflationary pressures were subdued for much of the decade; though it is worth
noting that this too has gradually changed owing to the pick up in commodity prices.
III. CAPITAL FLOWS AND BALANCE OF PAYMENTS PRESSURES—A TAXONOMY
The above discussion suggests some important differences in the nature and source of
balance of payments pressures; as such, the appropriate policy response may be expected to
vary as well. This section presents a simple conceptual taxonomy to highlight these
differences and their implications for the policy response of EMEs. Before doing so,
however, it is worth noting that the appropriate policy response should also depend on factors
not explicitly included in the taxonomy. Indeed, individual country observations should not
be thought as belonging to one category or the other; rather, it is a matter of degree that
depends on country-specific factors—from balance sheets and cyclical positions to financial
and institutional characteristics.
To develop a taxonomy of cases, it is useful to consider a two-dimensional representation of
net capital flows (vertical axis)—where capital flows excludes transactions in reserves—and
current account balances (horizontal axis), which can be segmented into five cases:
•
Case 1. Capital Inflows Responding to Current Account Financing Needs
(northwest quadrant below the 45 degree line). Capital flows are helping to finance
the country’s current account deficit. Although the net BOP pressure (defined as net
total capital flows plus the current account balance) is negative, the dependency on
capital flows might raise concerns about debt sustainability and the country’s
exposure to the risk of sudden stops (particularly if these are non-FDI flows). The
premise is that capital flows are responding to the country’s demand for external
savings. Thus, if there are concerns about capital inflows, economic policies should a
priori be geared to reducing the current account imbalance and cooling the economy.
•
Case 2. Capital Inflows in Search of Yield (northwest and northeast quadrants
above the respective 45 degree lines). In contrast to Case 1, here the “tail wags the
dog”—rather than responding to the country’s current account financing needs, net
total capital flows are assumed to be driven by supply-side factors (i.e., abundant
liquidity in search of yield).6 If the country has a current account deficit, then net total
capital flows would substantially exceed this deficit. In contrast, if the current account
6
See Ghosh (1995).
-7is in surplus, then it would still be the case that the BOP pressures are dominated by
the total capital inflows. Either way, such inflows are complicating macroeconomic
management and policies would need to be geared toward reducing these capital
inflows.
CASE 2
BOP Pressures; Dominating Capital Inflows
BOP Pressures; Dominating
Current Account Surplus
BOP Pressures; Dominating
Current Account Deficit
CASE 3
CASE I
CASE 5
Pre-Crisis Region
CASE 4
BOP Pressures; Dominating
Capital Outflows
-20
Total Capital Flows, Net (In percent of GDP)
-10
0
10
20
30
Figure 2. Taxonomy based on Total Capital Flows and Current Account Balances
(In percent of GDP; annual data 1989–2007)
-20
-10
0
10
Current Account Balance (In percent of GDP)
20
Note: x indicates negative BOP pressures and . indicates positive BOP pressures. Transition economies depicted only from 1995 onwards.
•
Case 3. BOP Pressures from Current Account Surplus (northeast quadrant
under 45 degree line and southeast quadrant with positive BOP pressures). In
this case, capital inflows are assumed to be less important than the current account
surplus; in fact, the surplus could be accompanied by small capital outflows and still
represent positive BOP pressures. If the current account surplus is excessive (for
instance, in terms of the evolution of the country’s NFA position), then policies
should seek to narrow it. By contrast, if the current account surplus is considered
appropriate (in terms of net foreign asset dynamics), then policies to encourage
capital outflows would be useful.
•
Case 4. Current Account Surplus Offset by Outflows (southeast quadrant under
45 degree line). Outflows offset the current account surplus—negative BOP
pressures.
-8•
Case 5. Pre-Crisis Region (southwest quadrant). Reflects large capital outflows
and current account deficits, perhaps portending a capital account crisis.
Table 1. Descriptive Statistics, 1989–2007 (In percent of GDP)
Current
account
balance
1989-2007
Total
capital
flows
BOP
pressures
Current
account
balance
181
3.9
4.1
181
-2.9
6.4
81
-5.5
4.0
447
7.0
5.7
447
3.3
3.6
223
-4.1
5.3
158
-1.8
4.2
158
4.5
3.4
112
7.0
5.7
38
-2.1
2.8
20
5.1
3.5
36
-4.8
3.4
14
-1.6
1.5
Case 1
Number of observations
Mean
Standard deviation
181
-6.8
7.5
Number of observations
Mean
Standard deviation
447
-3.7
4.3
Number of observations
Mean
Standard deviation
158
6.3
5.3
Number of observations
Mean
Standard deviation
38
3.6
3.2
Number of observations
Mean
Standard deviation
36
-3.1
3.4
1999-2007
Total
capital
flows
BOP
pressures
Case 1
Case 2
81
3.8
3.1
81
-1.8
2.2
223
7.7
6.1
223
3.5
3.2
112
-2.1
4.6
112
4.9
3.5
Case 2
Case 3
Case 3
Case 4
38
-5.8
4.2
Case 4
Case 5
36
-1.7
1.4
20
-7.3
5.0
20
-2.2
3.3
Case 5
14
-1.8
1.7
14
-3.3
1.7
Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook .
The above flows-based conceptual taxonomy provides definitions of different circumstances
under which a country might be facing balance of payments pressures; and, in particular,
capital inflows. Whether—or to what extent—a country fits into any single case will be a
matter of judgment that depends on a country’s own circumstances, including the balance
sheet and cyclical position of the economy. In fact, capital flows in some Case 1 countries are
not only financing and responding to the country’s current account deficit, but also helping to
fuel that deficit by causing a consumption boom and overheating the economy (as happened
in East Asia prior to the 1997–98 crisis); thus, the country could be considered to be closer to
a Case 2 and the policy response would change accordingly. As such, the classification in
Figure 2 is an illustration of how countries’ circumstances can be mapped to the taxonomy
based on total capital flows and current account balances. Moreover, since the focus of this
paper is primarily on capital inflows and positive balance of payments pressures, the
discussion and analysis in the remainder of this paper refers only to the policy responses in
Case 1 through Case 3.
While this flows-based taxonomy is useful, two caveats bear emphasizing. First, although
each policy option is discussed separately, policy responses should be considered as a
package of measures, including their mix. Second, the two dimensional taxonomy does not
-9take account of net foreign asset position dynamics or the cyclical position of the economy.
While how these modify the appropriate policy responses are discussed below when
relevant,7 and the empirical work in the next section includes controls to take account of
these factors.
A. Expected Policy Responses
Case 1
In Case 1, the premise is that capital flows are responding to the country’s need for external
savings. In such a case, an exchange rate appreciation would worsen the current account
balance; thus, policies should seek to limit nominal and real exchange appreciation
(Figure 3).
The main instruments in this case are monetary and fiscal policies, which should be tightened
to help dampen economic activity and narrow the current account deficit. Inasmuch as capital
was responding to the deficit, this would also reduce capital inflows.
A discussion of policy responses would be incomplete without discussing prudential
measures and controls. For Case 1 countries, neither imposing controls on inflows nor
removing controls on outflows makes much sense without first tackling the current account
deficit.8 That said, anything that can help shore-up external financing while corrective
monetary and fiscal policies are implemented might serve to reduce vulnerabilities.
While this prescription holds in general for Case 1 countries, it gets modified to the extent
that external sustainability (solvency and liquidity) is not a concern and the economy is
operating well below potential. Since, in Case 1, BOP pressures are negative, if external
sustainability is not a concern, there is essentially no problem of capital inflows. As such, no
policy response would be required. If, in addition, the economy is operating well below
potential, expansionary monetary and fiscal policies may be appropriate (this is where the
general prescription for Case 1 countries gets overturned). It might still best to avoid an
appreciation of the nominal (and hence real exchange rate), however, as the country has a
current account deficit and maintaining external competitiveness would be important, even if
the deficit is not excessively large.
7
The exposition does not discuss unorthodox policy responses; e.g., the possible role of tax policies not only in
tightening fiscal policy, but also in terms of their effect on resource allocation. Some of these measures could
target certain types of capital flows—as opposed to targeting all capital inflows (for example, real estate
investment). The merits of such specific tax measures are two-fold: targeting overheating in a specific economic
activity and reducing broader speculative activity and volatility. The drawbacks however, are also two-fold:
they might lead to distortions in resource allocation, and they act as the equivalent of capital controls, with the
usual attendant costs.
8
To the extent that the capital inflow is fueling the current account deficit (making the country a “blend”
between Cases 1 and Case 2 above), reducing the availability of foreign savings (by imposing controls) or
tightening prudential regulations on bank lending (if this is the source of external finance) could play a useful
role.
- 10 Figure 3. Policy Responses—Flow Approach
CASE 2
Combination
of Case 1 and
Case 2
CASE 1
° Limit nominal exchange rate
appreciation
° Sterilize reserves accumulation
° Tighten fiscal policy
° Tighten monetary policy
° Do not impose controls on inflows
° Allow limited nominal exchange rate
appreciation
° Do not sterilize reserves accumulation
° Tighten fiscal policy
° Do not tighten monetary policy
° Relax controls on capital outflows
° Possibly impose controls on inflows
Combination of
Case 2 and
Case 3
CASE 3
° Allow nominal exchange rate
appreciation
° Do not sterilize reserves
accumulation
° Do not tighten fiscal policy
° Do not tighten monetary policy
° Possibly relax controls on outflows
Combination of
Case 3 and
Case 4
CASE 5
CASE 4
Total Capital Flows
Case 2
In Case 2 countries, the tail wags the dog—capital flows are assumed to be supply-side
determined rather than responding to demand factors. Thus, the country should typically
allow some nominal exchange rate appreciation (unless the country has a current account
deficit whose sustainability is in doubt). Piecemeal appreciation should be avoided, however,
as the expectation of an appreciation would itself attract larger inflows, where as a
sufficiently large appreciation, by making investment in the country more expensive, would
deter further inflows.
Given the accumulation of foreign exchange reserves, a further decision is whether or not to
sterilize its monetary impact. Sterilization would be particularly unsuitable in this case
because capital flows are assumed to be driven mainly by supply-side factors—the search for
yield. In fact, by perpetuating higher interest rates, sterilization is likely to foster continued
capital inflows. Relatedly, monetary policy should not be tightened because the resulting
higher interest rates are likely to exacerbate the capital inflow problem. What if the country is
facing inflationary pressures? Its only recourse in this case would be to allow the nominal
exchange rate to appreciate and to tighten fiscal policy, which serves to lower interest rates
and reduce inflows—unless perceptions of a more “prudent” fiscal policy leads to a larger
- 11 decline in the risk premium demanded by investors.9 In practice, despite this clear policy
prescription, previous studies have found that few countries exercise fiscal restraint when
global liquidity is high.10 Finally, for Case 2 countries imposing controls on inflows could
potentially be useful—though experience to date suggests their effectiveness is limited and
their administrative and distortionary costs are high.11
Under what circumstances do these policy prescriptions get modified? Essentially if the
country has a current account deficit that is large relative to what is desirable from an
intertemporal or debt sustainability perspective. In such case, the country is better-off by
limiting the exchange rate appreciation and tightening monetary policy, especially if there is
a risk of overheating.
Case 3
Countries in Case 3 should allow the nominal exchange rate to appreciate (rather than
accumulate reserves), particularly if the BOP pressures reflect large current account
surpluses. Again, the appreciation should not be piecemeal as that would likely encourage
further capital inflows.12 To the extent that the current account surplus is considered broadly
appropriate (from the perspective of net foreign asset dynamics), BOP pressures can be
relieved by removing or relaxing controls on capital outflows. A tricky question is whether to
loosen or not fiscal policy. Loosening fiscal policy would deteriorate the current account
surplus and reduce the positive BOP pressures. On the other hand, it would also increase
interest rates and encourage capital inflows. To the extent that the positive balance of
payments pressures reflect current account surpluses, the surplus is considered excessive
from the perspective of net foreign asset dynamics, and the economy is not facing
inflationary pressures, fiscal policy should, on balance, be loosened. The implications for
monetary policy are less ambiguous. Monetary policy should not be tightened, nor should the
accumulation of reserves be sterilized—both of which would encourage further capital
inflows. If the country is facing inflationary pressures, its only recourse is to allow further
appreciation of the exchange rate, tighten fiscal policy, or otherwise encourage capital
outflows.
B. Observed Policy Responses and Outcomes: What is the Evidence?
To what extent do countries respond to capital flows and positive BOP pressures as
suggested by the taxonomy? This sub-section explores this question. The exercise is positive
9
Schadler et al. (1993) argue that fiscal consolidation was an important factor attracting capital flows to
developing and emerging market countries in the late 1980s and early 1990s.
10
A recent World Economic Outlook chapter on capital inflows (October 2007) shows that fiscal restraint works
well as a policy response to large inflows. Schadler et al. (1993) show that while fiscal restraint was advisable
to prevent overheating and appreciation, but only one country (Thailand) out of the six in their study did so.
11
For a discussion on the effectiveness of capital controls see Cardenas and Barrera (1997), Cardoso and
Goldfajn (1998), Dooley (1995), Edwards (1999), IMF (2000), and Cordella (2003).
12
In Case 3 countries, if exports are mainly of nonrenewable resources and there are hysteresis effects of an
appreciation on nontraditional exports, then it is likely that the authorities might seek to limit appreciation.
- 12 rather than normative: even if the empirical work finds that countries do not behave as the
taxonomy would suggest, this does not imply that they should not. Conversely, even if it is
found that countries do behave as the taxonomy suggests they should, it does not necessarily
follow that the taxonomy is correct—though it does suggest that the taxonomy reflects
authorities’ behavior. Finally, it is worth noting that the represented policies should not be
considered in isolation but as a package aimed at stemming BOP pressures. Thus, the
discussion below should be viewed as a convenient way of summarizing policy responses
rather than as formal hypothesis testing.13
The policy reaction functions examined cover various policy instruments; specifically,
measures of exchange rate appreciation and volatility (both nominal as well as real),
monetary policy and sterilization variables, and fiscal policy measures.14 The goal is to
examine how policies respond “per unit” of BOP pressures (as measured by the sum of net
capital flows and the current account balance or, in the case of sterilization, by the change in
central bank NFA) in each of the three cases of interest in the taxonomy—these are the
columns referenced as covering the period 1999–2007 in Figure 4.15 Moreover, as previously
noted, the actual policy mix will depend on the economy’s cyclical position and other
country-specific and global factors. To this end, Figure 4 also presents columns that include
these controls, and cover both the period 1999–2007 as well as the years within that period
when global liquidity was high.16
Nominal Exchange Rate Flexibility and Nominal Exchange Rate Volatility
As discussed above, faced with balance of payments pressures a first decision is whether to
allow a nominal exchange rate appreciation. Countries in Case 1 should be the least
welcoming to such an appreciation as this could exacerbate their current account deficit,
while those in Case 3 should be the most welcoming as their BOP pressures stem in fact from
their current account surplus. What is the evidence? Panel A in Figure 4 suggests that this is
the observed policy response—at least once controls for the output gap, external liquidity and
solvency, and the exchange rate regime are included in the analysis (the striped and light
shaded columns). Indeed, while all three cases appear to experience—on average—limited
nominal exchange rate appreciation, Case 1 countries have the least, followed by Case 2 and
Case 3 countries. This pattern is particularly evident when global liquidity is high. This is
consistent with an effort to resist appreciation pressures that could worsen current account
13
The activity index is constructed by combining inflation rates and output gaps into one index, where each
component enters the constructed index with mean 0 and variance 1.
14
The results are based on an unbalanced panel dataset of 50 EMEs using annual data over the period 1999–
2007.
15
Given the small sample size of Case 4 and Case 5 (see Table 1), these are excluded from the econometric
estimations. Moreover, as previously noted, Case 1 through Case 3 are the most interesting for the purposes of
this paper as they represent either cases with positive BOP pressures and/or cases with positive capital flows. In
effect we are carrying out econometric estimations where the lagged values of other policy variables are added
together with controls for the country’s cyclical position—debt-to-GDP ratio, short-term debt-to-reserves ratio,
inflation, and exchange rate regime. The estimations include both country and time dummies.
16
Periods of high global liquidity are identified as described in the footnotes to Figure 4 and WEO (April 2007).
- 13 imbalances. While the exchange rate experiences some appreciation in both Case 2 and Case
3 countries, Case 3 countries experience the largest appreciation pressures when global
liquidity is high. These conclusions are also consistent with the evidence on exchange rate
volatility, where Case 1 countries allow the lowest volatility and Case 3 allow the largest
volatility (Figure 4, Panel B). 17
Monetary Policy and Sterilization
Turning to monetary policy, the taxonomy would suggest the greatest tightening for Case 1
countries to help narrow the current account deficit. For Case 2 countries, monetary
tightening risks raising interest rates and attracting more inflows.18 Also, tightening would
not be appropriate for Case 3 inasmuch as it could lead to larger current account surpluses
and exacerbate capital inflows. Although all three cases are characterized by some monetary
loosening, Case 1 has the least, followed by Case 3, with the greatest loosening among Case
2 countries. (Figure 4, Panel C).19 A similar logic dictates that Case 2 should make the least
use of sterilization—this perpetuates high interest rates, thus exacerbating capital inflows.
While there is partial sterilization in all three cases, the least sterilization seems to occur
among Case 2 countries—the columns in Figure 4, Panel D are close to zero, where a value
of -1 implies full sterilization and 0 implies no sterilization.20
Fiscal Policy
By the logic of the taxonomy, Case 1 countries should undertake the most fiscal tightening
per unit of BOP pressures in order to reduce the current account deficit. Case 2 countries
should also tighten fiscal policy to stem capital inflows that respond to high interest rates.
Case 3 countries should generally not tighten fiscal policy, as this would increase their
current account surplus. The taxonomy’s implications are borne out, though only in times of
high global liquidity (Figure 4, Panel F).21 Specifically, at times of high global liquidity,
fiscal policy is tightened the most in Case 1 countries (to reduce the current account deficit),
followed by Case 2 (to reduce interest rates and capital inflows), and the least in Case 3,
where fiscal tightening would exacerbate the positive BOP pressures by improving the
current account balance.
17
The exchange rate volatility indicator is defined as the absolute value of the monthly percentage change of the
nominal exchange rate over the previous 12 months and averaged over a 12-month horizon (Ghosh and others,
2002). The flexibility indicator reflects the change in the exchange rate but without the absolute value.
18
The effect of monetary tightening on the current account balance is ambiguous as it would appreciate the
exchange rate—leading to lower exports—but also dampen economic activity, lowering imports.
19
Monetary policy is measured by the change in economic growth and inflation relative to the change in broad
money—an increase represent a tightening of monetary conditions.
20
Sterilization is represented by the effect of the change in net foreign assets (scaled by the level of reserve
money) on the change in net domestic assets (also scaled by the level of reserve money).
21
Fiscal policy is represented by the fiscal impulse; that is, the change in the difference between the regular and
the cyclically-adjusted general government balance—an increase represents a tightening of fiscal conditions.
- 14 Aggregate Macroeconomic Outcomes
The results seem to indicate that EMEs do not resort to any single policy response to capital
flows, but rather use the full portfolio of possible instruments to varying degrees according to
the circumstances they are facing. Since economic policies should not be considered in
isolation but rather as a package of measures to help stem BOP pressures, a key “summary
statistic” of the overall effect of policies is the real exchange rate. What conclusions can be
derived from the real exchange rate? In Case 1 countries, the goal is to limit the appreciation
of the real exchange rate to reduce the current account deficit and the need for capital
inflows.22 By contrast, in Case 3 (where the BOP pressures reflect current account surpluses),
an appreciation would reduce the current account surplus and help relieve BOP pressures;
thus, policymakers should be less concerned about allowing a real exchange rate appreciation
or an increase in its volatility. In between these extremes is Case 2, for whom the
implications are more ambiguous. If there is a current account surplus, the real appreciation
could help relieve the BOP pressures. However, this case also includes countries with current
account deficits, where limiting appreciation might be advisable.
What is the evidence? The pattern is largely borne out. Case 1 countries experience the
smallest real exchange rate appreciation per unit of BOP pressure—and even a small
depreciation when global liquidity is high (Figure 4, Panel F).23 Case 2 countries experience
slightly greater real appreciation, especially in the high global liquidity sample. Finally, when
global liquidity is high, the real exchange rate appreciation is greatest for Case 3.
22
The exchange rate volatility indicator is defined as the absolute value of the monthly percentage change of the
real exchange rate over the previous 12 months and averaged over a 12-month horizon. The flexibility indicator
also reflects the change in the real exchange rate but without the absolute value.
23
The results described in this section hold even more strongly when a reduced sample is used. Such sample is
intended to focus the empirical work on the “most extreme” observations for each case. The sample includes the
one-third of all the observations in each case that are farthest from the boundaries of each case. In effect, as
noted in Figure 3, the reduced sample drops observations that are on either side of the diagonals or close to the
origin.
- 15 Figure 4. Tailoring Policy Responses to Country-Specific and Global Factors 1/
4
Panel A. Nominal Exch. Rate Appreciation 2/
20
Panel B. Nominal Exchange Rate Volatility 3/
2
16
0
12
-2
-4
8
Case 1
0
Case 2
Case 1
Case 3
Panel C. Monetary Policy Tightening 4/
0.2
-2
0.0
-4
-0.2
Case 2
Case 3
Panel D. Sterilization 5/
-0.4
-6
Case 1
Case 2
Panel E. Fiscal Policy Tightening 6/
0.6
Case 1
Case 3
10
Case 2
Case 3
Panel F. Real Exch. Rate Appreciation 7/
8
6
0.4
4
2
0.2
0
-2
0.0
Case 1
Case 2
175.68
176.03
176.39
176.74
177.10
177.45
171.42
171.77
172.13
172.48
172.84
173.19
173.55
173.90
174.26
174.61
174.97
175.32
167.16
167.51
167.87
168.22
168.58
168.93
169.29
169.64
170.00
170.35
170.71
171.06
162.90
163.25
163.61
163.96
164.32
164.67
165.03
165.38
165.74
166.09
166.45
166.80
158.64
158.99
159.35
159.70
160.06
160.41
160.77
161.12
161.48
161.83
162.19
162.54
154.38
154.73
155.09
155.44
155.80
156.15
156.51
156.86
157.22
157.57
157.93
158.28
150.12
150.47
150.83
151.18
151.54
151.89
152.25
152.60
152.96
153.31
153.67
154.02
145.86
146.21
146.57
146.92
147.28
147.63
147.99
148.34
148.70
149.05
149.41
149.76
141.60
141.95
142.31
142.66
143.02
143.37
143.73
144.08
144.44
144.79
145.15
145.50
137.34
137.69
138.05
138.40
138.76
139.11
139.47
139.82
140.18
140.53
140.89
141.24
133.43
133.79
134.14
134.50
134.85
135.21
135.56
135.92
136.27
136.63
136.98
129.17
129.53
129.88
130.24
130.59
130.95
131.30
131.66
132.01
132.37
132.72
133.08
124.91
125.27
125.62
125.98
126.33
126.69
127.04
127.40
127.75
128.11
128.46
128.82
120.65
121.01
121.36
121.72
122.07
122.43
122.78
123.14
123.49
123.85
124.20
124.56
116.39
116.75
117.10
117.46
117.81
118.17
118.52
118.88
119.23
119.59
119.94
120.30
112.13
112.49
112.84
113.20
113.55
113.91
114.26
114.62
114.97
115.33
115.68
116.04
107.88
108.23
108.59
108.94
109.30
109.65
110.01
110.36
110.72
111.07
111.42
111.78
103.62
103.97
104.33
104.68
105.04
105.39
105.75
106.10
106.46
106.81
107.17
107.52
100.07
100.42
100.78
101.13
101.49
101.84
102.20
102.55
102.91
103.26
99.71
99.36
99.00
98.65
98.29
97.94
97.58
97.23
96.87
96.52
96.16
95.81
95.45
95.10
94.74
94.39
94.03
93.68
93.32
92.97
92.61
92.26
91.90
91.55
91.19
90.84
90.48
90.13
89.77
89.42
89.06
88.71
88.35
88.00
87.64
87.29
86.93
86.58
86.22
85.87
85.51
85.16
84.80
84.45
84.09
83.74
83.38
83.03
82.67
82.32
81.96
81.61
81.25
80.90
80.54
80.19
79.83
79.48
79.12
78.77
78.41
78.06
77.70
77.35
76.99
76.64
76.28
75.93
75.57
75.22
74.86
74.51
74.15
73.80
73.44
73.09
72.73
72.38
72.02
71.67
71.31
70.96
70.60
70.25
69.89
69.54
69.18
68.83
68.47
68.12
67.76
67.41
67.05
66.70
66.34
65.99
65.63
65.28
64.92
64.57
64.21
63.86
63.50
63.15
62.79
62.44
62.08
61.73
61.37
61.02
60.66
60.31
59.95
59.60
59.24
58.89
58.53
58.18
57.82
57.47
57.11
56.76
56.40
56.05
55.69
55.34
54.98
54.63
54.27
53.92
53.56
53.21
52.85
52.50
52.14
51.79
51.43
51.08
50.72
50.37
50.01
49.66
49.30
48.95
48.59
48.24
47.88
47.53
47.17
46.82
46.46
46.11
45.75
45.40
45.04
44.69
44.33
43.98
43.62
43.27
42.91
42.56
42.20
41.85
41.49
41.14
40.78
40.43
40.07
39.72
39.36
39.01
38.65
38.30
37.94
37.59
37.23
36.88
36.52
36.17
35.81
35.46
35.10
34.75
34.39
34.04
33.68
33.33
32.97
32.62
32.26
31.91
31.55
31.20
30.84
30.49
30.13
29.78
29.42
29.07
28.71
28.36
28.00
27.65
27.29
26.94
26.58
26.23
25.87
25.52
25.16
24.81
24.45
24.10
23.74
23.39
23.03
22.68
22.32
21.97
21.61
21.26
20.90
20.55
20.19
19.84
19.48
19.13
18.77
18.42
18.06
17.71
17.35
17.00
16.64
16.29
15.93
15.58
15.22
14.87
14.51
14.16
13.80
13.45
13.09
12.74
12.38
12.03
11.67
11.32
10.96
10.61
10.25
9.54
9.19
9.90
8.83
8.48
8.12
7.06
7.77
6.70
7.41
6.35
5.28
5.99
4.93
5.64
4.57
4.22
3.86
2.80
3.51
2.44
3.15
2.09
-0.04
1.02
1.73
0.67
1.38
0.31
Period 1999-2007
Case 3
With controls
Case 1
Case 2
Case 3
With controls during high global liquidity
Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook .
1/ Columns with controls are derived from fixed effects estimation with time dummies. They include controls for 'other' (lagged)
economic policies (fiscal and monetary policy, exchange rate flexibility, and sterilization) and for initial conditions (output gap,
liquidity (short-term debt-to-reserves), solvency (debt-to-GDP), and exchange rate regime. These columns cover both the period
1999-2007 as well as the years within that period with high global liquidity. The latter are the years in which the growth rate of
capital flows to EMEs exceeds GDP growth rates in advanced economies (G7 only) by more than 10 percent and builds on liquidity
indicators discussed in the WEO (April 2007).
2/ An increase represents an appreciation and a decline a depreciation (in percent per year).
3/ An increase represents greater volatility in the exchange rate; the absolute value of changes (in percent per year).
4/ An increase represents greater monetary tightening; the change in velocity (in percent).
5/ Numbers close to zero represent no sterilization while those close to -1 represent full sterilization; change in net foreign assets
(scaled by reserve money) on the change in net domestic assets (scaled by reserve money).
6/ An increase represents higher fiscal tightening; change in the difference between the general government balance and the
cyclically-adjusted general government balance (in percent of GDP).
7/ An increase represents an appreciation and a decline a depreciation (in percent per year).
- 16 -
IV. CONCLUSIONS
Recent capital inflows and large current account surpluses have resulted in positive balance
of payments pressures in many EMEs. In other cases, capital inflows where critical to finance
current imbalances. Depending upon such factors as the evolution of the country’s net
foreign asset position, the central bank’s holdings of foreign exchange reserves, the form of
the capital flows and the structure of domestic balance sheets, and the cyclical position of the
economy, these capital inflows need not pose a problem—and indeed may be welcome for
enhancing growth prospects. To the extent that they do, however, some policy response is
required.
This paper develops a simple conceptual taxonomy to identify the circumstances under which
various policy responses might be appropriate. In large measure, the implications of the
taxonomy are a matter of degree: as such, the framework can help inform judgments about
the correct policy response, but cannot replace the need for such judgment. While the
taxonomy is largely founded on flow factors (current account balance and total capital
flows), the discussion (and empirical work) also takes account of other considerations,
including the current account balance (in relation to net foreign asset dynamics) and the
cyclical position of the economy. In practice, other country-specific factors would also need
to be considered.
In general, there is some correspondence between the policy implications of the analytical
taxonomy and observed policy choices of EMEs—especially at times of high global
liquidity, which is when capital inflows to emerging market countries are much more likely
to be a problem requiring a policy response. Thus, Case 1 countries exhibit smaller nominal
exchange rate appreciation, greater sterilization and monetary and fiscal tightening relative to
Case 2 and Case 3. And comparing Case 2 and Case 3, the latter shows greater exchange rate
appreciation, monetary tightening and sterilization, but less fiscal tightening—again, as
would have been implied by the taxonomy. While this does not “prove” that the taxonomy is
correct, it does provide some suggestive evidence in favor of it.
But while the pattern of policy responses is broadly consistent with the taxonomy, this does
not necessarily imply that actual policy stances have responded appropriately to the BOP
pressures. For example, as the taxonomy would predict, Case 1 countries have—to a greater
degree than the other cases—tightened fiscal policy in response to BOP pressures, but this
does not mean that the fiscal stance is necessarily correct: in level terms, it may be too tight
or too loose. Also, while Case 1 countries have tightened monetary policy relative to Case 2
and Case 3 (as the taxonomy would predict), in level terms monetary policy was actually
loosened.
In applying this framework to draw policy prescriptions, therefore, four challenges remain.
First, to determine the right “level” at which to pitch policies—i.e., not just the pattern across
cases. Second, to anticipate where the country will be in terms of the taxonomy over the
relevant planning horizon. Indeed, it would be interesting to examine what can be learnt from
the transition experienced by countries over consecutive years. The third challenge relates to
taking account of the country-specific factors that are not captured by the taxonomy and have
- 17 not been included as controls (e.g., financial soundness indicators). Fourth, even though the
taxonomy has discussed a possible role for capital controls, this remains an area for research;
in particular, to examine whether the effectiveness of controls, especially on inflows, has
diminished with rapid financial innovation and globalization.
In conclusion, though capital flows pose formidable challenges and the appropriate policy
response is tied to country-specific factors, the taxonomy presented in this paper may provide
useful guidance on how to structure a country’s policy response to these inflows.
- 18 Appendix I. Market Access Developing Countries in Sample
Argentina
Azerbaijan, Rep. of
Brazil
Bulgaria
Chile
China, P. R.
Colombia
Costa Rica
Croatia
Czech Republic
Dominican Republic
Ecuador
Egypt
El Salvador
Estonia
Guatemala
Hong Kong
Hungary
India
Indonesia
Iran, I. R. of
Israel
Jamaica
Jordan
Kazakhstan
Korea
Latvia
Lebanon
Lithuania
Malaysia
Mexico
Morocco
Pakistan
Peru
Philippines
Poland
Romania
Russia
Slovak Republic
Slovenia
South Africa
Sri Lanka
Thailand
Trinidad and Tobago
Tunisia
Turkey
Ukraine
Uruguay
Venezuela, Rep. Bol.
Vietnam
- 19 REFERENCES
Cardenas, M. and F. Barrera, 1997, “On the Effectiveness of Capital Controls: The
Experience of Colombia during the 1990s,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol.
54, Issue 1, pp 27–58.
Cardoso, Eliana and Ilan Goldfajn, 1998, “Capital Flows to Brazil: the Endogeneity of
Capital Controls,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 45, No. 1, pp 161–202.
Cordella, Tito, 2003, “Can Short-term Capital Controls Promote Capital Inflows?” Journal of
International Money and Finance, Vol. 22, pp. 737–745.
Dooley, Michael, 1995, “A Survey of Academic Literature on Controls over International
Capital Transactions,” NBER Working Paper No. 5352.
Edwards, Sebastian, 1999, “How Effective Are Capital Controls?,” Journal of Economic
Perspectives, Vol. 13, No. 4, pp 65–84.
Ghosh, Atish, 1995, “Capital Mobility Among the Major Industrialized Countries: Too Little
or Too Much?” Economic Journal, 105, pp. 107–28.
International Monetary Fund, 2000, “Capital Controls: Country Experiences with Their Use
and Liberalization,” International Monetary Fund, Occasional Paper No. 190.
———, 2007 (April), World Economic Outlook (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary
Fund).
———, 2007 (October), World Economic Outlook (Washington, D.C.: International
Monetary Fund).
———, 2007 (October), Global Financial Stability Report (Washington, D.C.: International
Monetary Fund).
Schadler, Susan, Maria Cakovic, Adam Bennett, and Robert Kahn, 1993, “Recent
Experiences with Surges in Capital Inflows,” International Monetary Fund,
Occasional Paper No. 108.
Ul Haque, Nadeem, Donald Mathieson, and Sunil Sharma, 1997, “Causes of Capital Inflows
and Policy Responses to Them,” Finance and Development (March), pp. 3–6.