* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Lectures on International Money
Bretton Woods system wikipedia , lookup
Currency War of 2009–11 wikipedia , lookup
Reserve currency wikipedia , lookup
International monetary systems wikipedia , lookup
Currency war wikipedia , lookup
Foreign exchange market wikipedia , lookup
Foreign-exchange reserves wikipedia , lookup
Fixed exchange-rate system wikipedia , lookup
Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002 February 28, 2003 “There is no sphere of human thought in which it is easier to show superficial cleverness and the appearance of superior wisdom than in discussing questions of currency and exchange.” Winston Churchill, House of Commons, September 29, 1949 Preface These lectures where prepared for for a course the course “International money”, held at the Norwegian School of Management during the spring of 2002. The notes are incomplete, as far as they include no citations. Sandvika, March 2003 Haakon O. Aa. Solheim Contents 1 Money 6 1.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6 1.2 Money and currency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6 1.2.1 Examples of money . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 1.2.2 The creation of a national currency . . . . . . . . . . . 13 1.3 Money versus currency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 1.4 Money and prices—the Cagan model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 1.4.1 Solving the Cagan model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19 1.4.2 Seignorage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28 1.5 The balance sheet of the central bank . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32 1.5.1 Models without money . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34 1.6 Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35 2 International money 37 2.1 Some final remarks on the importance of money . . . . . . . . 37 2.2 Introduction to a discussion on international money . . . . . . 39 2.3 The relationship between the national currency and the international currency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40 2.3.1 A model of the exchange rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41 2.3.2 Choice of exchange rate regime . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48 1 2.4 2.5 The central bank and the supply of money . . . . . . . . . . . 49 2.4.1 The balance sheet of the central bank . . . . . . . . . . 49 2.4.2 Central bank interventions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52 Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56 3 Exchange rate regimes 3.1 59 Relating the national currency to the international currency market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59 3.2 3.1.1 A short history of exchange rate regimes . . . . . . . . 61 3.1.2 Types of exchange rate regimes . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65 3.1.3 Optimal currency areas . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68 3.1.4 The death of fixed exchange rates? . . . . . . . . . . . 70 Why a fixed exchange rate system might be unstable . . . . . 82 3.2.1 The n-1 problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82 3.2.2 The adjustment problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 87 3.2.3 The problem of a credible policy—the Barro Gordon model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90 3.2.4 Appendix: The real exchange rate . . . . . . . . . . . . 93 4 Currency crises 96 4.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96 4.2 Speculative attacks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98 4.3 The Krugman model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 103 4.4 Crises with no trend? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 106 4.5 4.4.1 The strategy of speculators . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109 4.4.2 The role of large speculators . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113 4.4.3 A short note on the Tobin tax . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 120 Contagion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121 2 4.5.1 Transmission of currency crisis via trade channels . . . 124 4.5.2 Transmission via a credit crunch . . . . . . . . . . . . . 127 5 The FX-market 5.1 5.2 130 Some definitions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 130 5.1.1 Instruments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 130 5.1.2 Bid-ask . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131 What we know for certain about the FX-market . . . . . . . . 132 5.2.1 Triangular arbitrage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132 5.2.2 Covered interest rate parity—CIP . . . . . . . . . . . . 133 5.3 How the FX-market is organised . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 134 5.4 Data from the FX-market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 140 5.4.1 International currency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 141 5.4.2 The roles of international money . . . . . . . . . . . . 143 6 The floating exchange rate 152 6.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 152 6.2 High expectations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 153 6.3 “Excess volatility” and some ‘puzzles’ of exchange rate economics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 155 6.3.1 The FX market vs. the stock market . . . . . . . . . . 157 6.4 Random walk?—the Meese and Rogoff results . . . . . . . . . 164 6.5 Equilibrium models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 167 6.6 Disequilibrium models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 169 6.6.1 The Dornbusch model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 171 6.7 Chartists and noise traders . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 179 6.8 Microstructure theories . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 182 6.9 The uncovered interest rate parity (UIP) . . . . . . . . . . . . 185 3 6.9.1 Testing the UIP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 188 7 Portfolio choice, risk premia and capital mobility 7.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 193 7.1.1 7.2 7.3 193 Some notes on methodology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 194 Demand for foreign currency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 195 7.2.1 The minimum-variance portfolio . . . . . . . . . . . . . 198 7.2.2 The speculative portfolio . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 199 7.2.3 Empirical calculations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 200 7.2.4 Heterogenous agents . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 202 7.2.5 Aggregate behaviour . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 203 The collapse of a currency board . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 214 7.3.1 Risk premium and the need for capital . . . . . . . . . 214 7.3.2 Risk premium and expected depreciation . . . . . . . . 214 7.3.3 Effects of a fall in risk premiums . . . . . . . . . . . . 216 7.4 Empirical applications of the portfolio choice model . . . . . . 219 7.5 Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 220 7.5.1 Mean-variance vs. state-preference . . . . . . . . . . . 220 7.5.2 The exchange rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 221 8 The real exchange rate and capital flows 223 8.1 Some notes on research strategy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 223 8.2 Some empirical observations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 223 8.2.1 8.3 8.4 Differences in the price level . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 225 Accounting for what we do not know about the real exchange rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 227 8.3.1 External balance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 230 Explaining long term shifts in the real exchange rate . . . . . 232 4 8.4.1 8.5 Fluctuations in the real exchange rate and capital flows . . . . 242 8.5.1 8.6 The Balassa-Samuelson effect . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 233 Model of two countries and terms of trade shocks . . . 243 The importance of capital flows for consumption smoothing . . 255 8.6.1 Explaining the Feldstein-Horioka puzzle . . . . . . . . 256 9 International capital flows, the IMF and monetary reform 259 9.1 Topics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 259 9.2 Capital flows . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 259 9.3 The international debt market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 265 9.4 Can a country default? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 273 9.5 The role of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) . . . . . . 274 9.6 Capital controls in Chile . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 280 10 Exercises 284 11 Solutions 319 5 Chapter 1 Money 1.1 Introduction This lecture will discuss the topic of money. Why do we use money? I then present the “Cagan model”—a framework that provides a useful view on the relationship between money and prices. In the next lecture we will use this model as a basis for a first discussion of foreign exchange rates. 1.2 Money and currency If you ask a non-economist what he thinks of when he hears the word economics he will probably say money. But as you are approaching the last months of a four year study in economics, how much have you actually learned about money? Economics is not about money. Economics is about maximising utility under constraints. To achieve this prices must adjust to clear markets. Prices are only ratios—the price of good 1 is the number of good 2 you need to obtain one unit of good 1. You don’t need “money”—that is currency—for that. 6 You only need more than one good. However, without money the economy turns into a barter economy. I will trade with you only if you have a good that I need, and you will trade with me only if I have a good you need. For a barter economy to work, there must be a high coincidence of wants. That might work in an economy where everyone supplies most of their own needs. In a more advanced economy individuals become specialised, and coincidence of wants become scarce. The economy needs an asset used for transactions. That asset is money. Money is introduced to play three main roles. It is supposed to be • a unit of account, • a means of payment, and • a store of value. The unit of account is just an accounting measure. We need something so standardised that everyone has a common understanding of its value. We can then measure the value of other things in quantities of this unit. The means of payment is the physical thing we use for transactions. Instead of exchanging one good for another we can exchange the good in the means of payment, and use this in new transactions. It is important that it is easy to evaluate the true value of this ‘product’. It must be reasonably safe from forgery or fraud. And it should be easy to carry around. The store of value is a more difficult concept. A store of value must be safe—one must be reassured that it does not lose its value over time. Iron, that rusts, is dominated by gold. Paper that receives no interest, like a USD 100 bill, is dominated by a bond that receives interest. The good that is supposed to fill these three criteria in the modern economy is currency. Today a currency is generally understood as a liability on 7 the national central bank. The national currency works as a unit of account, as a means of payment and as a store of value. As a store of value currency, that receives no interest, it is dominated by a number of other goods. Note that money is something more than currency. In this course money and currency will however be the same thing, unless otherwise stated. 1.2.1 Examples of money Different periods have solved the need for money by different means. Here is a number of examples of money. • In World War 2 prison camps the Red Cross supplied prisoners various goods, like food, clothing and cigarettes. However, the goods were distributed without attention to the prisoners actual needs; one might get cigarettes even if one was not a smoker. In these camps there evolved a system for trading the Red Cross rations. The “money” in this system was cigarettes. – A unit of account: all prices were stated in cigarettes. Mankiw (1992) reports that one shirt costed about 80 cigarettes. As a unit of account cigarettes is adequate. However, note that it would not work if the quality of different types of cigarettes differ to much. If e.g. American cigarettes were much better than e.g. German cigarettes, the price would have to specify the type of cigarette as well. – A means of payment: cigarettes are easily transportable. One problem is that they lose value if they get wet. – Store of value: cigarettes can be stored for some time without losing flavour. And there was a stable underlying real demand, as 8 smokers would demand cigarettes even if they were not used as money. However, cigarettes could be expected to lose value when the war ended. • Gold coins. Metal became the leading fabric used for currency in the European economies. Three metals were used: copper for smaller purchases, silver for medium sized purchases and gold for larger purchases. These were all commodity money. That means that they had a value independent from their value as money. One is willing to hold precious metals even if one can not use them in day-to-day transactions. – As a unit of account: gold works well if one can agree on a standardised weight. However, often one can not. This is one reason why currency, even in the time of the gold standard, was national. Weight measures were national specific to the end of the last century. They still to some degree are—i.e. the difference between US and European standards. – As a means of payment: gold as such is not a good means of payment. First, it is very expensive. For most purchases the amount need is so small that other metals, like copper, is more useful. Second, it needs to be meticulously measured each time to assure that one pay the right amount. To alleviate the last problem public authorities or banks—like the banks in Florence, therefore the “Florin”—issued gold coins. Each coin had a standardised value. However, even such coins can be problematic. A coin can be “shaved”—i.e. people take of some gold and hope to sell the coin 9 for its original value. Or the issuing institution can attempt to make money by issuing coins with less gold content, but sell the coin for its original value. This is called debasing the currency. In fact, debasing might lead to currency crises—people will try to store the coins with high gold content, and sell the coins with low gold content. Such currency crises were frequent in the later years of the Roman empire. – Store of value: over time the value of gold depends on who much gold is available. If much gold is found, the value of gold will fall. However, gold is scarce. And as gold has an intrinsic value in its beauty, it can be considered fairly safe. • Gold backed currency. Gold is bulky, heavy and difficult to carry around. So instead of using gold directly, people started to use claims on gold. A bank issues a “bill of credit” that states that a given amount of gold can be redeemed from the bank with this bill. E.g.: I deposit 1 ounce of gold in Bank A. Bank A gives me a bill stating that I get one ounce of gold if I make a claim with this bill in bank A. I use this bill to purchase a radio. The radio salesman uses the bill to pay his rent. The landlord uses the bill to pay ... → the bill works as currency. Why does a bank issue such a bill? As long as it is not required to keep 100 per cent reserves, it can make an income on the interest rate differential. 100 per cent reserves would imply that the bank keeps one unit of gold for each unit of gold backed currency issued. However, it is not likely that everyone will claim their bills at once. So the bank can keep less than 100 per cent of the gold as actual reserves. It can 10 therefore invest some of the gold deposited in activities with a positive return, and thereby get an interest rate. The return on issuing currency is the difference between this interest rate and the interest rate paid on the bill (usually zero). So why do I give my gold to the bank? A bill of credit is easier and safer to carry than gold. – As a unit of account: if everyone understand the denomination, i.e. how much gold one unit refers to, it should work well. However, it is clearly most useful if every bank uses the same denomination. – As a means of payment: bills of credit are easy to carry. However, here the value depends on the bank that has issued the bill. If you don’t trust the bank, you don’t trust the money. – Store of value: In the case of gold we had uncertainty about the future value of gold. Here we must add the uncertainty about the bank. And we still (normally) get no interest rate. So this bill is probably dominated as a store of value. The currencies above are all based on commodities. That means that the currency have a potential value even if it is not used as a currency. However, there are problems with such currencies. The supply of money is exogenous—it is mostly decided by factors outside the economy. This is not perfectly true: the mining activity for gold would to some degree depend on its monetary value. However, over time the gold supply is independent of how much money the economy actually needs. • Fiat currency Fiat money is an asset that only has value as a medium of exchange. An example of fiat money is a bill issued by a national monopoly stating 11 that it is the standard means of payment in a given country. The bill is however not redeemable in any commodity from the side of the issuer. Norges Bank is not obliged to give anything else in return for paper money than new paper money—a 50 NOK bill will only return you a new 50 NOK bill. It only has value because it is accepted as a means of payment. – As a unit of account? Actually fiat money is not very good. The problem is that the issuer, in theory, can issue as much such currency as he likes. But of course, it an infinite amount of currency is issued, then the currency loses all value. So in practice the issuer will limit the amount issued. However, inflation is or has been a problem in almost every country with a fiat currency. If inflation is high or unpredictable, the currency is no longer a good unit of account. In countries with extreme inflation one often changes the unit of account to a foreign currency, although the national currency is still the means of payment. E.g. in many high inflation countries the USD is used as a unit of account. – As a means of payment: fiat currency works good, as long as people trust the issuer. But it depends on how many uses the currency. If everyone accepts it, it is very handy. If no-one accepts it, it has no value—the value of a currency depends on its use. – As store of value: very uncertain, and clearly dominated by a number of other goods, including gold and bonds. 12 1.2.2 The creation of a national currency In modern times we have seen a movement from gold backed currency to fiat currency, and a movement from the use of currency issued by private banks to currency issued by a state monopoly. Those two movements probably depended on each other. The issuer of a currency need to be trustworthy, stable and have good credit. The modern state came to fulfill these criteria during the 19th-century, as national governments were firmly established, and tax systems were implemented. The private banking system seems to have worked in a satisfying manner. As an example the USA had no national currency from 1838 to 1863. All currency was issued by private banks. The Federal Reserve System was first established in 1913. However, there are potential problems: • “Wild-cat banking”—banks issues bills with no backing, or they keep insufficient reserves. • Potential instability. A currency becomes more valuable the more people who uses it. However, to extend the use of its currency, the bank needs to extend the number of customers. More customers generally means more bad customers as well. So a big bank might become more unstable, and the currency more unsafe. We get the potential of currency crashes. • Private banking creates uncertainty among general users, as it is difficult to evaluate if a bank is safe or not. • The state loses possible income from seignorage—the profit from issuing money. 13 Figure 1.1: Norwegian CPI from 1835 to 2000. Log of index value. 1920=100 8 Pure fiat currency 7 Bretton Woods Gold standard 6 5 4 18 35 18 40 18 45 18 50 18 55 18 60 18 65 18 70 18 75 18 80 18 85 18 90 18 95 19 00 19 05 19 10 19 15 19 20 19 25 19 30 19 35 19 40 19 45 19 50 19 55 19 60 19 65 19 70 19 75 19 80 19 85 19 90 19 95 20 00 3 These factors brought forward the nationalisation of the “currency industry” and centralisation of currency issuance by “central banks”. Note that a central bank is not always public. The only requirement is that it gets the monopoly to issue valid currency for a country. Norges Bank was a private institution in the first years of its existence. However, after some time most central banks were nationalised. A state backed monopoly issuer has less need for gold to back the value of its currency. Why? A government back the currency on the trust of the people and the income generated from future taxes. However, it is much easier to impose inflation if the currency is issued by a monopolist than if one has private issuance of currency. 14 1.3 Money versus currency Is money and currency the same thing? Currency is money, but money is not only currency. Currency is very liquid money, money used as means of payment and unit of account. However, other forms of money exists: • A short term bank deposit is money. But it is not as liquid as currency (there are stores that do not accept a debit card). • A savings account is money. However, these money are more illiquid than the primary account. One can not make purchases directly on a traditional savings account. • If one holds long term bonds, these can be bought and sold, but is not redeemed before after a certain number of years. Different types of assets have different degrees of liquidity. One moves one’s holding between different types of money all the time. Traditionally, and everything else equal, the return of an asset is decreasing in the degree of liquidity. Currency, i.e. very liquid money, usually returns no interest. Money has been divided into groups, like M1, M2 and M3. M1 is the most liquid money (currency and short term deposits), M2 is less liquid money and so on. Note: in modern banking the distinctions between different types of money is falling. My credit card offers an account with free debit card access and an interest rate formerly only expected on long term deposits. More and more money is stored electronically as we extend the use of bank cards. Most people no longer holds large holdings of non-interest bearing currency. 15 de s. m 92 ar .9 ju 3 n. se 93 p. de 93 s. m 93 ar .9 ju 4 n. se 94 p. de 94 s. m 94 ar .9 ju 5 n. se 95 p. de 95 s. m 95 ar .9 ju 6 n. se 96 p. de 96 s. m 96 ar .9 ju 7 n. se 97 p. de 97 s. m 97 ar .9 ju 8 n. se 98 p. de 98 s. m 98 ar .9 ju 9 n. se 99 p. de 99 s. m 99 ar .0 ju 0 n. se 00 p. de 00 s. m 00 ar .0 ju 1 n. se 01 p. de 01 s. 01 de s. m 92 ar .9 ju 3 n. se 93 p. 9 de 3 s. m 93 ar .9 ju 4 n. 9 se 4 p. de 94 s. m 94 ar .9 ju 5 n. se 95 p. de 95 s. m 95 ar .9 ju 6 n. se 96 p. de 96 s. m 96 ar .9 ju 7 n. se 97 p. 9 de 7 s. m 97 ar .9 ju 8 n. 9 se 8 p. de 98 s. m 98 ar .9 ju 9 n. se 99 p. de 99 s. m 99 ar .0 ju 0 n. se 00 p. 0 de 0 s. m 00 ar .0 ju 1 n. 0 se 1 p. de 01 s. 01 Notes and coin in the Norwegian economy NOK) Figure 1.2: Notes and coins in (Millions the Norwegian economy. Millions of NOK 45 000 43 000 41 000 39 000 37 000 35 000 33 000 31 000 29 000 27 000 25 000 Figure 1.3: M1 versus notes and coins 450 000 400 000 All numbers in million NOK 350 000 300 000 250 000 M1 200 000 150 000 100 000 50 000 Notes and coins 0 16 International Monetary System 2. Banking system The QTM in Argentina, 1974-1991 (log scale) Figure 1.4: Inflation and money growth in Argentina, 1974-91 Annual CPI Inflation Rate 100000 10000 1000 100 10 10 100 1000 10000 Annual Money Growth Rate 1.4 Money and prices—the Cagan model In the IS-LM model the relationship between money and prices is given by the LM-curve, Md = L (Yt , it+1 ) , Pt (1.1) where M d is money demand, Pt is the price level at time t, Y is output and i is the nominal interest rate. The LM curve assumes that real money demand is 8 rising in Y (because when output grows on needs higher real money holdings) and falling in i, as a higher interest rate rises the alternative cost of holding money (remember that money here is the same as currency). Phillip Cagan argued that during a period of hyperinflation expected 17 inflation would swamp all other influences on money demand. Figure 1.4 illustrates the relationship between money growth and price inflation in Argentina over the period from 1974 to 1991. This was a period with very high inflation. As we can see, as inflation gets higher, the relationship between money growth and inflation becomes stronger. Under high inflation one can therefore ignore the effect of output and interest rates, and instead write Mtd = Et Pt Pt+1 Pt −η . (1.2) Equation (11.48) tells us that if expected inflation rise, we reduce our demand for real money balances. If we know that prices will rise tomorrow, we want to hold less money today, as these money will lose value tomorrow. Et shows us that we look at expectations at time t. η is the semielasticity of demand for real balances with respect to expected inflation. It is parameter that tells us how much demand for real balances—the money stock divided by the price level—reacts to a change in expected inflation. If η is large this indicates that we would make a large adjustment in money balances if we know that prices will change tomorrow. If η is close to zero we do not care about inflation when deciding the level of real money balances. If we take logarithms on both sides we obtain mdt − pt = −ηEt (pt+1 − pt )) , (1.3) where small letters are the logarithms of large letters. We will use the equation on logarithmic form, as this simplifies the analysis. 18 1.4.1 Solving the Cagan model We want to study the relationship between money and prices. So we need to find the equilibrium of the model. We have an equation for money demand. However, we know that in equilibrium supply must equal demand. So we must have md = mt . (1.4) We can then restate equation (11.48) as mt − pt = −ηEt (pt+1 − pt ). (1.5) Further, let us assume that all agents are rational and have perfect foresight. If so we can eliminate the expectation term. We get mt − pt = −η(pt+1 − pt ). (1.6) Equation (11.53) is a first order difference equation. We want to find the relationship between p and m, in other words we want an expression of the type pt = γm. (1.7) The easiest way to solve a first order difference equation is by iteration. First, write equation (11.53) with pt on the left hand side. We get pt = 1 η mt + pt+1 . 1+η 1+η (1.8) We see that today’s price level depends on the unforseen price level of tomorrow. What does the price level of tomorrow depend on? Lead equation 19 (1.8) with one period, and we get pt+1 = 1 η mt+1 + pt+2 . 1+η 1+η (1.9) We can now substitute the expression from equation (1.9) into equation (1.8). Doing so we obtain 1 pt = 1+η η mt + mt+1 1+η + η 1+η 2 pt+2 . (1.10) If we repeat this procedure, eliminating pt+2 and then pt+3 and so on, we will in the end get s−t T ∞ 1 X η η pt = ms + lim pt+T . T →∞ 1 + η s=t 1 + η 1+η (1.11) How shall we interpret equation (1.11)? We often choose to assume that lim T →∞ η 1+η T pt+T = 0. (1.12) This is the same as assuming that there is no “speculative bubbles” in the price level. Indeed, equation (2.10) will be zero unless the level of prices changes at an ever increasing proportional rate. Bubbles What is a speculative bubble? One can say that a bubble is an explosive path which brings the level progressively farther away from economic fundamentals. However, “economic fundamentals” is something we define—it is a “model specific term”.1 A better definition is probably that a bubble is 1 What do I mean with “model specific term”? When we build a model we define a relationship between variables. The only thing we know about the relationship between 20 a movement that leads to increasing divergence from the equilibrium value defined by an economic model. Notice that in this model we assume perfect foresight and rational agents. Despite this quite strong assumptions we can not rule out the existence of rational bubbles. We can only assume that they do not exist. However, it is reasonable to believe that rational bubbles exist? Bubble can not exist if we know that it will “burst” at a given point of time. Why? If we know the price level will revert to its “true value” at a given time, we will try to make a fortune going short in the asset. However, if everyone does this, prices must fall today. A bubble can never exist if there is certainty about when the bubble will collapse. It is easier to see this if think about e.g. stocks instead of the general price level. Assume that there is stock price bubble. If we expect the prices to fall at time t, we will go “short” today—i.e. we will sell assets for delivery at time t + 1. Why? Because we expect that we can buy stock to a much lower price than in the forward contract when time t + 1 arrives. At t + 1 we buy stock in the spot market at a low price to fulfill our forward contract. However, if the timing of the crash of the bubble is uncertain, a bubble can exist even if everyone knows it is a bubble. If we expect prices to rise in this period, and the next period, and the period after that, we can make money by buying the asset today. But doing so, we just fuel the bubble—the more people who buy the asset, the more do prices rise. In fact everyone find it profitable to let the bubble exist—although everyone knows that a some time in the future the prices need to revert to a lower level. “Rational bubbles” are models where the there is much uncertainty about when the the price level and money is what we have defined in economic models. If the price level does not behave as in the model we say that it does not behave according to “economic fundamentals”. However, notice that we do not know if the behaviour of the price level defies logic, or if it is our model that is flawed. 21 bubble will collapse. Note that it is very difficult to test if a bubble really exists. If we test for the existence of a bubble, we will simultaneously test whether 1. there is a divergence from the values predicted by the economic model, and 2. whether the economic model in fact is the true model, or if the divergence only is the product of bad modelling. It is more or less impossible to distinguish these two issues from each other. Prices and money—a solution? We assume no bubbles. We can then rewrite equation (1.11) as s−t ∞ 1 X η ms . pt = 1 + η s=t 1 + η (1.13) We can draw several interesting conclusions from equation (1.13): • First, note that2 s−t ∞ 1 X η 1 1 = ( η ) = 1. 1 + η s=t 1 + η 1 + η 1 − 1+η 2 (1.14) Here I use the rules of summations. Remember the following two results from your classes in mathematics: ∞ X 1 ks = 1−k s=t T X s=t ks = 1 − k T −t 1−k 22 If the money supply is constant, i.e. m = m we have that pt = m. (1.15) Not only is inflation zero for all periods, the price level is also fixed at the level m. However, if the money supply makes an unexpected jump at time t to a new level, i.e. mt = m t < t (1.16) m0 t ≥ t, (m0 > m), this implies that pt = m, t < t (1.17) m0 , t ≥ t. As we see, if there is an unexpected shock to m the price level will change immediately. The change in the price level will be equiproportionate with the change money stock. These results implies that in this model, money is fully neutral. Changes in the level of money supply or changes in the denomination used, i.e. a change in the unit of account, leads to an immediate equal proportional change in the price level. For example, exchanging 8 “old NOK” with 1 “new NOK” will only lead to all prices being divided by 8. This result will be found in all models that have no nominal rigidities, such as sticky prices, and no “money illusion”.3 • Real variables are not affected by a change in money supply—we have 3 Money illusion is the idea that people do not understand the consequences of a change in the money supply immediately). 23 real-monetary dichotomy—money affect only prices. Money is a “veil”— and rational agents are able to look through it without letting it affect their decisions. • Notice that prices depend on expectations of the future. This implies that – it will matter whether a shock is expected to be temporary or permanent, and – it will matter whether the shock is expected or unexpected. Above we illustrated the case of an unexpected shock. Assume instead that at time t the government announces a change in the money supply at some future time T . Suppose mt = m t < T (1.18) m0 t ≥ T, (m0 > m). One will then find that the path of the price level becomes4 pt = m + ( η )T −t (m0 − m), t < T 1+η (1.19) m0 , t ≥ T. The price level will make a small jump when the news is announced. It will so accelerate over time until it reaches its new level at time T . News will immediately be incorporated in the price setting. Last, consider the case when the money supply grows at a fixed rate. Assume that mt = m + µt. It is reasonable to believe that if money grows at 4 A proof is provided at the end of the lecture notes. 24 Figure 1.5: A perfectly anticipated rise in the money supply Price level m’ m m t T time the rate µ, prices must grow at the same rate, so that inflation also equals µ. If we insert this in the real money demand function, equation (11.48), we have mt − pt = −ηµ, (1.20) pt = mt + ηµ. (1.21) or This result will be used later in the course. Does the Cagan-model fit Norwegian data? According to the above model an unexpected increase in the money stock should lead to • an immediate, equiproportionate increase in the price level, and 25 • causality should go from money to prices, not the other way around. One empirical methodology to identify unexpected shocks is to do a socalled Vector Auto Regression (VAR) and find impulse response functions. A VAR is a system of equations estimated simultaneously. An impulse response function estimates how the variables in the system will react to a shock in the error term of one variable. The error term is something that is not explained in the model. A shock to the error term is therefore by definition unexpected. Figure 1.6 illustrates the impulse response functions from a shock in the 12-month growth rate of M1. The results can be summarised as follows: • Prices react to a change in the money stock. However, the reaction occurs with a lag of between 4 and 10 months. • We see that a shock to money affects prices, but a shock to prices do not affect money. This should imply that causality runs from money to prices. There is a correlation between money and prices. However, the prediction of an immediate jump in the price level is not reflected in the data. This might have two causes: • the shocks in the model are not “unexpected”, or • prices only react to a shock in money with a lag. The first explanation is not implausible, as we only estimate a model containing lagged values of changes in the CPI and M1. However, it is reasonable to believe that prices do indeed only react with a certain lag. Three explanations are offered for why prices do not react immediately to a shock to money: 26 Figure 1.6: Money growth versus inflation—Norway 1987-2001 Response to One S.D. Innovations ± 2 S.E. Response of DCPI to DCPI Response of DCPI to DM1 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.0 -0.1 -0.1 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 5 Response of DM1 to DCPI 10 15 20 25 30 35 30 35 Response of DM1 to DM1 3 3 2 2 1 1 0 0 -1 -1 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 5 10 15 20 25 DCPI is the 12-month change in CPI, and DM1 is the 12-month change in M1. 27 1. Sticky prices. This is the traditional assumption in Keynesian models. It is built on the argument that contracts take time to adjust. 2. Money illusion. When people get more money between their hands, they are not able to conclude if this is the result of increased productivity on their part, or of more money in circulation. 3. Portfolio balancing. People will not adjust their money holdings immediately. As a result the effect of increased money supply will take time to dissipate through the economy. These theories have different implications. However, on one account they all agree: if prices do not adjust immediately, a change in money growth might have real effects on the economy. Money will no longer be neutral. 1.4.2 Seignorage Seignorage is the revenue the government acquires by using newly issued money to buy goods or repay debts. It is assumed that most hyperinflations are results of the government’s need for seignorage revenues.5 Seignorage in period t is defined as Seignoraget = Mt − Mt−1 . Pt (1.22) This is the real increase in the money supply from period (t − 1) to period t. However, above we saw that the price level depends on the present money supply and future expected money growth. This implies that there must be a limit to how much the government can collect as seignorage. To see this, 5 A hyperinflation is a period when prices rise at a rate averaging 50 per cent per month. The highest monthly inflation recorded is in Hungary in July 1945 when prices rose 19800 per cent in one month. 28 rewrite equation (1.22) as Seignoraget = Mt − Mt−1 Mt . Mt Pt (1.23) If higher money growth leads to higher expected inflation, demand for real balances (M/P ) will fall. So higher money growth might not always increase seignorage revenues. We can use the Cagan model to find the of money growth will maximize seignorage revenues. We had that Mt = Et Pt Pt+1 Pt −η . (1.24) If we substitute (1.24) into (1.23) and rearrange a little, we get Mt−1 Seignoraget = (1 − ) Mt Pt+1 Pt −η . (1.25) We now assume that the government can commit itself to a certain rule for money growth. More specifically, we assume that money growth is given by Mt = 1 + µ ⇔ mt+1 − mt = µ. Mt−1 (1.26) If money supply grow at a constant rate µ, we have seen that prices grow at the same rate µ, so we have that Mt Pt =1+µ= . Mt−1 Pt−1 (1.27) Substituting (1.27) into (1.25) we obtain Seignoraget = (1 − 1 )(1 + µ)−η = µ(1 + µ)−η−1 . 1+µ 29 (1.28) We find the µ that optimises seignorage by taking the first-order condition of (11.73) and setting equal to zero, so that (1 + µ)−η−1 − µ(η + 1)(1 + µ)−η−2 = 0. (1.29) The revenue maximising net rate of money growth must equal 1 µM AX = . η (1.30) This is the inverse of the semielasticity of real balances with respect to money. In fact, we have just found out that an optimising central bank will behave in exact the same way as monopolist with zero marginal cost of production (we simplify by ignoring the cost of printing currency). That should not be a surprise; after all a central bank is just a monopolist in the “currency issuance market”. An other way to see the result from equation (1.30) is illustrated in figure 1.7. We can draw a “Laffer-curve” for seignorage revenue. There will be a level of money growth that maximises seignorage revenue—to issue more money than this will only be counter productive. In a hyperinflation it is reasonable to believe that the government exceeds this optimal level of money growth. But why? If expectations are not forward looking, but backward looking, the government might earn money by printing money at an increasing speed. If expectations are backward looking, everyone believes that last periods money growth will be next periods money growth. Increasing money growth in the next period over the money growth in this period will by definition exceed expectations. It is however doubtful if one can fool the public for a long time in this way. A problem with the above analysis is that we assume that the government 30 Figure 1.7: “Laffer-curve” for seignorage revenue Seignorage revenue 1/n Rate of money growth Note that n in the figure equals η in the model. can commit itself to a given rate of money growth for an infinite future. However, if this is credible, the government has an incentive to fool the public by increasing the rate of money growth for one period, thereby getting an extra revenue. If the public does not trust the government, the optimal rate of money growth might be less than what implied from the above analysis. In the end, how large is actual seignorage revenue? For most industrialised countries the yearly revenue is about 0.5 per cent of GDP. In the case of Norway that would be about 500 million USD. In developing countries it can be much more of total government expenditure, however it reportedly rarely exceeds 5 per cent of GDP on a sustained basis. 31 1.5 The balance sheet of the central bank The government is often seen as one entity in economic models. It should not matter that one public institution has a surplus on its books, if another public institution has a deficit. What matters are the net position over all government institutions. However, in monetary matters it is useful to distinguish between the “fiscal authority” and the “central bank”. In fact this distinction is artificial. As long as the central bank is publicly owned, it is part of the governments balance sheet. Money, a liability on the central bank, is at the same time a liability on the government. However, because money is so important for the workings of the modern economy, there tends to be a separation between government expenditure and the central bank. If there was no separation between the central bank and the government, the government would have two choices if it needed to finance a deficit: • it could issue more money, or • it could issue bonds. An independent central bank is supposed to be a guarantee against monetary financing of public expenditure. However note that the distinction between issuing bonds and money is only a “veil”. If the central bank issues money to purchases government bonds, the two cases are exactly the same. In most advanced economies there is a tight wall separating the fiscal and monetary authorities. If the government uses money to finance public deficits, the money will loose value, and no longer fulfill its purposes as unit of account, means of payment and store of value. In the long term the cost of undermining the value of money exceeds the potential gains from financing public deficits by printing money. However, leading experts on monetary 32 economics (like Michael Woodford) have argued that a target for inflation will only be credible if there is some target for public spending as well. Over time the one needs to see the government accounts from a consolidated standpoint—and one can not expect that the central bank balances its book if other parts of the government do not balance their books. A central bank typically holds four types of assets. These are • claims on foreign entities, i.e. – foreign currency, and – foreign-currency-denominated bonds. • gold (although the stock of gold has been reduced in the later years) and SDR’s (claims on the International Monetary Fund, so-called “paper gold”), and • home-currency-denominated bonds. On the liability side the central bank has two types of assets, 1. currency and 2. required reserves. Required reserves are accounts domestic banks must hold in the the central bank to be able to borrow money from the central bank. Currency plus required reserves make up what is called the “monetary base”. The liability side will also contain an accounting term, “net worth” to assure that the accounts balance. The balance sheet is presented in figure 2.3. If the central bank want to reduce the monetary base, it sells one of its assets to the public. When it wants to increase the money supply, it buys assets from the public. 33 Figure 1.8: The balance sheet of the central bank Assets Liabilities Net foreign-currency bonds Monetary base Net domestic-currency bonds Net worth Foreign money Gold 1.5.1 Models without money Although we have spent much time in this lecture on the topic of money, one will usually find that discussions of monetary policy is conducted in models that do not contain the term money at all. The reason is that is very difficult to establish stable econometric relationships between the money and other variables in the economy. The lack of stable money aggregates make money of little use in practical policy. Indeed, attempts to focus on the money supply, as was conducted by e.g. the Bank of England in the early 1980’s, failed. Instead of targeting money, most central banks today target the inflation rate, and use the interest rate as instrument, not the money supply.6 However, the central bank’s control of short term nominal interest rates ultimately stems from its ability to control the quantity of base money in existence. If some power different from the central bank could control M , 6 The ECB makes one important exception. They have continued the tradition from the Bundesbank, and keep an official target for money growth. 34 then this power could directly affect monetary policy. One should also note that although modern monetary theory looks like a theory with no money, it still rests on the assumption that in the long run inflation is a monetary phenomena. 1.6 Appendix Proof of equation (1.19). T ∞ 1 X η 1 X η pt = m+ m0 1 + η s=t 1 + η 1 + η s=T 1 + η ∞ ∞ η 1 X η 1 X pt = m+ m0 − m 1 + η s=t 1 + η 1 + η s=T 1 + η ∞ 1 X η m0 − m pt = m + 1 + η s=T 1 + η "∞ X # T X 1 η η pt = m + m0 − m − 1 + η s=t 1 + η 1+η s=t pt = m + η 1+η T −t 1− 1 (1 + η) − m0 − m η 1+η 1 − 1+η " T −t # 1 η pt = m + (1 + η) − (1 + η) + (1 + η) m0 − m 1+η 1+η " T −t # 1 η pt = m + (1 + η) m0 − m 1+η 1+η 35 pt = m + η 1+η T −t 36 m0 − m Chapter 2 International money 2.1 Some final remarks on the importance of money In Lecture 1 we discussed the nature of money. The value of the currency we hold at a given point of time depends on how much we can purchase for this amount. If the price level increases, our currency loses value. The value of money depends on the price level. Currency is an asset were the level of return is given by inflation. The higher inflation, the lower the return on holding currency, as high inflation implies a falling value of your currency holdings. Several points were made in the first lecture: • For all types of money, even for a commodity currency, there is a need for trust between the issuer of a currency and the holder of currency for the currency to be accepted. • The Cagan model showed us that the trust in a currency depends on the future expected supply of the currency. This implies that money is an asset—its value depends on expectations of the future. 37 • Our example of seignorage revealed that a fiat currency is indeed only a product supplied by a monopolist. However, for this monopolist to maximise profit, given perfect foresight, there is an absolute limit to how fast money supply can grow. This limit depends on the semielasticity of money demand in expected inflation. The value of money depend on the credibility of the issuer of money. In that respect money does not differ from other assets we are holding, like bank deposits, bonds or equity. However, why are money special? Two things make the credibility issue of special importance when we talk about money: 1. Money is one of the few assets that encompass the whole economy. 2. For many people money the only financial asset they hold. For them money is an asset with no alternatives. For a large group of people, especially among the poor, financial markets are incomplete. Most important are perhaps that the poor have difficulties getting loans. This implies that they do not posses the credit necessary to buy e.g. their own home. For these people money or short term deposits are the only store of value. Further, almost all expenses are based on nominal prices. If prices rise very fast, wages tend to lag prices. At the same time their holdings of money are diminished by inflation. Loans are and real assets are both a hedge against inflation. Even though interest rise, the cost of a loan tends to fall if inflation is high, because a loan is fixed in nominal terms. The price of real assets should be expected to rise with inflation. The value of the holdings of money is however diminished by inflation. 38 The problem of incomplete financial markets grow the less sophisticated the financial market is. One implication is that instability in the value of money might is especially costly in developing countries. 2.2 Introduction to a discussion on international money In the first lecture we argued that the economy needed money; something that could work as a unit of account, means of payment, and also be a store of value. It was also pointed out that the value of money depended on the use of money. However, why are money national? There has always (i.e. as long as there has existed money) existed international money—means of payment accepted across borders. However, generally small change and money used in daily transactions have been national currency. That is probably a question of both trust, standards and, with the emergence of a national state, the ability of a government to impose a monopoly. • If e.g. gold is used as a currency, everyone must agree on a weight unit if gold is going to work as a unit of account. However, weight measures have traditionally differed between countries. • The value of money is a question of trust in the institution that has issued the money. Proximity traditionally increases the ability to trust. • The revenue from seignorage has been an important factor when governments have imposed a state monopoly in currency issuance. Would it be optimal to have only one currency? One has compared a currency to a language: the more people who use a language, the more useful 39 does it get. But would it be optimal for everyone to speak the same language? In a world where communication is difficult, languages get specialised. Even if one starts up with one language, the different needs of different areas turn a common language into different dialects, and over time into distinct languages. In the current world, with easy communication over long distances a common language could probably be an option. However, is it optimal? Perhaps one would have created only one language if we could redraw the world from scratch. Given that multiple languages already exist it would probably not be optimal to impose one language on everyone. However, for international communication only a few languages are in fact actively used. These function as “international languages”. This is also the case with money: side by side there exists national currencies and international monies. In this lecture we will discuss what determines the use and value of currencies in international markets. How is the value of national currencies determined? How does monetary policy affect the value of an exchange rate? And what is the role of international money? 2.3 The relationship between the national currency and the international currency In the last lecture we used the Cagan model to say something about the relationship between money and prices. However, one can also use the Cagan model to get an understanding of how a currency is priced in international markets. This is a starting point for our discussion of monetary policy and exchange rates. 40 2.3.1 A model of the exchange rate General assumptions We can use the Cagan model to derive a monetary model of the exchange rate. However, we want the model to be more general than the one we discussed in the first lecture, so we reintroduce nominal interest rates and real income in the equation. If we assume that expected inflation is low or non-existing, we can write the demand for real money balances on log-form as mt − pt = −ηit+1 + φyt . Here i is the nominal interest rate 1 (2.1) and y is real output. We want to find a link between the model of money and the exchange rate. Let us first define the exchange rate , as the price of one unit of foreign currency denominated in domestic currency. This is the standard denomination in most countries2 . It implies that · (domestic currency) = (one unit f oreign currency). (2.2) Note that seen from the point of view of the home country, a higher exchange rate implies that the home currency has depreciated, or has lost value. A higher exchange rate means that it takes more units of the home currency to buy one unit of the foreign currency. Similarly, a lower exchange rate implies an appreciation of the home currency. Also note that the log of will have the label e. To be able to say anything about an exchange rate we need to make two assumptions, linking the value of local money to the value of foreign money. 1 Formally measured as log of 1+i, where i is the nominal interest rate. One exception is Great Britain, where a currency is usually quoted as units of foreign currency that is needed for the purchase of GBP 1. 2 41 If we shall be able to say something about relative prices we must assume • free trade, and • free capital mobility. Unless these two requirements are fulfilled, the monetary model will not give a good empirical fit. However, what does these two assumptions imply for our model? 1. The assumption of free trade makes it possible to assume purchasing power parity, or PPP. PPP implies that the exchange rate between two countries shall equal the relative ratio of the price levels between two countries, Pt = t Pt∗ , (2.3) where is the exchange rate and P ∗ is the foreign price level. On logs (2.3) can be expressed as pt = et + p∗t . (2.4) The PPP states that the price level should be the same in all countries if prices are re-calculated to one currency. One way to look at this is through the “law of one price”. LOP states that if a good is priced differently in two countries, arbitrage would assure that the good is bought in the country where it is cheap, and transported to the country where it is expensive. Over time this should trade away the price difference. There is a number of problems concerning the PPP. Although there is free trade of many physical products, there are e.g. restrictions on the trade of labour, so one should assume it to be considerable price 42 differences in labour intensive products. This is taken account of in the “Balassa-Samuelson” model, presented in your prior macro course. However, for the time being we assume the PPP to hold. 2. If markets are efficient, free capital mobility should assure that the return on capital assets are equalised between currencies. This relationship is formalised in the uncovered interest rate parity (UIP), that can be written as 1 + it+1 = Et 1 + i∗t+1 t+1 t . (2.5) What does the UIP say? It states that the expected return on investment should be independent on the currency the bond is denominated in. If I hold NOK I should get the same return if I invested my money in a Norwegian bond, or if I exchanged NOK for EUR today, invested in a perfectly similar bond in the Euro zone, and exchanged back to NOK after the bond came up for payment. Why should this hold? If there is perfect foresight it should hold by pure arbitrage. If one expected a higher return in EUR-bonds than in NOK bonds, everyone would buy EUR-bonds, depressing the interest rate on such bonds. On logs the UIP can be written as it+1 − i∗t+1 = Et et+1 − et . (2.6) Deriving the exchange rate If we substitute equations (2.4) and (2.6) into equation (11.31) we obtain mt − (p∗t + et ) = −η(Et et+1 − et + i∗t+1 ) + φyt . 43 (2.7) Again we assume perfect foresight, so that we can dispose of the expectation term. Then equation (2.7 can be rewritten as et = 1 (mt − φyt + ηi∗t+1 − p∗t ) + ηet+1 . 1+η (2.8) If you remember back to lecture 1, you will see that this is the same difference equation as we derived in the stochastic Cagan hyperinflation model. The only change is that we have exchanged p with e and m with (m−φy+ηi∗ −p∗ ). In the same way as we solved for p in lecture 1 we can now solve for e. The solution will be s−t T ∞ η η 1 X ∗ ∗ et = (ms − φys + ηis+1 − ps ) + lim et+T . T →∞ 1 + η s=t 1 + η 1+η (2.9) As in the case of the solution for the price level we obtain two terms. The last term is a potential bubble term. A rational model with perfect foresight, and where the PPP and the UIP hold at every point of time is not enough to be certain that bubbles does not exist. However, it is usual to assume that lim T →∞ η 1+η T et+T = 0. (2.10) If so we can express the exchange rate as s−t ∞ 1 X η et = (ms − φys + ηi∗s+1 − p∗s ). 1 + η s=t 1 + η (2.11) We see that an increase in the money stock will lead to a higher exchange rate. In other words, an increase in the money stock leads to a depreciation as a higher rate implies that you must pay more for foreign currency because the local currency loses value. A lower money stock will imply a stronger exchange rate. Higher output will imply a stronger currency. However, if foreign interest rates rise, the currency will depreciate. 44 Implications As we will later discuss, this model does not have a very good empirical fit in the short term. Whether this is due to • the fact that the assumptions of free trade and free capital mobility do not hold, • whether it is due to a bad model specification, • whether it is due to bubbles actually being a factor, • whether it is due to public interference not captured in the model, • whether we do not understand how expectations are formed, or • whether markets are just not as rational as this model assumes, is not easy to tell. These are important questions in current economic research. However, a monetary model of this type is not an unreasonable approximation to the exchange rate in the long term. And there are several important implications that can be derived from the monetary approach. 1. The exchange rate must be seen as an asset price—the exchange rate depends on the expectation of future variables. That is a very important finding. One should analyse the exchange rate in the same way as one analysis e.g. a stock or bond. In fact, we still know very little about how asset markets are actually priced. As we will find later in this course, this is also the case for exchange rates. 2. The exchange rate is determined by stocks, not flows. Up till the 1970’s 45 most models of supply and demand in the FX-market3 was based on a flow approach. Foreign exchange was seen as medium of exchange for executing international trade transactions. In this model the currency is treated as an asset—something that is infinitely durable, which can be transferred but not destroyed. One important implication of this shift: • in the flow approach exchange rate movements are expected to be sluggish, as flow specifications would be slow to change. • in the stock approach exchange rate movements are expected to be quick to reflect new information. The last is clearly a better description of a floating exchange rate than the first. 3. It is important to distinguish between different types of shocks. The consequence of a temporary shift in a variable will differ from the consequence of a permanent shift. Likewise, the consequence of an anticipated shock will be differ from the consequence of an unanticipated shock. In the last lecture we distinguished between an unexpected and expected shock. Let us see how a permanent shock will differ from a temporary shock. • Let y, i∗ and p∗ all equal zero4 , and assume that there is no bubble. Assume that at time T the government announces a permanent change in the money supply. Then the exchange rate must rise equiproportionate 3 This is the short term for “the foreign exchange market”—the markets where currencies are traded. 4 As these are on logarithmic form, setting a value equal to zero implies setting the actual value equal to one. As you know, ln(1) = 0. 46 with the money stock, i.e. m, t < T mt = m0 , t ≥ T , (m0 > m). (2.12) implies that et = m, t < T (2.13) m0 , t ≥ T . • Assume that at time T the government announces a temporary increase in the money supply. However, at T the money supply reverts to its level before T : m, t < T mt = m0 , t ∈ T , T (m0 > m) m, t > T . We find that the path of the exchange rate becomes5 m, t < T T −t 0 − m) < m0 , t ∈ T , T et = m0 − η (m 1+η m, t > T . (2.14) (2.15) The price level will make a jump in period T . However, the jump will be less than if the shock was permanent. The exchange rate will then fall, just to reach its previous level at time T . Both cases are illustrated in figure 2.1. 5 Proof provided in the appendix. 47 Figure 2.1: Temporary vs. permanent shock to the money supply e m' m T_ 2.3.2 T time Choice of exchange rate regime Let us assume two extreme cases. 1. The government fixes the exchange rate, i.e. et+1 = et . For simplification we set = 1, which implies e = 0 ⇒ (2.16) pt = p∗t and it+1 = i∗t+1 . It follows that mt = p∗t − ηi∗t+1 + φyt . (2.17) → the money stock that is necessary to support a fixed exchange rate is determined by changes in real output, foreign prices and foreign interest rates. The central bank must adjust the money supply accordingly. For the fixed exchange rate regime to be credible the central bank must let 48 the money supply be endogenous. 2. The government fixes the money supply. The money supply is the only variable the central banks can control directly in this system. Fixing the money supply is the most extreme example of an exogenous rule for money supply. For simplicity we assume the central banks sets m = 0.6 Using the equations above, we obtain that the exchange rate is given by s−t ∞ 1 X η (−φys + ηi∗s+1 − p∗s ). et = 1 + η s=t 1 + η (2.18) The central bank can not influence any of the variables in equation (11.43). This implies that the exchange rate become an endogenous variable—it is determined within the system. The exchange rate is outside the control of the central bank. The central bank can not control the money supply and the exchange rate at the same time. 2.4 The central bank and the supply of money A choice of exchange rate regime is the same as a choice of a rule for money growth. But how do the central bank affect the money supply in the first place? 2.4.1 The balance sheet of the central bank The government is often seen as one entity in economic models. It should not matter that one public institution has a surplus on its books, if another 6 This is not the same as setting money supply to zero. Remember that m = log(M ), and that log1 = 0. 49 Figure 2.2: Fixed exchange rate vs. fixed money supply. Consequences of a shock to output Fixed exchange rate e y0 y1 e y2 Fixed money supply y0 e0 m0 m1 m2 e1 y1 e2 y2 m m m A shock to output will have different consequences depending on the choice of target in the monetary policy. public institution has a deficit. What matters are the net position over all government institutions. However, in monetary matters it is useful to distinguish between the “fiscal authority” and the “central bank”. In fact this distinction is artificial. As long as the central bank is publicly owned, it is part of the governments balance sheet. Money, a liability on the central bank, is at the same time a liability on the government. However, because money is so important for the workings of the modern economy, there tends to be a separation between government expenditure and the central bank. If there was no separation between the central bank and the government, the government would have two choices if it needed to finance a deficit: • it could issue more money, or • it could issue bonds. 50 An independent central bank is supposed to be a guarantee against monetary financing of public expenditure. However note that the distinction between issuing bonds and money is only a “veil”. If the central bank issues money to purchases government bonds, the two cases are exactly the same. In most advanced economies there is a tight wall separating the fiscal and monetary authorities. If the government uses money to finance public deficits, the money will loose value, and no longer fulfill its purposes as unit of account, means of payment and store of value. In the long term the cost of undermining the value of money exceeds the potential gains from financing public deficits by printing money. However, leading experts on monetary economics (like Michael Woodford) have argued that a target for inflation will only be credible if there is some target for public spending as well. Over time the one needs to see the government accounts from a consolidated standpoint—and one can not expect that the central bank balances its book if other parts of the government do not balance their books. A central bank typically holds four types of assets. These are • claims on foreign entities, i.e. – foreign currency, and – foreign-currency-denominated bonds. • gold (although the stock of gold has been reduced in the later years) and SDR’s (claims on the International Monetary Fund, so-called “paper gold”), and • home-currency-denominated bonds. On the liability side the central bank has two types of assets, 1. currency and 51 Figure 2.3: The balance sheet of the central bank Assets Liabilities Net foreign-currency bonds Monetary base Net domestic-currency bonds Net worth Foreign money Gold 2. required reserves. Required reserves are accounts domestic banks must hold in the the central bank to be able to borrow money from the central bank. Currency plus required reserves make up what is called the “monetary base”. The liability side will also contain an accounting term, “net worth” to assure that the accounts balance. The balance sheet is presented in figure 2.3. 2.4.2 Central bank interventions If the central bank want to reduce the monetary base, it sells one of its assets to the public. When it wants to increase the money supply, it buys assets from the public. The central bank can adjust money supply in two ways: 1. it can intervene in the FX-market by buying or selling currency, or 2. it can change the short-term interest rates. 52 The first alternative implies a change in the holdings of the foreign currency denominated assets held by the central bank. The second alternative implies a change in some of the domestic currency denominated assets of the central bank. However, in theory these types of interventions are equivalent. To see this, remember that for every change made on the asset side of the central bank’s balance sheet, an equivalent change needs to made on the liability side. If the central bank intervenes in the FX-market by selling foreign currency, it must at the same time reduce its liabilities. So the stock of currency falls. This implies an increase in the interest rate Likewise, a change in the interest rate will be an indirect change in the money supply. When the central bank increases an interest rate it offers government bonds in the market at the new rate. When the central bank sells a bond, it gets domestic currency in return. The supply of domestic currency in the market will fall, and the supply of bonds will increase. The money supply will contract. In fact the central bank will not set an exact target for neither exchange rate nor money supply. In a fixed exchange rate regime the exchange rate will be allowed to fluctuate inside a defined target zone. If demand for the currency increases, the currency will appreciate. If demand shift so much that the going rate will be at the boundary of the target zone, the central bank will adjust money supply to keep the exchange rate within the target zone. In a inflation targeting regime the central bank will (indirectly) target the money supply. The money supply shall be kept inside a certain band. the central bank will no longer intervene in the markets because of fluctuations in the exchange rate. Rather it will intervene because of fluctuations in the money supply. The choice between an inflation target and an exchange rate 53 Figure 2.4: A fixed exchange rate target e D ehigh elow S m 54 Figure 2.5: A price level target e D S m low m high m target will therefore imply a choice between price volatility and exchange rate volatility. Sterilised vs. unsterilised interventions In the discussion above I assume that the central bank uses interventions to change the domestic money supply. Such an intervention will affect prices and interest rates. However, in many instances the central bank would like to influence the exchange rate without affecting prices and interest rates. A sterilised intervention means that while the central bank e.g. buy NOK 55 in the foreign exchange market it will simultaneously buy bonds (or in the Norwegian case, something called F-loans). In other words, when the central bank reduces its holdings of foreign currency assets, it will at the same time increase its holdings of domestic currency assets. That way it leaves the total supply of NOK unaffected. However, in our model only an actual change in m can affect the exchange rate. In the monetary model presented above, sterilised interventions make no sense. Two reasons have been presented for why sterilised interventions might work. 1. Portfolio balance effects: if investors believe that foreign and domestic assets are imperfect substitutes, a change in the relative supply of foreign and domestic assets might have real effects. 2. Signaling: an intervention, even if it is sterilised, can signal to the market that the central bank believe the exchange rate to be out of bounds. Unless the market corrects this itself, the central bank might go in with real interventions in the future. Economist often argue that the effect of sterilised interventions are low. However, central banks continue to use them. Making things even more curious, most interventions are done in secret, which should in fact reduce the signaling effect. 2.5 Appendix Proof of equation (2.15). T ∞ X 1 X η 1 η pt = m0 + m 1 + η s=t 1 + η 1+η 1+η s=T 56 International Monetary System 2. Banking system . LOUIS EDERALSt. RESERVE BANK of STFed): A discussion of sterilized intervention (from Fthe Louis Figure 2.6: From the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis: STERILIZED INTERVENTION Stylized Balance Sheet of the U.S. Monetary Authorities Assets Liabilities Foreign exchange reserves 1$100 million (1) U.S. government securities 2$100 million (2) Because exchange rates are important prices that influence the time path of inflation and output, central banks often intervene in the foreign exchange market, buying and selling currency to influence exchange rates. Such intervention typically is sterilized, meaning that the central bank reverses the effects of the foreign exchange transactions on the monetary base.1 For example, if the Federal Reserve Bank of New York— following the instructions of the Treasury and the Federal Open Market Committee—purchased $100 million worth of euros, the U.S. monetary base—composed of U.S. currency in circulation plus deposits of depository institutions at the Federal Reserve Banks—would increase by $100 million in the absence of sterilization. This transaction is illustrated in the stylized balance sheet items marked as (1). To prevent changes in domestic interest rates and prices, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York also would sell $100 million worth of government securities—sterilizing the intervention by reducing deposits with the Federal Reserve—to absorb the liquidity. This transaction is marked as (2) in the balance sheet. To prevent euro-denominated short-term interest rates from rising, the European Central Bank would have to conduct similar open market purchases of euro-denominated securities to increase its money stock to completely sterilize the original transaction. The final net effect of such a sterilized intervention would be to increase the relative supply of U.S. government securities versus euro-denominated securities on the market. Because sterilized intervention does not affect the U.S. monetary base or interest rates, it cannot Currency plus deposits held with the Federal Reserve 1$100 million (1) 2$100 million (2) influence the exchange rate through price or interest rate channels. It might, however, affect the exchange rate through the portfolio balance channel and/or the signaling channel. The reasoning behind the portfolio balance channel is that if foreign and domestic bonds are imperfect substitutes, investors must be compensated with a higher expected return to hold the relatively more numerous bonds. In the example in which the Federal Reserve purchases euros/sells dollars (USD), the intervention must result in an immediate depreciation of the dollar that creates expectations of future appreciation, increasing the expected future return to dollar-denominated assets and convincing investors to hold the greater quantity of them. The signaling channel, on the other hand, suggests that official intervention communicates to the market information about future monetary policy or the long-run equilibrium value of the exchange rate. A purchase of euros/sale of dollars may signal to the markets that the central bank considers the dollar’s current value to be too high given current and expected future policy. The consensus of the research on sterilized intervention is that any influence intervention has on the exchange rate is weak and temporary.2 1 2 Unsterilized intervention is equivalent to domestic monetary policy and therefore is often implicitly excluded from discussions of the efficacy of intervention. Humpage (1999) provides some evidence that U.S. intervention may influence dollar exchange rates. central banks keep interventions secret? Taylor possibility that central banks are reluctant to release (1982a and 1982b) suggests that the practice dates such information because they are trying to avoid back to the Bretton-Woods era of fixed exchange accountability. Finally, it is possible that secret interrates, when reports of intervention could trigger a 15 ventions—or at least concealing the size of interrun on the currency. Given that the practice has vention—may make the transaction more effective persisted for more than 25 years after the end of 57 in influencing the exchange rate in certain circumfixed exchange rates, one also must consider the stances (Bhattacharya and Weller, 1997). S EPTEMBER /O CTOBER 2000 21 T −t X ∞ T 1 − X η 1 η 1 0 m − pt = m + η 1 + η 1 + η 1 + η 1+η 1 − 1+η s=t s=t η 1+η " pt = 1 (1 + η) − (1 + η) 1+η pt = m0 − pt = η 1+η T −t # η 1+η T −t η 1+η m0 − " m0 + 1 (1 + η) 1+η T −t m0 + 58 η 1+η T −t m0 − m m η 1+η T −t # m Chapter 3 Exchange rate regimes 3.1 Relating the national currency to the international currency market If a country wants to trade with an other country without adopting the other country’s currency, there needs to be some mechanism that assures that a currency can be used for international transactions. Most important, it must be some system for converting the local currency into other currencies. The government has three measures to assure international convertibility. 1. It can use coercion or control—all trade with abroad must be approved, and conducted at a given rate. This was the system in Europe after the Second World War, in the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe until 1989, and is still the case in some developing countries. 2. It can commit to a certain fixed exchange rate, and guarantee that it will use all measures to defend that rate. 3. It can depend on the trust of the markets, and let the market set the rate. If trade is severely restricted, coercion is the only way to assure some 59 balance in currency flows. However, most developed economies allow a relatively high degree of free trade. This leaves the choice between commitment and a free float. Classical economic doctrine argues that markets will give the optimal solution. However, for this to be true markets need to have a certain degree of liquidity and a sufficient number of participants to work effectively. If these requirements do not hold, markets can be manipulated. Whether this is a real problem in the FX-market is uncertain. But remember that the financial market of small and/or developing countries are often very small compared to the financial markets of large and/or developed countries. There are a number of American funds managers that control resources that exceeds the total Norwegian GDP—and measured in GDP Norway is a large country. Second, and perhaps more important for political decision makers, open markets might imply serious limitations on the degrees of freedom in national policies, as the exchange rate is vulnerable to swings in the moods of market participants. This have lead governments to limit the mobility of capital. If capital flows are limited, it is possible to achieve some degree of freedom in monetary policy at the same time as the exchange rate is fixed This is because the UIP will not hold if capital can not move freely. However, most economist believe that it is impossible to have both an independent monetary policy, a fixed exchange rate and free mobility of capital at the same time. For the markets to work properly, the national economy must be developed and financial markets sufficiently sophisticated. In fact, the combination of a fiat currency and free convertibility was first introduced in the early 1970’s. Before that all forms of currency exchange across boarders had imposed either coercion or commitment to guarantee the value of the currency. 60 3.1.1 A short history of exchange rate regimes “The gold standard” describes a system where national currencies were convertible to gold at fixed rates. This implied that the exchange rates were fixed as well. The gold standard was in existence from about 1870 to 1914, although it worked properly only in the first part of that period. This was a period with very strong commitment. Even if a “crisis” of some kind made a country unable to fulfill the requirements of the gold convertibility for a certain period, it was usual for governments to make a strong effort to return to the previous parity after the crisis had ended. At the same time it was little or no coercion, as there existed no limitations on capital flows.1 During the First World War most countries abolished the convertibility to gold, and instead imposed strong coercion, as trade flows was restricted. After the war many countries attempted to return to their old parity values. However, as prices had risen quite extensively during the war, a return to parity implied that prices had to be deflated. This became a very costly affair for a number of countries, Norway included. Britain, the leading country in international relations up till the First World War, managed to restore the old parity in the late 1920’s, only to be forced of gold in 1931. Commitment was soon again replaced by control and coercion. During the 1930’s many countries restricted the flow of goods, and limited trade to bilateral agreements. In 1944 a number of economists met at the Bretton Woods Hotel in upstate New York. There it was worked out an agrement on how the exchange 1 As we will see later in this course, according to some measures capital flows was larger per unit of output in the year 1900 than in the year 2000. It can also be noted that Great Britain, which as the leading economy of the world at that time had a vested interest in a stable foreign exchange market, intervened heavily in support of other currencies under pressure. Great Britain worked as a stabiliser in the world markets, to some degree filling the role the IMF has today. 61 Figure 3.1: Commitment versus coercion in the exchange rate system coercion Norway, 1945, Early Bretton Woods Most small open economies today USA, Japan, Germany after 1973 Norway, 1990, USA 1945-1973 commitment 62 rate system should work after the war. To make a long history very short, the gold standard (where every currency was convertible into gold) was exchanged with a “dollar-gold” standard: all currencies was to be convertible into USD, and USD was to be convertible into gold at a given rate (USD 35 per ounce of gold).2 The International Monetary Fund (IMF) was founded to oversee the international currency system. After the Second World War there was a large demand for investments in most European countries. At the same time many people had money they wanted to spend on luxury imports from abroad (i.e. the US). European governments were afraid that if they let people exchange home currency into USD without restrictions, to much of private spending would be used on the imports of luxury goods, and not enough on more important investment. It was therefore enforced quite strong restrictions on capital movements and the private exchange of currency. As currencies was not freely convertible balance in international trade could not be left to the markets. To balance trade between two countries can be compared with a barter economy on the country level—each country must accept what the other has to offer, or there will be no trade. To make the system more flexible one therefore institutionalised a multilateral payment system—e.g. if Norway had a trade deficit versus Denmark and trade surplus versus Great Britain, while Denmark had a deficit versus Great Britain, this could be netted out in the system. Payments and receipts were handled by the Bank of International Settlements (BIS) in Basel. By the end of the 1950’s the financial system was stable enough to allow for free convertibility. By the end of the 1960’s great strain was put on the system. Bretton Woods collapsed in early September 1971. In 1973 the big currencies (USD, 2 This was a natural solution, as 70 per cent of all gold reserves in 1945 was held by the Federal Reserve System. 63 JPY, DEM and GBP) was allowed to float. It was predicted that this would result in reduced international trade and more financial uncertainty. That does not seem to have happened. By 1973 the major economies had established trust in their economic policies. Increased volatility could probably be handled as long as there was certainty about the long-term value of the currencies. However, in parallel with the experience of floating exchange rates between the large currencies, one saw an co-operation to stabilise exchange rates at the regional level. European economies worked out an “exchange rate snake”, a system that was supposed to reduce volatility between European currencies. The “snake” evolved into the European Monetary System—a system of stabilising the currencies of the member countries towards a common currency basket, defined as the ECU. On paper all countries in the EMS was supposed to support each other if any one country faced pressure against the fixed rate. However, in practice EMS was a fairly flexible system, that allowed for frequent changes in the exchange rates between countries. And while Germany was the country in the EMS with the lowest inflation, and also the most credible monetary policy, Germany became “first among equals”. In practice the EMS looked like a system for fixing European currencies to the value of the DEM. In the end of the 1980’s EMS changed character. EMS was now described as the forerunner to the future European currency union that was expected to be established sometime during the 1990’s. As a first step in this process the flexibility in the EMS was reduced. From 1987 until 1992 the EMS worked as a pure fixed exchange rate system. However, in 1992 severe speculative attacks forced many countries to leave the EMS. Despite this seeming setback the process towards the EMU continued, and a common European 64 currency with 11 (currently 12) members was established January 1, 1999. The national bills and coins where exchanged with bills and coins denominated in EUR from January 1, 2002. The transformation was completed within the end of February 2002. 3.1.2 Types of exchange rate regimes A country can choose between a number of different regimes for the exchange rate. Note that when we e.g. say that the USD is a floating currency, we mean that the federal Reserve will not attempt to reduce short-term volatility in the USD. However, the USD might still be fixed against a number of currencies, simply because many countries choose to stabilise their currencies against the USD. This will be unilateral pegs. Also note that an exchange rate regime must be defined not for a currency, but for an exchange rate cross. If Argentina has fixed its currency to the USD this does not imply that the the ARP (Argentinean peso) has a fixed value in the market. It only means that the currency cross ARP/USD will be fixed. The ARP will be floating with regard to all currencies that are floating with regard to the USD. E.g the ARP/EUR will be a floating rate, as the USD/EUR rate is floating. One can describe seven different types of exchange rate regimes: 1. A floating rate. The central banks make no attempt to stabilise the exchange rate in the short run. (Examples: USD/EUR, JPY/USD) 2. A managed float. There exist some statement that the central bank will not allow to much fluctuation in the exchange rate. If the exchange deviates much from a target value, the central bank might make limited interventions, either in the form of interest changes or in the form of direct currency interventions. (Example: NOK/ECU (1993-1998(?))) 65 3. Multilateral exchange rate pegs. Several countries agree to stabilise their currencies against each other. The currencies shall fluctuate within predetermined bounds. All countries retain an independent monetary policy. However for the country to remain in the system, monetary policy must be adjusted according to the monetary policy of the system as a whole. Mostly a multilateral peg is dominated by a single country. The countries are obligated to support each other if there is a speculative attack against any one country. If one country wants to make an adjustment in its exchange rate, the other countries in the system must be informed in advance. (Example: the European Monetary System (EMS)—European currencies were stabilised against ECU) 4. Unilateral peg. One country fixes its currency to some other currency. There is no obligation from the other country with regard to interventions. (Example: NOK/ECU from 1990 to 1992). However, more often a country fixes the value of its currency to a “currency basket”—an index value of several currencies. The basket weights are often based on the composition of trading partners. (Example: NOK, SEK and FIM in the 1980’s) 5. Currency board. The currency is fixed completely to the value of another currency. There is no allowance for a target zone as in a multilateral or unilateral peg. The central bank promises to exchange the local currency into the foreign currency at the fixed rate, and must have sufficient reserves to make this promise credible. There is no longer an independent monetary policy. The only role of the central bank is to adjust the level of reserves to assure that the fix remains credible at 66 every point of time. The central bank can no longer adjust the money stock in periods of e.g. banking crises, and can therefore no longer work as credible lender of last resort. A speculative attack against a currency board can therefore often take the face of a speculative attack against banks (as in e.g. Argentina). 6. Dollarisation. The local economy adopts a foreign currency as its own. All local currency must be exchanged at a given rate, and destructed. All contracts must be re-denominated in the foreign currency. There is no central bank in the sense of a monetary authority. All monetary policy is made in the country of the adopted currency, without consideration for local needs. (Examples: Ecuador and Panama have adopted the USD. The Jugoslav province of Montenegro has adopted the EUR.) 7. Currency unions. Several countries come together and create a common currency. A new central bank is created. Monetary policy is to be adjusted for the best of the currency union as a whole. (Example: EMU) Note that the distinctions between these groups are not strict. Even in a floating currency like the USD monetary authorities will from time to time make interventions to adjust what is perceived as “extreme misalignments”. One example is the so called Louvre Accord in 1985 when the G-7 agreed that the USD was overvalued. In the following months the USD depreciated extensively. A currency board will often be followed by dollarisation of much of the economy. There will almost always remain uncertainty about the long-term prospects of the board. Many will therefore chose to use foreign currency instead of the home currency as a store of value. 67 If any exchange rate peg shall be successful, one must keep the inflation close to the inflation in country to which the currency is targeted. In shorter periods, an exchange rate peg can survive even if monetary policy is not fixed. In the long run a fixed exchange rate does demand a common monetary policy. As most exchange rate pegs are in reality unilateral, that will normally imply that the smaller country must adopt the monetary policy of the larger country if a fixed currency shall be credible. Over longer periods of time this only observed in very few cases. The Austrian peg to DEM is one of a few such instances. Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995) find that only a few so-called fixed exchange rates indeed had been fixed for more than 10 years. Unilateral exchange rate system will generally be unstable, as a fixed exchange rate by definition demands some sort of common monetary policy. This is first solved if the unilateral system evolves into a currency union. 3.1.3 Optimal currency areas Lack of credibility has made governments turn to fixed exchange rates to assure convertibility. However, a fixed exchange rate might leave the open for sudden adjustments, so-called currency crises (to which we return in the next lecture). Although day-to-day volatility is less than in a flexible regime, the volatility over time might be high if one has to leave the exchange rate system at some time. This leaves us with the question of why a country needs an independent currency at all. In general one would at least keep a currency area as large as the area of political independence—i.e. an optimal currency area will at least contain the national borders of one country. That is not to say that the borders of this “political area” necessarily comprise the borders of the “optimal currency area”. From the OCA theory it might well be that e.g. the US should have 68 had more than one currency. In practice political realities always overrule the OCA-theory. If multinational organisations get a strong hand in national decision making, one can extend the optimal currency area to the extension of the whole (or parts) of the organisation, as has been done in the EU through the European Monetary Union, EMU. The main benefits of entering a common currency have been listed to be that a currency union • reduce transaction costs from currency conversion, • reduce accounting costs and give greater predictability of relative prices for firms doing business with firms in the other countries of the currency area, • if prices are sticky, insulate from monetary disturbances that could affect real exchange rates, and • reduce political pressure for trade protection based on swings in the exchange rate. For a small open economy the first two points are probably the most important. The potential costs of joining an optimal currency area include to • forgo the possibility to use monetary policy to respond to regionalspecific real shocks. Remember that if the exchange rate is fixed, the money supply is endogenous. It can no longer be adjusted by the government. • Further, one can no longer inflate away public debt or increase revenues by extracting more seignorage. 69 In the end the choice of the size of currency unions remains a political one. The more integrated an area is, the less will the costs of a common currency be, and the higher will the potential gains be. However, areas that are tightly integrated economically, are often tightly integrated in other dimensions as well. How integrated an area needs to be for a currency union to work is uncertain. However, with increasing ease of communication, many of the traditional arguments for national currencies disappear. There is for example difficult to see why the citizens of EMU should trust the ECB less than they trusted their former central banks. 3.1.4 The death of fixed exchange rates? To assure an efficient flow of trade it is necessary that there is some sort of convertibility between the national currency and the international currency. If the national currency is not accepted abroad the country reverts to defacto barter trade. This is the case for e.g. North Korea. Almost all trade with North Korea is in the form of bilateral trade agreements—North Korea gets a certain amount of one good against the delivery of a certain amount of North Korean goods. Until the early 1970’s it was accepted that to assure growth in trade there had to some sort of fixed relationship between currencies to avoid to much uncertainty. The actual experience after 1970, with more liberalised capital flows, has shown us that • floating exchange rates, although volatile, does not seem to be destabilising for world trade nor financial flows as long as there is sufficient trust in the governments issuing the currencies. For most developed countries a floating exchange rate does not seem to reduce national welfare. 70 • With free capital flows speculative attacks cause abrupt adjustments in fixed exchange rates. These adjustments might be very destabilising. Many economist argue that the danger of such adjustments make fixed exchange rates very unfortunate. A popular argument today is that one no longer can make a unilateral decision to peg a currency. According to this argument, there is only two options: • to float, or • to “super-fix” the exchange rate, either through a currency board, dollarisation or by joining a currency union. This view is captured by the following quote made by then U.S. Secretary of the Treasury, Larry Summers in 2000: “[F]or economies with access to international capital markets, [the choice of the appropriate exchange rate regime] increasingly means a move away from the middle ground of pegged but adjustable rates toward the two corner regimes of either flexible exchange rates, or a fixed exchange rate supported, if necessary, by a commitment to give up altogether an independent monetary policy. ... [This policy prescription] probably has less to do with Robert Mundell’s traditional optimal currency areas considerations than with a country’s capacity to operate a discretionary monetary policy in a way that will reduce rather than increase the variance in economic output.” From a historical perspective this view seems to be based more on a disillusionment with the intermediate alternatives—like pegged-but-adjustable 71 rates or managed floats, than the historical merits of either of the two corners. In fact, there are only a small number of countries that have attempted to “super fix” their exchange rate. Likewise, with the recent exception of Mexico, one has no good example of a developing market with a long experience of a floating exchange rate. The super-fixed exchange rate A super fixed exchange rate includes a currency board and dollarisation. Supporters of super-fixed exchange rates have argued that these arrangements provide • credibility, • transparency • very low inflation, and • financial stability. In addition, as in principle a super-fixed rate should reduce the risk of speculation and devaluation, domestic interest rates should be lower than under alternative regimes. The argument in favour of a super-fixed exchange rate is made even stronger if one can argue that there is a correlation between country risk and currency risk. Country risk is the risk of investing in a given country. This can be measured as the premium on long-term domestic government bonds relative to foreign government bonds. Country risk should, among other things depend on the long term prospects of a country. Currency risk is the risk of devaluation. This can, assuming the UIP to hold, be measured as the premium on short-term domestic interest rates over 72 foreign short-term interest rates. The argument is that a stable exchange rate results in an environment that is more conductive to long term growth. So low currency risk should lead to lower country risk. As can be seen from figure 3.2, it does seem to be a relationship between these two measures in the case of Argentina. However, several things must be in place for a super-fixed rate to be credible. • Fiscal solvency. In a super-fixed rate regime the government can no longer reduce the burden of public debt through inflation. This increases the need for fiscal responsibility. Also, as monetary policy can not be used for stabilisation purposes, there must be in place an ability to run counter-cyclical fiscal policy. • The lender of last resort function, which under flexible and pegged-butadjustable regimes is provided by the central bank, has to be delegated to some other institution. This can either be a consortium of foreign banks or some international organisation. • Related to the point above, there is a need for a very solid domestic banking sector, as the lender of last resort function will not function properly. • A currency board requires that the central bank holds enough reserves, an amount that in fact will exceed the monetary base. For a super-fixed exchange rate to succeed, all the above points need to be satisfied. However, even then super-fixed regime will not be without problems. There will always remain the possibility of a regime switch. If the cost of the regime increases, e.g. due to an external shock, this can create 73 61 Figure 4: Currency vs Country Risk Premia: Argentina, 1994-1999 Figure 3.2: Currency risk vs. country risk, Argentina 1994-1999 Country Risk Premium 15 10 5 0 -5 0 500 1000 1500 2000 Currency Risk Premium Source: Edwards, 2000 74 2500 uncertainty about the future of the regime. If investors start to move money out, domestic interest rates will increase, thereby further increasing the cost of maintaining a fixed regime. Argentina adopted a currency board early in 1991. At that point the Argentinean peso had lost confidence. In the late 1980’s the USD had become the de facto unit of account. For many types of purchases the USD worked as means of payment as well. The currency board fixed the exchange rate between ARP and USD at 1:1. The currency risk from 1993 to 1999 is illustrated in figure 3.3. In the early years of the board, Argentine inflation exceeded US inflation, leading to a real appreciation of the the ARP. Argentina was hit hard by the ripple effects of the Mexican devaluation (the “Tequila-crisis”) in late 1994. However, as the board survived this event, the confidence grew. Inflation stabilised, and Argentina faced deflation in 1999 and 2000. Argentina addressed the lender of last resort issue in three ways: • Banks were required to hold a very high level of reserves. • The central bank negotiated a substantial credit line with a consortium of international banks to be used in times of financial pressure. • Many of the domestic banks were taken over by foreign banks. Seven out of eight of Argentina’s largest banks were in 2000 owned by major international banks. An important problem in the case of Argentina was probably fiscal solvency. The Argentine government was not able to reform government in an efficient manner. Attempts of privatisation did not result in increased productivity, mainly because public monopolies were often exchanged for private monopolies. 75 62 Figure 3.3: Interest differential between peso and dollar denominated deposits 20 15 10 5 0 2/09/93 1/10/95 12/10/96 11/10/98 ARG_DIF Source: Edwards, 2000 Figure 5: Argentina, Interest Rate Differential between Peso and Dollar Denominated Deposits 76 (Weekly Data 1993-1999) Figure 3.4: Fiscal balance in Argentina, 1991-2001 Source: The Economist, 2002 77 At no time did expectations of devaluation disappear completely. The result was a certain interest differential between the ARP and the USD. One implication was that Argentineans choose to deposit money as ARP— as ARP’s got the highest interest rate. However, if they borrowed money, they borrowed USD, as the interest rate in USD was lower. This made the banking sector very vulnerable to the effects of a change in the currency board. So what happened in Argentina? We will return to that question in the next lecture. Argentina’s government did fulfill most requirements of a stable currency board. However, it evidently failed on two important accounts: it was not able to get full control of fiscal policy, and it was never able to remove all doubts about the long term viability of the regime, not even among their own people. In the end these two things terminated the regime. The floating exchange rate? If a super-fixed regime is so difficult to achieve, a floating exchange rate remains the alternative. Table 3.5 shows that over the last twenty years more and more countries have chosen managed or flexible exchange rate regime instead of a regime with an exchange rate peg or limited flexibility. However, recent empirical studies show that this apparent “floating” of exchange rates might not be as clear cut as the IMF data suggests. In fact, ? find that most developing countries that claim to have a float or a managed float do not let their exchange rate fluctuate much outside a band of +/-2.5 per cent— equivalent to pegged regime. This is even true for a number of industrialised countries including, until recently, Norway. Floating regimes resemble noncredible pegs—an observation Calvo and Reinhart attributes to a “fear of floating”. 78 "0% 34A Figure 3.5: Choice of exchange rate regime A 8$$1 8 @ % 1 % >C >C" " " "E >C I."> " ."> " >E .E"> "I ,C" E". >E ..". "I .I" " >> >", ."> ."I .I" >> ."> E". .E"> .E"> >>> " " ..". ,," Source: Calvo and Reinhart, 2000 Why should there be a fear of floating in emerging markets? This can probably be attributed to a lack of credibility. • A fixed exchange rate provides a more clear-cut nominal anchor, as the exchange rate is observable today. An inflation target will depend on expectations about future inflation rates—and if credibility is low this might result in higher interest rate volatility. • In emerging markets debts are often denominated in foreign currency. Large swings in exchange rates might impair the access to financial markets. Sharp depreciations can be very expensive as the cost of servicing debt rise. • The pass through from exchange rates to inflation is traditionally higher in emerging markets than in developed markets. There is an ongoing debate on the issue of fixed versus flexible exchange rates. Mainstream academic economists in the US and Europe, and the IMF, 79 Figure 3.6: Exchange rate volatility in recent of current “floating” exchange rate regimes !"#$ $ & '$()*#&$((( ./ !"#% !" #"! !" ! ) +,- 0$()%#1$((+ +) (-( '$(+,#&$((( 2) (-2 3 4$((-#&$((( ) (-* 5 6$((-#1$((+ %, + 4 1$((*#&$((( -*2 2-% 78 4$()%#&$((( -($ + 7 6$()2#4$((- -2* +*% 7 1$((#1$((* +( (%) &$((,#&$((( *% +$* '$())#&$((( 2,+ +*( 0& '$()-#&$((( -) 22 0 '$()*#4$()( %+) (-) 0 7/$((#&$((( -%$ +%% 9 '$((#&$((( %( ++( &/: 90' %$2+ +(+ 0/: 90' $+)- $$*$ 4 #&#; 3 '$((+#&$((( (% $*- 5 7/$((+#&$((( %( $++ '$((+#&$((( $*- -)$ Source: Calvo and Reinhart, 2000 80 Figure 3.7: Exchange rate volatility in recent of current “managed floating” - exchange rate regimes !"#$ !"#% $ ./ '$(()#&$((( .< '$((*#1$(() )-$ (*- 6$()#&$((( *%% )-) '$(+(#&$((( $%2 )2) =$(($#1$(() (%+ ()( > '$(++#1$((+ %)2 )%- 3 =$(+(#=$((- %-2 )*% 3 7/$(+)#'$((+ (2* (($ 3 1$(($#&$((( *%% (,( 5 '$(()#&$((( %$ +,2 5 4$(),#6$((+ ),$ (+2 4 1$((#0$(() %(* )$ 4 '$()(#7/$((* 2*- (%+ 7 '$((%#&$((( %2( (, ? '$()#&$((( ++) () 0 '$())#&$((( 2$% ))( ? '$(),#&$((( $2 -2) 9 '$((-#&$((( + ( < &$((2#&$((( 2,2 (-( &/: 90' 2,,% )+%* 0/: 90' %*- $*) Source: Calvo and Reinhart, 2000 81 !" #"! !" ! $,, $,, argue in support of flexible rate regimes. Many economists from developing countries, and some western economists as well, are in support of more fixed rates. As an example, several Asian countries have recently signed agreements to secure common interventions in the case of speculative attacks— certainly not what one would do in a floating exchange rate regime. For many countries some sort of fixed exchange rate regime is still the only option for gaining credibility in their monetary policies. 3.2 Why a fixed exchange rate system might be unstable As we seen in the above discussion, there are benefits and costs of having a fixed exchange rate. However, even if a fixed exchange rate seems like an optimal solution, it is difficult to retain a stable exchange rate. As we have noted, few exchange rates remain fixed for a long period of time. The n-1 problem illustrates a problem that occurs if two countries fix their common exchange rate. A fixed exchange rate implies that if one country changes its money supply, the other country must do so as well if the fixed exchange rate shall survive. The second problem occurs when different shocks implies different policy strategies in the two countries. The third problem occurs because the two governments might have different goals for their monetary policy. 3.2.1 The n-1 problem In the last lecture we found that if the exchange rate was fixed, money supply would be determined by real output, the foreign interest rate and the foreign price level: mt = p∗t − ηi∗t+1 + φyt . 82 (3.1) The central bank must adjust the money supply to assure that equation (3.1) hold. In a unilateral exchange rate regime the country that fixes its exchange rate will take the interest rate and the price level in the other country as given. However, in a bilateral fixed exchange rate regime this becomes more tricky. The fixed exchange rate determines the ratio of the money stocks in the two countries, but not the level of the money stock. Either the two countries must agree on how the money stock shall be determined, or one country must accept the money stock set by the other country. To see this we can use the following example. From the UIP we know that if exchange rates are fixed between two countries, the nominal interest rate must be the same in both countries. From the real money demand functions discussed in the Cagan model we know that there is a relationship between the interest rate and the money stock. For every level of the money stock there will be a certain interest rate. We illustrate this relationship in figure 3.8. If we have a fixed exchange rate, and the UIP hold, then the following relationship must hold: if the interest rate in the foreign country fall because the foreign country increases the money stock, then the domestic interest rate must fall as well. This can only be achieved by increasing the money stock in the home country. So a change in the money stock of one country must imply a similar change in the money stock in the second country. This is the n-1 problem. One has two countries, but only one exchange rate. The basis of a multilateral exchange rate agreement is that the two countries agree on how interest rates and money stocks shall be set. However, often a multilateral fixed exchange rate regime is containing countries that are not willing to compromise their opinion of what is the optimal money 83 Figure 3.8: Interest rates and money stock Country A ia ib Country B ma mb supply. If the two countries can not agree, the fixed exchange rate will break down. Most fixed exchange rate systems has a de facto “base country” that is supposed to work as a “nominal anchor”—i.e. set the money stock. In the Bretton Woods the US was the base country. In the European Monetary System (EMS) Germany was the base country. In both cases this worked fine as long as the interests of the base country were the same as the interest of the countries who took part in the exchange rate system. However, in both instances situations occurred when that were no longer the case. The breakdown of Bretton Woods In the end of the 1960’s the USA were running considerable trade deficits. When a country run a trade deficit, we must expect the currency to be overvalued. As the exchange rate was fixed, an overvaluation can be alleviated either through deflation in the home country or by inflation abroad. Accord- 84 ing to the rules of the Bretton Woods system such deficits should not cause a problem to the exchange rate. The process was supposed to proceed as follows: if a country was running a trade deficit, there is increased demand for foreign currency in the home country. To meet this demand for foreign currency, the local central bank must sell foreign exchange reserves. When the foreign exchange reserves are reduced, this should cause a proportionate change in the money base. When the money base falls, the local price level shall fall. A falling price level will reduce the overvaluation. Over time the trade deficit will disappear. A trade deficit in one country should be reflected in a trade surplus in another country. The country with a trade surplus will experience excess demand for the domestic currency. This will imply that the central bank increases its holdings of foreign reserves. An increase in the holdings of foreign reserves should imply an increase in the money base, and a rise in the domestic price level. The real exchange rate should appreciate. The US experienced a an increase in home demand mainly due to the welfare reforms conducted under the Johnson administration, and due to the increasing costs of the Vietnam war. The US government financed its public deficit by printing more money. This money was used to purchase goods abroad. To reduce the money base would reduce the US ability to run a public deficit. The US administration was not interested in paying such a cost. The countries running trade surpluses were countries like Germany, Japan and Switzerland. The US money stock had increased. To alleviate the misalignments in the system, these countries had to allow their money stocks to increase as well. However, a country like Germany was not interested in importing US 85 inflation. When the demand for DEM increased, the Bundesbank chose to sterilise the increase in its currency reserves. At the same time as currency reserves rose, it sold domestic bonds. This way the German money base remained stable. However, at the same time the automatic stabilisation in the Bretton Woods system broke down. The real problem here was perhaps not that Germany did not want to import inflation. In fact, the Bretton Woods system was supposed to include an additional check to assure that the US should use its all important position to impose inflation on other countries. Remember that the USD was fixed to gold at the rate of USD 35 per ounce of gold. If the holdings of USD increased to much, central banks in other countries was supposed to bring these dollars to the Federal Reserve and claim gold in return. Doing so, they would reduce the asset holdings of the Federal Reserve. The Federal Reserve was supposed to react to such claims by reducing the money base. However, the most important holders of excess USD reserves, Japan and Germany, chose not to do this. The reason was that both countries depended on the US for both political and military reasons. They did not want to endanger these relationships by forcing the US to reduce its money supply. The only country that to some degree did claim gold for USD was France. Over time it became “evident” to speculators that countries like Germany, Japan and Switzerland rather would revaluate their exchange rates at a new level than stay at a fixed level with an increased money stock. At this time speculators started to move from USD to DEM, CHF and JPY. As no country was willing to compromise about the optimal money supply in the Bretton Woods system, the system was posed to break down. In early September 1971 US president Richard Nixon declared that the US was no longer committed 86 Figure 3.9: Money supply shock in the US... USD/DEM DUSD S1 USD S0 USD M DEM US money supply increased as a result of more public spending, due to welfare reforms and the Vietnam war. to fixed parity between USD and gold. With this declaration the Bretton Woods system was de facto dead. 3.2.2 The adjustment problem The point is this: If a country has a fixed exchange rate, it can not use monetary policy for stabilising the economy. However, assume that there is a shock to only one of the countries in the exchange rate mechanism. Then the government must make a choice. Either it can use fiscal policy to stabilise the economy, or it can leave the fixed exchange rate and use monetary policy. Why might it choose the last strategy? 87 Figure 3.10: And the consequences for Germany DEM/USD Do DEM D1 DEM SDEM M DEM A money supply shock in the US increases demand for DEM. To hold the exchange rate within the target zone Germany has two alternatives: exchange USD-reserves for gold, and thereby contract the US money supply (however this was not politically feasible), or increase their own money supply (which they did not want to do, as this would imply importing US inflation to Germany). 88 There will be a cost of leaving a fixed exchange rate. E.g. the government might loose credibility if it wants to go back to a fixed exchange rate at a later stage. However, there might also be a cost of not using monetary policy for stabilisation. This will especially the case if prices and wages are sticky—i.e. that they adjust only slowly. Example: Assume that the cost of producing in the home country increases. This might e.g. be due to a restriction of working hours that have a negative effect on labour productivity. Implicitly this is a wage shock that will affect the domestic price level. If the domestic price level increases, Q will fall. The country experiences a real appreciation. A real appreciation implies that domestic goods are less competitive on international markets. This will have a real economic cost. However, to alleviate the real appreciation the government has two choices: 1. it can force the price level down, or 2. it can devalue the nominal exchange rate. The last option will however imply a break with the fixed exchange rate policy. Why would a government choose this option over the option of deflating the economy? In fact it is very difficult to impose a downward change in wages. It is also a process that might take a very long time, as most wages are set by long term contracts. By devaluing the exchange rate home goods will become cheaper abroad over night, without lowering wages at home. One should however note that the purchasing power of home wages of course will fall—as imports become more expensive. Note that if the shock is symmetric, i.e. both countries in the system get the same shock, monetary policy can be used for adjustment. Both countries now have incentive to move the money supply in the same direction. This 89 can be done without affecting the fixed exchange rate. Remember that the fixed exchange rate can be sustained for an infinite number of different money supplies, but only for one ratio of home money over foreign money. However, in this case the real exchange rate will of course not be affected. 3.2.3 The problem of a credible policy—the Barro Gordon model From your former lessons in macro, you know the concept of a Phillips curve. The Phillips curve implies a relationship between unemployment and inflation. In “modern macroeconomics” one thinks about the Phillips curve as a fluctuations around a “non-accelerating-inflation-rate-of-unemployment” (the NAIRU). The NAIRU is seen as the long-run rate of unemployment. In the short term unemployment can be higher or lower than the NAIRU, depending on whether inflation is higher or lower than expected inflation. If we call unemployment for u, the NAIRU for un and inflation for π, and we let π e be expected inflation, we can express the Phillips curve as u = un + a(π e − π). (3.2) If inflation exceeds expected inflation, the unemployment rate can for a short period be less than the NAIRU. However, one can not expect inflation to exceed expected inflation over time. We assume that the government has two policy goals: to keep inflation stable, and to keep unemployment low. In fact, the government has as a goal to keep unemployment at a level u∗ < un . This can be rationalised if ne think there are some sort of inefficiencies in the labour market that lead to an increase in the NAIRU rate. As a second best policy the government 90 target an unemployment rate below the NAIRU. We specifically assume that u∗ = σun , (3.3) where 0 < σ < 1. The government minimises a loss function, L, that contain these two elements: L = π 2 + b[u − u∗ ]2 , (3.4) where b (assumed to be > 0) is the weight on holding unemployment at u∗ . If we substitute in for the equations (11.85) and (11.86), we obtain L = π 2 + b[(1 − σ)un + a(π e − π)]2 . (3.5) The government want to set inflation such that it minimises the value of L. To do so we must take the derivative of L with regard to π, and set equal to zero. This gives us δL = 2π − 2ab[(1 − σ)un + a(π e − π)] = 0 δπ (3.6) If we solve with regard to π we get π opt = ab(1 − σ)un ba2 π e + . 1 + ba2 1 + ba2 (3.7) Assume that the government set π = 0, and that this is fully credible (the public believes the government, so that π e = 0 as well). The the loss would be L = b[(1 − σ)un ]2 . (3.8) However, if π e = 0 we know that the optimal inflation rate from the point of 91 view of the government would be ab(1 − σ)un , 1 + ba2 (3.9) 1 b[(1 − σ)un ]2 . 1 + ba2 (3.10) π= which would give a loss of L= One can show that b[(1 − σ)un ]2 > 1 b[(1 − σ)un ]2 1 + ba2 (3.11) for all values of b > 0. So, in a one period game—if the government only cares about today, and not about the future, it will always be rational for the government to try to fool the public by setting inflation higher than they expect.3 However, if the public have rational expectations they will look through this strategy. In fact the public will understand which inflation rate will minimise the loss of the government, and expect this inflation rate. Indeed, equilibrium if we assume rational expectations must be that π opt = π e . We therefore know that πe = ab(1 − σ)un ba2 π e + , 1 + ba2 1 + ba2 (3.12) which implies that the equilibrium rate of inflation will be π = π e = ab(1 − σ)un . 3 (3.13) Why should the government play one period games? Very simplified: because an elected government is supposed to only think about the next election. 92 This will give the government a loss of L = [ab(1 − σ)un ]2 + b[(1 − σ)un ]2 > b[(1 − σ)un ]2 . (3.14) The government will in other words be worse of than if it could follow a credible policy of no inflation. However, it can not, because if a zero inflation policy is indeed credible, the government has incentive to cheat be setting inflation above zero for one period. The government is not able to tie itself to the mast. How should this affect a fixed exchange rate regime? Assume that country A (e.g. Norway) has fixed its exchange rate to country B (e.g. Germany), and that Germany follows a “zero inflation” policy. That is, Germany has a bG = 0. If we assume the PPP to hold, the results from the Cagan model implies that Norway must follow a zero inflation policy too. However, if the Norwegian government has a bN > 0, such a policy will not be credible for Norway. 3.2.4 Appendix: The real exchange rate One reason why exchange rates are important for international trade is that they are closely related to the real relative price of foreign goods. For example, let P ∗ be the price, in foreign currency, of a bushel of foreign wheat, and let P be the dollar price of a bushel of domestic wheat. We assume that the quality of foreign and domestic wheat is the same. Which good is more expensive? The relative price of foreign to domestic wheat is the ratio Q= P∗ . P (3.15) This makes sense. P ∗ is the price of foreign wheat, and is the domestic price of foreign currency, so P ∗ must be the price of foreign wheat in domestic 93 currency. We then find the relative price by taking the ratio. Q is often referred to as the real exchange rate. This is another way of saying ‘relative price of imports’. Also, in practice we often use prices of larger baskets of goods, such as the country specific CPI’s, to form the relative price. Loosely speaking, the real exchange rate indicates how competitively priced foreign goods are in terms of domestic goods: higher real exchange rates tend to make a country’s exports more attractive on world markets. If you think domestic and foreign goods are very similar, and that there are relatively few barriers to trade it is reasonable to expect little variation in the real exchange rate. The extreme case is to assume Q = 1. To see why this is reasonable, assume that Q < 1, This implies that imported goods are less costly than domestic goods. Consumers will therefore tend to purchase foreign goods, creating a downward pressure on either (or both) the price of domestic goods or the value of the domestic currency, until Q = 1. In other words, prices of common goods should, expressed in units of a common currency, be the same. When we talk about one good, price equalisation is called the law of one price. When we talk about basket of goods, we call this assumption purchasing power parity, PPP. Remember that when we defined PPP in lecture 2 as = P , P∗ (3.16) we implicitly assumed that Q = 1. Although in theory a fixed exchange rate can only be viable if the PPP holds, in practice on will find that the PPP does not hold exactly all the time. More specifically, if shocks differ between countries, Q might at any point of time be bigger or smaller than one. If Q exceeds one, domestic goods improve their competitiveness abroad, and we should expect that there evolves a trade surplus. If Q < 1, domestic goods have lost competitiveness abroad, and the 94 country should turn to trade deficit. 95 Chapter 4 Currency crises 4.1 Introduction Some definitions: • A “devaluation” is the move taken by the government to change the target value of the fixed exchange rate regime to a weaker (higher) exchange rate. A “revaluation” is the move taken by the government to change the target value of the fixed exchange rate regime to a stronger (lower) exchange rate. • A speculative attack is a situation where a large number of market participants go “one way” in the market—all participants either sell or buy the asset. In a speculative attack on a fixed exchange rate the central bank is obliged to stand as counter party to all transactions within the target zone, unless someone else takes the deal. The central bank will either do so by intervening in the markets directly, or by changing interest rates. Changing interest rate might induce private investors return to the currency to profit on the interest differential. At the same time higher interest rates increase the cost of speculation. When (if) the central banks pulls out the price of the asset will fall (or 96 rise). Often a period of turbulence occurs before a new equilibrium is established. • A “currency crisis” is a situation where a speculative attack forces the central bank to make a change in the fixed exchange rate not actually intended by the central bank. What is the difference between a “controlled” change in the exchange rate and a currency crisis? If the markets believe that the central bank will change the target rate, rational investors would only trade on one side of the markets—i.e. behave like in a speculative attack. The central bank has incentive to present this as if it was forced to abandon the fixed exchange rate, although its own behavior actually caused the markets to behave as they did. Note that a currency crisis might occur even if the exchange rate is not fixed. If the markets bring forth a large change in a floating exchange rate over a short period of time, the central bank will be expected to intervene, as large changes in an exchange rate might destabilise financial markets. The inability of the central bank to keep the exchange rate at the wanted target can be considered a “currency crisis”, even if it does not induce a formal devaluation. There are three sides to all currency crisis: the government, investors with liquid assets and investors with illiquid assets. For the government a currency crisis is a question of credibility, of flexility in political decision making and about a possible fallout because of negative implications of a sudden change in the exchange rate. For a liquid, well informed investor a currency crisis is a question of potential financial gains. The illiquid investors are the most vulnerable to currency volatility. They might not have the financial strength to diversify investments, or they might 97 be contained to long term contracts. Further, these investors also tend to be smaller and perhaps less informed than the liquid investors. The presence of illiquid investors is especially a problem in countries with underdeveloped financial markets. In this lecture we will discuss the interaction between government incentives and the behavior of the markets, by which we mean the liquid investors. We will return to issue of the illiquid investors in the last part of the course. 4.2 Speculative attacks In the last lecture we discussed three reasons for why a fixed exchange rate might break down. They were all based on the fact that in a fixed exchange rate system monetary policy is outside the full control of the central bank. Changes in the money supply must be symmetric between the countries involved in the system. If optimal policy makes for asymmetric monetary policy, a fixed exchange rate is not sustainable. 1. The n-1 problem: the countries involved can not agree on a proper rate of growth in the money supply. 2. The adjustment problem: if we have asymmetric shocks and sticky prices, it might be optimal with leave the fixed rate regime. 3. The credibility problem: a fix is not sustainable if the governments involved have different loss functions, i.e. they care about different things. If these were all the reasons why fixed exchange rate systems broke down, one should expect that governments chose to leave such systems by purpose. However, countries often first leave a fixed exchange rate system after a 98 “speculative attack”, an event where the whole market has sold the currency to the central bank because everyone believes that the central bank soon will break its promise of a fixed rate. An example of this is the EMS-crisis in 1992-93. After 1990 the countries in the European Monetary System had attempted to limit fluctuations in their exchange rates more actively—they had agreed on a less lenient use of the escape clause. Some countries outside the EMS, as Norway, Sweden and Finland also attempted to fix their currencies closer to the ECU. In the August of 1992 the currencies came under great stress. First, investors sold ITL and FIM. Both countries choose to devalue (or more exact—they let the value of the currency float). In early September Great Britain left the EMS. This attack is famous for the role of George Soros. His Quantum Funds is said to have increased its value with 25 per cent due to exchange rate movements in the fall of 1992. The speculators then turned to Scandinavia. Sweden came under pressure. However, the Swedish government, eager to build credibility in a new monetary policy, attempted to defend the exchange rate by rising over night interest rates to 500 per cent. This policy was not sustainable, and when the rates came down the attack continued. In November Sweden devalued. Norway devalued in December after heavy interventions. In a fixed exchange rate regime the central bank has promised to buy and sell the currency at specified levels. The distance between the sell and buy price will be the “target zone”, the room for fluctuations in the exchange rate. The target zone is usually about +/- 2.5 per cent around the stated “fixed rate”. However, a central bank can only buy the local currency in exchange for foreign currency as long as it has foreign reserves available. In theory it can borrow reserves for interventions. However, one rarely sees this in practice. If the level of reserves become too low, the cost of standing by 99 Figure 4.1: Swedens exit from the EMS—1992 100 80 60 40 20 0 6/01/92 10/19/92 3/08/93 7/26/93 12/13/93 7/26/93 12/13/93 SEINT1W 5.2 4.8 4.4 4.0 3.6 3.2 6/01/92 10/19/92 3/08/93 DEMSEK 100 the promise of a fixed exchange rate might become to expensive—and the currency is devalued. There has been much effort to understand the nature of speculative attacks. Some of what we know about speculative attacks can be summarised in these points: • From the “first-generation model” (the Krugman model), we have that – A currency crisis will occur if the “shadow exchange rate”—the exchange rate that would have been if the rate was floating—is sufficiently different from the fixed rate ⇒ there must be some relationship between the fixed rate and a “fundamentally sound” rate. – If there are any kind of “trend” that will affect the shadow exchange rate the timing of an attack can be calculated. The time will be independent of “news”—it will only be a function of the rate of growth in the trend and how this affects the shadow exchange rate. • If there is no trend affecting the shadow rate, the shadow rate might still fluctuate due to shocks. – If fundamentals are very strong (the shock is weak) the government will probably defend the currency no matter what. – If fundamentals are very weak (the shock is strong) the government will probably choose to devalue anyway. – Between these levels there will be a “window of uncertainty”. For a speculative attack to occur in this window, a sufficient number of speculators must believe in a crisis at the same time. If only 101 a few investors speculate against the currency, they might lose money. For a speculative attack to succeed many investors must act simultaneously. This is the so-called “second generation model, or the “Obstfeld model”. In this case speculation can cause a devaluation even if the government did not intend to devalue if there had been no speculation. In the last couple of years (after the Asian crisis) new questions have been raised. • Originally a trend that affected the shadow rate, as described in the Krugman model, was understood as growth in the money supply or depletion of foreign reserves. However, new models have emphasized the role of implicit obligations of the government: if the government has growing obligations to e.g. the banking sector, this might have the same implications for the shadow exchange rate as a fall in the actual level of foreign reserves. • There has been much discussion on the question of contagion: why do currency crises tend to occur in “batches”—why do several countries experience currency crises at the same time? • One has investigated whether e.g. hedge funds play a special role under speculative attacks. One can show that this might be the case if different investors have different information. If hedge fund have more information than others, and this is known to everyone, the presence of hedge funds might increase the volatility of capital flows. • Last, much has been done on the role of regulating the exchange rate market. This is an issue we return to at the end of the course. 102 4.3 The Krugman model We consider a small open economy where both the PPP and the UIP holds, and all investors have perfect foresight. Further, we assume for simplification that y = 0, i∗ = 0 and p∗ = 0. If we use a continuous time setting, and we · let e be the rate of change in e, we can write the Cagan equation from the lecture 2 on the form · mt − et = −η e. (4.1) It follows from equation (11.96) that if the exchange rate is fixed at e, the money stock is fixed at m = e. (4.2) We now assume that the money stock is composed by two parts, domestic credit, D, and foreign reserves, R, such that Mt = Dt + Rt , (4.3) when R is denominated in foreign currency terms. Let us further assume that the government follows a policy that expand domestic credit at a fixed rate µ, such that · · D = d = µ. D (4.4) This can be thought of as a fiscal deficit monetisation by the central bank, i.e. that the central bank issues money to pay for government expenditure. However, if the central bank at the same time follows a fixed exchange rate policy, if can not let the expansion of domestic credit affect the exchange rate. So by definition we must have that · · D = −R, 103 (4.5) ⇒ expansion of domestic credit must be followed by a fall in the level of reserves. Such a policy can not last. Domestic credit can increase forever. Foreign reserves have only a limited supply. At some point of time the foreign reserves must be zero. At this time the central bank will no longer be able to stand by its obligations in the fixed exchange rate regime—with no foreign reserves the central bank can not fulfill the promise to exchange the domestic currency into foreign currency at a given rate. So a policy of domestic credit expansion must necessarily lead to the fall of the fixed exchange rate system. When will such a collapse happen? Will it be when the inconsistent policy is introduced? Or will the the exchange rate first collapse when the the reserves are zero? In fact we observe that “currency crises” often seem to occur independent of new information. How can we explain that in this framework? Let us define a “shadow exchange rate”, ee, as the exchange rate that would have been if the speculative attack had already occurred. After a speculative attack, foreign reserves must be zero. In this case the money stock will only contain domestic credit, so we must have that mt = dt . However, we assume that domestic credit continues to grow at the rate µ. If the money supply grows at a fixed rate, the exchange rate must depreciate at the rate ηµ, as we found Lecture 1. This implies that the shadow rate of the exchange rate will be eet = mt + ηµ = dt + ηµ = d0 + µt + ηµ. (4.6) The Krugman model argues that by arbitrage the fixed exchange rate must collapse at the moment when the shadow rate equals the fixed rate, ee = e. Why? Assume that the fixed exchange rate equals the shadow rate at time T . Let the fixed exchange rate collapses at a T + 2. In this case 104 the shadow rate will exceed the fixed rate. The fixed rate is terminated at this point, the exchange rate must make a jump from e to ee. A discrete jump in the exchange rate will imply infinite profit opportunities for rational speculators. As everyone have perfect foresight, everyone will try to sell the domestic currency at time T + 1. Hence, the speculative attack will take place at T + 1. However, at T + 1 the jump will still be discrete. So everyone will sell at T . Why not sell at T − 1? Simply because one would lose money by doing so. If everyone sell at T − 1 the exchange rate actually will appreciate, as the shadow rate at this time is lower than the fixed rate. If we know when a speculative attack will occur, we can calculate the exact timing of an attack. We know that the attack will occur when e = d0 + µT + ηµ. (4.7) e = mo = ln(D0 + R0 ) (4.8) ln(D0 + R0 ) = d0 + µT + ηµ. (4.9) Further, we know that so that T will then be given by T = ln(D0 + R0 ) − d0 − ηµ . µ (4.10) We see that the larger the initial holdings of reserves, the higher must T be. Further, T will decrease in the rate of growth in domestic credit. T must occur at a time when R > 0. The speculative attack will occur when the central bank still has some foreign reserves left. The result will 105 be a fall in the money supply at time T as the central bank must sell its foreign reserves during the attack. The reason why the money stock must fall is because the investors expect the growth in domestic credit to continue after the attack. Before the attack we had e = m. After the attack we have e = m + µη. The money stock must fall so that m = mT + µη ⇒ m − mT = µη. (4.11) There are a number of weaknesses in the Krugman model. These include that we assume perfect foresight, that we assume the UIP to hold at every point of time and that we assume that the government follow a totaly inconsistent policy over time. One relevant question is why, when everybody has perfect foresight, should the government care to follow an inconsistent policy of this kind? However, the model tells us that if we want to understand why a seemingly “irrational” event occurs—remember, here a speculative attack occurs even if the central bank still controls foreign reserves—it is important to understand long term underlying trends, and how these affect the expectations of market participants. 4.4 Crises with no trend? In the August 1993 the French franc, the Belgian franc and the Danish krone all experienced severe speculative attacks. As a result of this the countries agreed to widen their target zones within the EMS system from +/-2.5 per cent to +/-15 per cent. However, within two years of the attack all three currencies were not far from the edge of the original band. Figure 4.3 illustrate the movements of the BEF over the period from 1990 to 1999. Over this time period little changed in the Belgian economic policy. Belgium had with success followed a low inflation policy in the late 1980’s. 106 Figure 4.2: Anatomy of a speculative attack log exchange rate T Shadow floating rate Fixed rate log money supply time time log foreign reserves Level of foreign reserves at time of attack time 107 BGF TO DEM Figure 4.3: The BEF against DEM—1990 to 1999 22.5 22 21.5 21 20.5 20 24.10.99 24.07.99 24.04.99 24.01.99 24.10.98 24.07.98 24.04.98 24.01.98 24.10.97 24.07.97 24.04.97 24.01.97 24.10.96 24.07.96 24.04.96 24.01.96 24.10.95 24.07.95 24.04.95 24.01.95 24.10.94 24.07.94 24.04.94 24.01.94 24.10.93 24.07.93 24.04.93 24.01.93 24.10.92 24.07.92 24.04.92 24.01.92 24.10.91 24.07.91 24.04.91 24.01.91 24.10.90 24.07.90 24.04.90 19.5 Inflation remained low. The Belgian state debt was high—it was (and is) well above 100 of GDP—however it remained stable over the whole period.1 There was strong support in Belgium for the long term goal of joining a common European currency. There was no obvious “trend” in Belgian policy that could be considered as incompatible with the commitment to a fixed exchange rate. The Krugman model is clearly not able to explain events such as those we observed in Denmark, France and Belgium in 1993. In fact, a number of more recent currency crises have aspects that are similar to what we observe in these three countries. The Norwegian devaluation in 1992 happened in a country that at the time of attack had lower inflation than Germany and a very sound fiscal position. A new line of currency crises models therefore emerged to suggest that 1 One should note that the Belgian debt is mainly debt issued in domestic currency to domestic residents. This makes the high debt levels less of a problem with regard to the exchange rate. 108 even sustainable currency pegs could be attacked and even broken. These models focus on the choice of governments: they assume that the government will make a continuous comparison of the net benefits from changing the exchange rate versus the net benefits of defending it. When costs become to high the fixed rate is abandoned. An important aspect is that speculation itself will affect to the cost of holding an exchange rate fixed. 4.4.1 The strategy of speculators The following game theoretic approach2 illustrates the case of how speculative attacks might occur even in situations when the exchange rate peg is sustainable. The basis of the argument is that there is a correlation between the “discomfort” a government will feel about a devaluation and the level of reserves the government chooses to hold. Assume that if fundamentals are very strong, the government is not under any circumstances willing to give up the fixed rate. In this case the level of reserves the government is willing to commit to defending the exchange rate is high. If fundamentals are very weak—think e.g. about a period when the real exchange rate is overvalued—the government might be willing to, or even interested in devaluing the exchange rate. So the level of reserves committed to defending the rate will be low. The problematic case is the “grey zone”. Where do “good” fundamentals end and “bad” fundamentals start? Assume that the currency is slightly overvalued in real terms. However, there are reasons to believe that one can adjust this through lower inflation and tight fiscal policy. So the exchange rate peg is sustainable. However, given the economic difficulties, the government is not willing to put its full force behind the exchange rate peg. 2 From Obstfeld, 1995. 109 In the model we assume that at such “intermediate” levels of fundamentals the government is only willing to commit an intermediate level of reserves to defend the exchange rate. More specific, we assume three possible states of the economy. In the good state the governments commits reserves equal to 20 “domestic money units”, e.g. 20 billion NOK. For simplicity we assume that this equals the total monetary base. In fact, such a commitment will make it impossible for speculators to topple the exchange rate. In the intermediate stage the government commits reserves equal to 10. In this situation it is possible for speculators to topple the regime, but only if the whole markets reacts at the same time. In the bad state the government commits reserves equal to 6. In this case one large trader can topple the regime alone. We assume the existence of two traders. Each trader control resources of 6 domestic money units. The traders incur a cost of −1 by attacking the exchange rate. Figure 4.4 presents the result of alternative strategies in the “good state”. In this case the traders will not be able to topple the regime under any circumstances. They will gain 0 by doing nothing, and lose −1 by speculating against the currency. The case of “hold, hold” can be characterised as a “Nash equilibrium”.3 Assume that we are in the low state, and that one trader attack the exchange rate. Then the central bank will offer this trader its whole portfolio of reserves, equal to 6. Assume the currency depreciates with 50 per cent. The trader makes a profit of 2—the income from the speculation is 34 and 3 A Nash equilibrium is a state where nobody, when the behaviour of everyone else is taken as given, can improve on their outcome by changing their own strategy. 4 Assume that the peg was on the level 1:1. The trader exchanges 6 domestic currency units in 6 foreign currency units at the rate 1:1. After the devaluation she can exchange back at the rate 1.5:1—for her 6 units of foreign currency she will get 9 units of domestic 110 Figure 4.4: Attack when fundamentals are strong. Committed reserves=20. Trader 1 Hold Sell Hold 0,0 0,-1 Sell -1,0 -1,-1 Trader 2 111 Figure 4.5: Attack when fundamentals are weak. Committed reserves=6. Trader 1 Hold Sell Hold 0,0 0,2 Sell 2,0 1/2,1/2 Trader 2 the cost of speculation is −1. However, if both traders sell at the same time, the traders will share the central bank reserves between each other. Both will make an income of 3/2, and a profit of 1/2. This case is illustrated in figure 4.5. In this case the “sell, sell” strategy will be a Nash equilibrium. The most interesting case is made up by the intermediate fundamentals. In this case no trader can topple the regime alone. So if a trader acts alone, she will gain nothing, and lose the cost of speculation. However, if both traders attack at the same time, both will gain 5/2 − 1 = 3/2, as they will share the committed reserves of the central bank between them. This case is illustrated in figure 4.5. Her we have two Nash equilibria—it will be an equilibrium to “hold, hold”, but it will also be an equilibrium to “sell, sell”. currency. She will make a profit of 9 − 6 = 3 units of domestic currency. 112 Figure 4.6: Attack when fundamentals are “intermediate”. Committed reserves=10. Trader 1 Hold Sell Hold 0,0 0,-1 Sell -1,0 3/2,3/2 Trader 2 In this situation we have possible instability—the peg might survive or it might not, depending on whether the traders are able to co-ordinate their attack or not. 4.4.2 The role of large speculators Of course, the investor will never know exactly what commitment the central bank is ready to offer. So the investor must first observe some signal that gives her an opinion about the economy. Then she makes up her mind about a speculation strategy. If she finds that she have positive expected returns, she will attack. If expected returns are negative, she will not attack. One question that has been asked is what role large speculators play in 113 determining the fait of fixed exchange rate regimes. Above, I referred to the story of George Soros and the devaluation of the GBP in 1992. Soros is said to have made billions of USD during this attack. What is a large speculator? There exist funds that control enormous amounts of money. Several American pension funds have resources in excess of the Norwegian GDP. However, when we talk about a “large player” in the FX-market, it is not necessarily market capitalisation that is interesting. Rather it is the ability to take high risk positions. Most banks and pensions funds have strong restrictions on the level of risk they can take. However, there exists a type of institutions that have no juridical restrictions on their risk positions. These are the so-called hedge funds. Hedge funds are financial institutions that specialise on making money on potential mis-pricing in financial markets. The hedge fund will form an opinion of what it perceives to be the “shadow exchange rate”. If the fixed rate and the “shadow rate” diverges, there are potential profits to be gained by speculating in this market. The main difference between a hedge fund and a e.g. mutual fund is that while public regulators will take some responsibility for checking up on the practices of a mutual fund, the investors in a hedge fund is perceived to be able to take care of themselves. There is no restrictions on how a hedge fund can invest. The fast way to make money in financial markets is by gearing risk. That is to gamble with loaned money. Assume that you expect the stock of firm A to increase with 50 per cent over a year. You have NOK 100. If you invest all you have in the firm, you expect to make NOK 50. However, assume that you gear your investment 10 times. That is, you offer a bank 100 as a security, and borrow 1000 for investment in the stock. The cost of the loan 114 is 10 per cent, i.e. 100 for a year. If your expectations go in you gain 500 on your investment, and earn 400 after loan cost are paid. So you increase your profits by 800 per cent. However, the risk is of course considerable. Say that the firm actually goes bust. Then you lose 500 plus the cost of the loan, a total of 600. That is 500 more than you have... An institution that basis its investment strategy on gearing is called a highly leveraged insinuation. Most hedge funds fall in this category. This implies that even a relatively small fund can take very large positions during e.g. a speculative attack. How can an American hedge fund with no NOK assets attack a currency peg involving the NOK? It can do so by going short—i.e. sell currency in the forward market. When the hedge funds sells a forward contract on the delivery of NOK, the opposing party will be a bank. The contract implies that the bank must take a delivery of NOK sometime into the future. However, the bank does not want to expose itself to currency risk. So it will cover the contract by selling NOK today. If there is no market for this NOK today, the central bank must intervene, and foreign reserves will be depleted. The hedge fund can force a spot sale of NOK today by intervening in the forward market. However, one should note that this strategy is not risk free. The cost of the forward contract is the same as the interest differential between the two currencies of the contract. To short sell NOK is equivalent to taking a loan in NOK. If Norges Bank increases its interest rates to stop the attack, the cost of such a contract can be high. Hedge funds have been accused of trying to destabilise financial markets. The accusors are both politicians and economists, and they include, in a random order of importance, the former French president Francois Mitterand, the Malaysian prime minister Dr. Mathahir and the head of Norges Bank 115 Svein Gjedrem. The central banks of Hong Kong and Australia have both issued reports where they accuse hedge funds of manipulating the local exchange rates. In the case of Norway, it has been reported that the fund Tiger Management has been actively involved in speculation against NOK. The same is the case of Chase Manhattan, although Chase is not a hedge fund. The idea is that a “large player” could generate profits by secretly selling the currency forward and then deliberately trigger a crisis by making a large spot sale combined with some public statements of how weak the currency is. One example of manipulation might have taken place in Hong Kong in 1998. It is said that funds short sold both the HKD and the Hang Seng index at the same time. The idea was that by selling HKD they would force the Hong Kong Monetary authority to leave the currency peg. Then they would make money in on the currency contracts. Short selling the stock market would increase the pressure for a devaluation. However, if the authorities raised interest rates to defend the pegged rate one should expect the stock market would fall. Then the investors would make money on the stock contracts instead. Was this a case of manipulation? “Fundamental analysis” probably could justify both going short in the currency, and short in the stock market. Of course by taking such positions, investors might contribute to making such events inevitable. But whether this is “manipulation” or not is hard to say. In fact the Hong Kong authorities pulled of a “double defence”. They increased interest rates to defend the peg. However, at the same time they intervened in the stock market to boost prices. This way investors lost money on both their contracts. Hong Kong authorities might have fooled potential speculators. The question is how this willingness to intervene in the markets 116 affected the perception of other potential investors in Hong Kong. How should we analyse the role of large investors? Take the example of speculation given above. Assume that the two traders have unequal size. E.g. let one investor control resources equal to 9 domestic currency units, and the small investor controls resources equal to 3 units. What would change? The “good state” remains as before. No devaluation would occur. In the bad state the small investor could no longer attack the currency alone. In fact, the “large player” gets a proportional share of the central bank reserves— i.e. 75 per cent of the reserves, as she has 75 per cent of the market, then the small investor would not care about the currency markets at all. The small investor would lose money by selling anyway, given the high costs of speculation. This is illustrated in figure 4.7. In the intermediate case however, there would be no real change. The large trader needs the support of the small trader to succeed. Only the payoffs would be different from the case where the traders were of equal size. If size is the only difference between two traders, this might affect who takes part in an attack when the central bank has only a low commitment to a fixed exchange rate. However in these cases an attack is probably due to happen anyway. In the cases when fundamentals are stronger, the whole market still needs to take part for an attack to succeed. If the large trader is different from the small trader on other counts than just size, this argument will of course change. If the large player is perceived to have superior information, that might increase her ability to influence the behavior of the market. If the large player has less cost of speculating than the small investor, this might also affect the results. An extreme version of this case is reflected in figure 4.9. Here we assume the large trader has no cost of speculating. In this case it would be optimal for the large trader to 117 Figure 4.7: Attack when fundamentals are weak. Committed reserves=6. Trader 1 controls 9 units, trader 2 3 units. Trader 1 Hold Sell Hold 0,0 0,-1 Sell 2,0 5/4,-1/4 Trader 2 118 Figure 4.8: Attack when fundamentals are intermediate. Committed reserves=10. Trader 1 controls 9 units, trader 2 3 units. Trader 1 Hold Sell Hold 0,0 0,-1 Sell -1,0 11/4,1/4 Trader 2 119 Figure 4.9: Attack when fundamentals are intermediate and the large trader has no cost of speculation. Committed reserves=10. Trader 1 controls 9 units, trader 2 3 units. Trader 1 Hold Sell Hold 0,0 0,-1 Sell 0,0 15/4,1/4 Trader 2 always speculate—and therefore for the the small trader to speculate as well. If the costs of speculation is very small, the volatility of the exchange rate might increase. 4.4.3 A short note on the Tobin tax A Tobin tax is a proposed tax on on all transactions in the foreign exchange market. Intention: to reduce excess volatility caused by low costs of transaction. Will it work? Yes—and no. • Hinder currency crises? If the cost is high relative to expected gains 120 a tax will reduce the probability of crises. However, the tax necessary must probably be high. And there are possible problems, see example below. • A tax would make the markets less liquid. It is not perfectly clear how that will effect the price process. However, short term volatility might fall. • It has been argued that for a Tobin tax to be effective it must be implemented in all territories—if only a tiny bit of land is excluded one could move all FX transactions there to avoid the tax. However, a tax that covers the OECD countries will probably still have a substantial effect. • The real problem is financial derivatives. It is possible to speculate in the FX-market without being in the FX-market—one can create financial derivatives that reflect the risk in the FX market. 4.5 Contagion Figure 4.11 depicts the development of Asian currencies over the period from 1996 to 1998. As we see, during 1997 there occurred a period of severe volatility that lead to a shift from fixed exchange rate regimes to floating exchange rate regimes. In figure 4.12 we take a closer look at the period from May 15 to December 31 1997. We observe that the crises did not occur simultaneously. Rather they occurred one after another. There is signs of some sort of regional “spread”. This phenomena is often referred to in the literature as “contagion”. 121 Figure 4.10: Example of how a Tobin tax can be destabilising (note that this is an extreme case). Trader 1 controls 6 units, trader 2 6 units. Cost increases from 1 to 2. Trader 1 Hold Sell Hold 0,0 0,2 Sell 2,0 1/2,1/2 Trader 2 Trader 1 Hold Sell Hold 0,0 0,1 Sell 1,0 -1/2,-1/2 Trader 2 Attack when fundamentals are weak. Committed reserves=6. In first case cost of speculation is set to -1. In second case cost of speculation is set to -2. In the first case we have one Nash equilibrium, in the lower, right corner. In the second case we have two Nash122 equilibria, in the upper right and lower left corner. This creates the possibility of a more unstable situation. -0.2 123 25.12.97 18.12.97 11.12.97 04.12.97 27.11.97 20.11.97 13.11.97 06.11.97 30.10.97 23.10.97 16.10.97 09.10.97 02.10.97 25.09.97 18.09.97 Thailand 11.09.97 04.09.97 28.08.97 21.08.97 14.08.97 07.08.97 31.07.97 24.07.97 17.07.97 10.07.97 03.07.97 26.06.97 19.06.97 12.06.97 05.06.97 29.05.97 22.05.97 15.05.97 01.12.98 01.11.98 01.10.98 01.09.98 01.08.98 01.07.98 01.06.98 01.05.98 01.04.98 01.03.98 01.02.98 01.01.98 01.12.97 01.11.97 01.10.97 01.09.97 01.08.97 01.07.97 01.06.97 01.05.97 01.04.97 01.03.97 01.02.97 01.01.97 01.12.96 01.11.96 01.10.96 01.09.96 01.08.96 01.07.96 01.06.96 01.05.96 01.04.96 01.03.96 01.02.96 01.01.96 2 Figure 4.11: Asian currencies against USD, 1996-98 Indonesian rupiah 1.5 1 South Korean won Malaysian ringgit 0.5 Thai bath 0 Taiwan dollar -0.5 Figure 4.12: Asian currencies against USD, May 15, 1997-December 31, 1997 1 Indonesia 0.8 South Korea 0.6 0.4 Malaysia 0.2 0 Why do contagion occur? Four reasons have been presented: 1. Several countries can be similarly affected by a common shock. 2. Trade linkages can imply that a crisis in one country weakens fundamentals in other countries. 3. Financial interdependence. 4. A currency crisis in one country can change market participants’ perceptions of other countries, resulting in the withdrawal of capital. Argument one is providing a “fundamental” explanation of the spread of crises. Argument number four favour the perception of crisis as “self-fulfilling”. This argument does however depend on assumptions of limited rationality among market participants. It is no reason why a crisis in one country should affect rational expectations of other countries unless there are real links between the two economies. Arguments two and three are therefore perhaps the more interesting, as they provide explanations of why a crisis can be transmitted between countries even if there are no common shock. 4.5.1 Transmission of currency crisis via trade channels It is important to point out that transmission via trade channels do not depend on the existence of trade channels between the countries affected. In fact, in the case of Asia one common feature is the relatively small trade flows between the countries affected by the speculative attacks. The important feature is to which degree the exports of two countries are competing in foreign markets. In table 4.3 we illustrate the case with countries A and B exporting to countries C and D. Country A sends most 124 of her exports to country C, while country B sends most of her exports to country D. Assume that country A devalues with 10 per cent. What is the effect on the exports of country B? To say something about this we must make some assumptions about how close substitutes the goods of A and B are in C and D. We assume that there is a one-to-one relationship between a devaluation and an change in demand in the importing country. If the price of goods from country A falls with 10 per cent, the demand for goods from country B falls with 10 per cent. The relative price elasticity ρ, is set equal to 1. The total effect of a devaluation in country A on the exports of country B will be given by ∆exshareB = X [ρ(k) · exshareB (k) · marketshareA (k)] · dev, (4.12) k=C,D where exshareB (k) is the export share of country B in market k, k ∈ {C, D}, and dev is the devaluation in per cent. If we substitute in from table 4.3 we obtain ∆exshareB = [1 · 0.1 · 0.9] · 0.1 + [1 · 0.9 · 0.1] · 0.1 = 1.8%. (4.13) The exports of country B will fall by 1.8 per cent. However, assume that country A and B are competing in the same markets. An example is given in table 4.2. In this case the effect of a 10 per cent devaluation in country A will be ∆exshareB = [1 · 0.1 · 0.5] · 0.1 + [1 · 0.9 · 0.5] · 0.1 = 5%, (4.14) a 5 per cent fall in the exports of country B. In the case of South East Asia, these countries were all competing in 125 126 Initial trade flows value C D From A 10 90 B 10 90 trade flows Market share D percent C D 10 A 90 10 90 B 10 90 Table 4.2: Competing trade flows Export share Market share percent C D percent C D A 10 90 A 50 50 B 10 90 B 50 50 Table 4.1: Non-competing Initial trade flows Export share value C D percent C From A 90 10 A 90 B 10 90 B 10 foreign markets. They all specialised on electronics and computer components, sending their goods to Japan, the USA and Europe. The actual trade between these countries was of lesser importance. However, in this case the actual devaluations were not 10 per cent. Thailand, Malaysia and South Korea experienced devaluations of close to 50 per cent. If we assume a 50 per cent devaluation in country A, we get a 9 per cent fall in exports in country B in the “little competition case”, and as much as 25 per cent fall in the exports of country B in the “strong competition case”. Effects of that magnitude would certainly create a “fundamental” basis for a devaluation in country B as well. 4.5.2 Transmission via a credit crunch We consider a case where two banks, bank 1 and 2, lend to three different countries, A, B and C. However, the dependence on the two banks differ between the three countries. This is not an unrealistic assumption. Often banks will specialise on lending to specific geographical regions. No assume that there is a speculative attack in country A, and that country A defaults on its foreign debt. Both bank 1 and 2 will lose all they have lent to country A. As a result both banks need to recall loans to satisfy the demands of their creditors. Bank 1 have total loans of 40 (20+20) after the default of A. It must recall a total of 20, which makes up 20/(20+20)=50 per cent of its loan portfolio. Bank 2 had an exposure of 10. It must no recall 10, which makes up 10/(10+80)=11.1 per cent of its portfolio. For country B this means that total loans are reduced from 30 to 20 ∗ 0.5 + 10 ∗ 0.899 = 18.9. That implies a reduction in total loans of (30-18.9)/30=37 per cent. For 127 128 Initial portfolio From: Bank 1 Bank 2 To: A 20 10 B 20 10 C 20 80 Total: Table 4.3: Bank dependence Exposure Dependence Bank 1 Bank 2 Bank 1 Bank 2 Total: 33 10 33 10 66 33 100 33 80 20 80 100 100 100 country C we find that total loans are reduced from 100 to 20 ∗ 0.5 + 80 ∗ 0.899 = 81.1. That implies a reduction in total loans of (100-81.1)/100=18.9 per cent. The point here is that a default in one country might have large effects on the financing of other countries if there are some kinds of concentration in lending. If credit channels and trade channels are both regional specific the transmission effects can be substantial. In other words, a shock to one country might have substantial implications for other countries, even though these countries before the crisis had “strong fundamentals”, and even if we assume investors to be fully rational. Through trade and credit channels economies can be interdependent despite no direct links between them. 129 Chapter 5 The FX-market 5.1 Some definitions 5.1.1 Instruments • Spot market: Spot transactions in the FX-market are transactions made today that shall be completed within two days, i.e. formal delivery of the currency will take place in two days. • Outright forward: transaction that contract delivery of the currency at some point beyond two days. • Option: The right to buy (or sell) an asset at a predetermined value. • Swap: Bundles two FX transactions that go in opposing directions. Usual to combine a spot transaction and an outright forward. Example: buy 100 million EUR today for USD at spot exchange rate. At the same time agree to sell EUR 100 million in one month. Purpose: Lock in interest rate differential. If I need EUR 100 million from now and one month into the future, I can reduce the cost of holding this sum to the interest differential between EUR and USD by doing a swap today. I will remove all exchange rate risk. 130 Swaps come in two types. – “Short swaps” are contracts that give delivery today or tomorrow— i.e. before the delivery in a standard spot contract. Short swaps are used for liquidity purposes. – “Long swaps” are swaps with spot contracts and future contracts with delivery beyond two days. 5.1.2 Bid-ask All exchange rates are quoted as two prices—a bid and an ask. On the Reuters screes you will see quotes of the type: USD/EUR 0.8810-0.8812 0.8810 will be the price where the bank is willing to buy EUR. This is the bid price for EUR. 0.8812 will be the price where the bank is willing to sell EUR. This is the ask price for EUR. The seller asks 0.8812 USD to give you one EUR. Note that the bid price for EUR will be the aks for USD—the price of one USD is after all only the inverse of the price of one EUR. This might be confusing... Table 5.1: Example of bid-ask. Assume that CAD/USD=1.5858/1.5865 Bid Ask Price of USD 1.5858 1.5865 Price of CAD 0.6303 0.6306 Trading in the market, dealers will only quote the last two numbers of the exchange rate. In the above transactions, dealers will say they have a bid of 10 and an ask of 12. 131 The spread is measured in basis points. One basis point is one 1/10000 of the unit, that is one point in the fourth decimal of the quote. In the above example the spread is two basis points. The spread is the only ‘transaction cost’ in non-brokered interbank foreign exchange transactions. The spread is a ‘fee’ on the trading. Note that the spreads in the sport FX-market is much lower than what you will expect in most financial markets. E.g. a standard fee in equity trading can be 1 per cent of amount transacted—if the fee is symmetric (same for sell and purchase) that amounts to the the equivalent of 200 basis points. In the FX market spreads are seldom above 10 points in liquid markets. 5.2 What we know for certain about the FXmarket The FX-market is riddled with “puzzles”—things we do not understand. However, there are a few things we do know will hold for certain. In both examples bellow we will ignore the bid-ask spread. This simplifies things considerably. However, the logic still holds it we assume the existence of spreads. 5.2.1 Triangular arbitrage Let us ignore the bi/ask spread. Assume that we have • HKD/USD 7.70 (HKD-Hong Kong Dollar) • ZAR/USD 11.9 (ZAR-South African Rand) What is the HKD/ZAR rate? HKD/U SD 7.70 = = 0.6471 HKD/ZAR. ZAR/U SD 11.9 132 (5.1) Suppose not. Suppose e.g. that HKD/ZAR=0.75. This means that we can make a profit by arbitrage. How? Sell one ZAR and get 0.75 HKD. Sell 0.75 HKD and get 0.0974 USD. Sell 0.0974 USD and get 1.159 ZAR ⇒ you have made a profit of 16 per cent! Such profits can not exist for long in a free market. They will be traded away. In the end triangular arbitrage must hold. 5.2.2 Covered interest rate parity—CIP Let F be the forward exchange rate. Consider two portfolios: 1. Invest 1 USD at the US 1 year interest rate of i. In one year you will have U SD · (1 + i). 2. Convert 1 USD to GBP at the spot rate today. This gives you a total of GBP=U SD/. Invest this at the UK 1 year interest rate of i∗ . In one year you will have the equivalent of (U SD/) · (1 + i∗ ). However, you measure your money in USD, so you want to convert back to USD in the end of the year. To lock in the profit you buy a forward contract at the price F for delivery of USD in one year. The contract should cover an amount of GBP=(U SD/) · (1 + i∗ ). The amount earned will then be (U SD/) · (1 + i∗ ) · F . These two transactions are equivalent. If the UK and the US assets are similar, there is no risk difference involved by doing one transaction versus the other. So we should expect that: (1 U SD) · (1 + i) = (1 U SD) · (1 + i∗ ) · F. 133 (5.2) It follows that we must have F (1 + i) = . (1 + i∗ ) (5.3) CIP should hold at every point of time unless there are restrictions on the trade in capital assets. To sum up: it should not be possible to lend riskless dollars at different rates in two different markets. A covered international investment is the same as a domestic investment: they both involve no currency risk. Ergo, the return should be the same. The forward rate should reflect this. In logarithmic terms the return of the covered international investment will be i∗ + f − e. (5.4) The return on the domestic investment must be i. So we must have that f − e = i − i∗ . 5.3 (5.5) How the FX-market is organised Assets are traded in three different types of markets: 1. Auction market. Customers submit orders. These can either be • market orders—buy or sell at the current market price, or • limit orders—buy or sell at a the in the contract predetermined price. When the market reaches the limit price, the order is executed. If the market never reaches the limit price, the order is never executed, or at least not at that price. There will be no dealers in this market, only a system for organising the stream of orders. 134 An example of an auction market is to be found at the Paris Stock Exchange. 2. Single-dealer market. In this market we have one dealer who offers a best bid and a best ask. The customer must accept the offer of the dealer. FX markets in some developing countries will work as single dealer markets, with the central bank acting as the single dealer. 3. Multiple dealer market. • Centralised. Quotes from many dealers will be available at one screen at the same time. Example: NASDAQ. • Decentralised. Many dealers will offer quotes. However, there is no system to keep track of all offers in the market at the same time. The FX-market can best be described as a decentralised multiple dealer market. There exists no exchange and no common screen for all quotes. This means that trading will be partly fragmented—it is not possible to observe the price in all simultaneous transactions. Note that there are two types of traders that are active in the FX-market: 1. brokers, and 2. dealers. These groups offer slightly different services. Dealers will offer two-way prices (both bid and ask). Direct trade between dealers will be conducted over a computer system, or over the telephone. Mostly they will use something called Reuters D2000-1. An example of communication over Reuters D2000-1 is provided in figure 5.1. One dealer 135 Figure 3 provides an example of a D2000-1 conversation when a trade takes place. A conversation starts by a dealer contacting another dealer. The contacting dealer usually asks for bid and ask quotes for a certain amount, for instance USD one million. 4 When seeing the quotes, the contacting dealer states whether he wants to buy or sell. Sometimes he asks for better quotes, or end the conversation without trading. However, most conversations result in a trade (70%). All D2000-1 transactions in the data set take place at quoted bids or asks. Figure 5.1: Interdealer communication Figure 3: D2000-1 conversation on D2000-1 From ‘‘CODE’’ ‘‘FULL NAME HERE’’ *0728GMT ????98 */7576 Our Terminal: ‘‘CODE’’ Our user: ‘‘FULL NAME HERE’’ DEM 1 # 45.47 BA> I BUY # TO CONFIRM AT 1,8147 I SELL 1 MIO USD # VAL ??(+2)??98 # MY DEM TO ‘‘FULL NAME HERE’’ # THANKS AND BYE TO CONFIRM AT 1,8147 I BUY 1 MIO USD VAL ??(+2)??98 MY USD TO ‘‘FULL NAME HERE’’ THANKS FOR DEAL FRDS. CHEERS # # END REMOTE # ^ ^ ^ ## TKT EDIT OF CNV 7576 BY ‘‘CODE’’ 0728GMT ????98 STATUS CONFIRMED ##ENDED AT 07:27 GMT# ( 293 CHARS) An example of a D2000-1 conversation when a trade takes place. The first word means that the call came “From” another dealer. There are information regarding the institution code and the name of the counterpart, and the time (Greenwich Mean), the date, and the number assigned to the communication. DEM 1 means that this is a request for a spot DEM/USD quote for up to USD 1 million, since it is implicitly understood that it is DEM against USD. At line 4, we find the quoted bid and ask price. Only the last two digits of the four decimals are quoted. In this case, the bid quote is 1.8145 and the ask quote is 1.8147. When confirming the transaction, the communication record provides the first three digits. In this case, the calling dealer buys USD 1 million at the price 1.8147. The record confirms the exact price and quantity. The transaction price always equals the bid or the ask. There is also information regarding the settlement bank. “My DEM to “Settlement bank” identifies the settlement bank of “our bank”, while “My USD to “Settlement bank” identifies the settlement bank of the other bank. It is usual to end a conversation with standard phrases, such as “thanks and bye,” “thanks for deals friends.” Source: Bjønnes and Rime, 2001 3.2.2 Electronic broker systems will contact another, and for afunctions price quote. These quotes are considered Electronic broker systems fill ask the same as voice-brokers, but are more efficient. A bank dealer with access to one of the electronic broker systems can enter his buy and/or to be binding. A market maker is a dealer that is supposed to always be sell price into the system as a market maker. D2000-2 and EBS show only the highest bid and the lowest ask, thereby minimizing the spread. These normallyparty be entered able to give a quote. In direct interdealer contact thewill opposing will by be different banks, but the identity of the inputting bank is not shown. The total quantity known. entered for trade on these quotes is also shown. This means that when more than one bank input the same best bid (ask) price, the quantity shown is the sum of that offered by A banks. single This dealer will ismostly specialise only currency cross. The these quantity shown as integers of in USD one one million, and in some bilateral cases DEM one million. When the quantity is at least ten million, “R” is entered on the dealer might take considerable positions in this currency intra-day. However, D2000-2 screen. EBS shows two set of bid and ask quotes, for amounts up to ten million USD or DEM, close and fortheir amounts of at least millions. This information is optional on most dealers positions overtennight. Figure 5.2 illustrate observed 4 In some rare cases, the contacting dealer also tells whether he wants to buy or sell. dealer inventories for four different dealers in two different markets over one week, collected from a Norwegian bank. As we see, dealer strategies can 9 136 Figure 5.2: DealerInventory inventory Figure 2: Dealer 6 20 4 10 USD USD 2 0 0 -10 -2 -20 Mon Tue Wed Thu -4 Fri Mon a) Dealer 1: DEM/USD Market Maker 60 Thu Fri 5 20 0 USD DEM Wed 10 40 0 -5 -20 -10 -40 -60 Tue b) Dealer 2: DEM/USD "Nintendo-dealer" Mon Tue Wed Thu -15 Fri c) Dealer 3: NOK/DEM Market Maker Mon Tue Wed Thu Fri d) Dealer 4: DEM/USD The evolution of dealers inventory over the week. Dealer 1 (panel a), 2 (panel b) and 4s (panel d) inventory are in USD million, while Dealer 3s inventory is in DEM million. The horizontal axis is in“transaction”-time. Vertical lines indicate end of day. The numbers are in USD million. Source: Bjønnes and Rime, 2001 be described as “individual”.1 In this sample we see that dealer might take intra-day positions of up to 20 million USD. It is not unusual for dealers to trade for USD 1 billion a day. As a comparison US equity traders trade for an average of USD 10 million a day. A broker is a pure matchmaker. Dealers will submit limit orders to the broker. The broker will post these orders on a screen. One such system is 8 the Reuters D2000-2. In the broker system traders can observe the quotes available in the market on one screen. However, it is not revealed who has 1 The dealer consistently making most money of these four is supposed to have been the “Nintendo-dealer”—a guy who never held a position for more than two minutes. 137 posted the quote. This is first revealed after the trade has been completed. A difference between the direct trade and the broker system is that the as the broker system is based on limit orders, one will post a maximum size of the order at a given price. Further, one needs not post limit orders on both sides of the market. A dealer can choose to post orders a bid or an ask. The cost of trades will depend on the counterparty. Direct interdealer contact has the lowest spreads. Brokers take somewhat higher spreads, not least because brokers only make money through transaction costs. Customer get the highest spreads. The market is illustrated in figure 5.3 Three characteristics of the FX market: 1. A very high volume, 2. high intra-dealer volume, and 3. low transparency. In all these regards the FX-market is different from other multiple dealer asset markets. The daily volume in the FX spot market in April 1998 was 600 billion USD, of which about 2/3 is supposed to have been intradealer trade. As a comparison, the daily volume in the New York Stock Exchange in this period was 30 billion USD, and average daily world trade in goods and services was about 15 billion USD. One way to explain the high amount of trade in the FX-markets is the “hot-potato-hypothesis.” Assume that a dealer gets an order from a customer. However, the dealer wants to keep his inventory as close to zero as possible. So the dealer makes a trade with another dealer. This dealer will keep a little, and trade the rest. And so on. That way every customer trade gets multiplied when we look at the FX-market as a whole. One question might be why dealers conduct such trading. Seemingly they could try to seek 138 Figure 5.3: The FX-market Customer à dealer Spread: 3-7 basis points Brokered interdealer Spread: 2-3 basis points Direct interdealer Spread: 2 points Why use a broker? 1. Do not have access to direct market 2. Do not have to reveal identity before trade is completed 3. Access to a larger market Source: Lyons, 2001 139 a better match for their orders, thereby reducing the number of rounds before the currency risk is spread thin enough to satisfy the market. The willingness to trade might be explained through the low transparency in these markets. The only way dealers can obtain information about the flows in the market is by trading themselves. The FX-market has evolved almost with no government intervention. This might point to low transparency being in the interest of the dealers. Low transparency gives active dealers an advantage in the markets—and it might be an advantage for their customers as well, as they always get the best quotes. The smaller and less informed loose out however. In fact we have seen an increasing concentration in the FX-market over the last 10 years. The largest 10 firms did in 1998 control about 50 per cent of the market. 5.4 Data from the FX-market In April every three years Bank of International Settlements, BIS, collect data on transactions in the FX-market from 48 national central banks. The total volume reported in the survey for 2001 is found in figure 5.4. As we can see, after years of increase in FX-volume, the volume has fallen considerably over the last three years. This is probably fairly simple to explain—with the introduction of the EUR the number of heavily traded currencies fell dramatically. Figure 5.5 summarises the types of instruments used in the market. We see that most deals are made with ‘reporting’ dealers—dealers that are ‘registered’ by the central bank as reporters. We also see that most swaps are conducted as transactions with a life of less than 7 days—short-swaps are the leading type of swap transactions in this market. 140 Table5.4: 1 Figure Global foreign exchange market turnover1 Daily averages in April, in billions of US dollars Instrument 1989 1992 1995 1998 2 2001 Spot transactions 317 394 494 568 387 Outright forwards 27 58 97 128 131 190 324 546 734 656 56 44 53 60 36 590 820 1,190 1,490 1,210 570 750 990 1,400 1,210 Foreign exchange swaps Estimated gaps in reporting Total “traditional” turnover Memorandum item: Turnover at April 2001 3 exchange rates 1 Adjusted for local and cross-border double-counting. 2 Revised. 3 Non-US dollar legs of foreign currency transactions were converted into original currency amounts at average exchange rates for April of each survey year and then reconverted into US dollar amounts at average April 2001 exchange rates. Source: BIS, 2001 5.4.1 International currency Just as domestic currency is the reference in the domestic economy, there needs to be a point of reference in the international currency markets as well. In a flexible currency system this point is not clear. However, at different times Greek coins, Roman coins, Florins, bills of credit on German banks or British pounds have worked as accepted means of payment in international transactions. Since the Second World War USD has filled this role, although some observers now predict a larger role for the EUR. How do we define an international currency? What will determine which currencies are dominating the world markets? Factors that the determine the international use of a currency is • size of the economy, • importance in international trade, • size, depth, liquidity, and openness of domestic financial4/13markets, 141 Table 2 Figure 5.5: Reported foreign exchange market turnover by instrument, counterparty and maturity1 Daily averages in April, in billions of US dollars 1992 Instrument/counterparty 1995 1998 2 2001 ....................................................... 394 494 568 387 With reporting dealers ............................... With other financial institutions .................. With non-financial customers..................... 282 47 62 325 94 75 348 121 99 218 111 58 Outright forwards .................................... 58 97 128 131 With reporting dealers ............................... With other financial institutions .................. With non-financial customers..................... Up to 7 days .............................................. Over 7 days and up to 1 year .................... Over 1 year................................................ 21 10 28 … … … 33 28 36 50 44 2 49 34 44 66 59 5 52 41 37 51 76 4 Foreign exchange swaps ........................ 324 546 734 656 With reporting dealers ............................... With other financial institutions .................. With non-financial customers..................... Up to 7 days .............................................. Over 7 days and up to 1 year .................... Over 1 year................................................ 238 39 47 … … … 370 108 68 382 155 7 512 124 98 529 192 10 419 177 60 450 197 8 Total.......................................................... 776 1,137 1,430 1,173 With reporting dealers ............................... With other financial institutions .................. With non-financial customers..................... 541 96 137 728 230 179 909 279 241 689 329 156 Local.......................................................... Cross-border.............................................. 316 391 526 613 658 772 499 674 Spot 1 Adjusted for local and cross-border double-counting. 2 Revised. Source: BIS, 2001 REVIEW Table 1 Figure 5.6: The roles of international money Functions of an International Currency Sector Function Private Official Unit of account Invoice Store of value Financial assets Exchange rate peg Reserves Medium of exchange Vehicle/substitution Intervention reserves in this currency and (ii) as a medium of Korean economy, U.S. exports comprise a much Source: Pollard, 2001 larger share of world exports. exchange if it is used for intervening in currency Clearly the dominance of the U.S. economy markets. and the decline of the U.K. economy in the twentieth The three functions of an international currency reinforce each other. For example, the use of a 142century were related to the rise of the dollar and the decline of the pound as international currencies. currency for invoicing trade and holding financial Likewise, the growth of the German and Japanese assets increases the likelihood that the currency 5/13 economies in the last several decades of the twenwill be used as a vehicle currency. In the official tieth century prompted the use of their currencies sector, if a country pegs its exchange rate to another in international markets. As a result, the overwhelmcurrency, it is likely to hold reserves in that currency ing dominance the dollar held in international and conduct its interventions in exchange markets markets in the 1950s and 1960s diminished. in that currency. In addition, the use of an interTable 2 compares the relative size of the U.S., national currency by one sector reinforces its use euro-area, and Japanese economies. The U.S. econby the other sector. For example, using a currency omy is the largest in the world, accounting for about as an exchange rate peg facilitates the use of that FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS Table 2 5.7: Factors that determine the international use of a currency Figure Comparison of United States, Euro-Area, and Japanese Economies in 1999 United States Euro area Japan Share of world GDP (%) 21.9 15.8 Share of world exports (%) 15.3 19.4 9.3 40,543.8 24,133.4 20,888.5 6,662.5 Financial markets ($ billions) Bank assets ($ billions) 7.6 7,555.3 12,731.3 Domestic debt securities outstanding ($ billions) 15,426.3 5,521.9 6,444.9 Stock market capitalization ($ billions) 17,562.2 5,880.2 7,781.4 NOTE: GDP is based on purchasing power parity equivalents. World exports excludes intra-euro-area trade. SOURCE: GDP: IMF, World Economic Outlook, October 2000. Exports: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics Quarterly, September 2000. Bank assets: European Central Bank, Monthly Bulletin; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Flow of Funds Accounts; IMF, International Financial Statistics. Debt securities: Bank for International Settlements, Quarterly Review of International Banking and Financial Market Developments. Stock market: Eurostat. exchange a currency for other2001 currencies limits its this currency; (ii) if this currency is used to facilitate Source: Pollard, the exchange of other currencies; and (iii) if this global use. At the end of World War II almost every currency is used as a substitute currency. country, with the exception of the United States, restricted the convertibility of its currency. This Invoice Currency • convertibility ofthecurrency, and inconvertibility persisted for first decade after the war. The convertibility of the U.S. dollar prompted The dollar is the main currency that functions its use as the currency in which international trade as a unit of account for private international transwas • conducted. macroeconomic policies. Policies actions. fostering lowdatainflation (i.e.of invoice a stable Although on the currency Macroeconomic policies also play an imporin international trade are limited, the available data tant role in determining whether cur- important. confirm the dominance of the dollar. In 1995 the value of money) area country’s especially rency will be used internationally. These policies U.S. dollar was used as the invoice currency for more affect a country’s economic growth and its openthan half of world exports, down only slightly from ness to the world economy. Policies fostering a low 1980, as shown in Table 3. The Deutsche mark was So what currencies are actually international currency markets? inflation environment are especially important. usedthein next most popular invoice currency, used for Countries experiencing hyperinflation and/or approximately 13 percent of world exports, followed crises often see the use of their Aspolitical can be seen from tables 5.8currenand 5.9 the most traded is the USD, by the French franc andcurrency the British pound. While cies collapse not only internationally but also the yen’s use in world trade lagged behind these within domestic economy, as residents turn is the European currencies, its share had more than and thethemost traded currency pair USD/EUR. to a substitute currency. doubled since 1980. The combined share of the Clearly the size and openness of the U.S. econfour major euro currencies was less than half that omy have been major factors in encouraging the of the U.S. dollar. international use of the dollar in the post-World More importantly, there is a clear distinction War II period. Its use as an international currency between the use of the dollar and other invoice in the private sector and the effect of the emergence currencies. The U.S. dollar is the only currency Invoice of the eurocurrency in this sector is examined in the next whose use in world trade far surpasses its country section. share in world trade, as shown by its internationalization ratio in Table 3. An internationalization ratio THE PRIVATE USES OF AN Rules for choice of invoice currency: less than 1.0, as with the yen, lira, and guilder, INTERNATIONAL CURRENCY indicates that not all of that country’s exports are denominated in the local currency. An internationAs stated above, a currency operates as an alization ratio greater than 1.0, as with the dollar, international currency in the private sector (i) if • Between industrialised countries: price the good in the currency of the the mark, and the pound, indicates that other couninternational trade and debt contracts are priced in 5.4.2 The roles of international money exporter. S E P T E M B E R / O C TO B E R 2 0 0 1 19 • Between industrialised countries and developing countries: price the good in the currency of the industrialised country, or in a third country currency (most likely the USD). 143 3 Figure 5.8: Currency distribution of Table reported global foreign exchange market Currency distribution of reported global foreign exchange market turnover1 turnover Percentage shares of average daily turnover in April Currency 1989 1992 1995 1998 2 2001 US dollar................................................. Euro ....................................................... 3 Deutsche mark ...................................... French franc ........................................... ECU and other EMS currencies ............. Japanese yen ......................................... Pound sterling ........................................ Swiss franc ............................................. Canadian dollar ...................................... Australian dollar...................................... 4 Swedish krona ...................................... 4 Hong Kong dollar .................................. 4 Norwegian krone ................................... 4 Danish krone ......................................... 4 Singapore dollar .................................... 4 South African rand ................................ 4 Mexican peso ........................................ 4 Korean won ........................................... 4 New Zealand dollar ............................... 4 Polish zloty ............................................ 4 Brazilian real ......................................... 4 Russian rouble ...................................... 4 Taiwan dollar ......................................... 4 Chilean peso ......................................... 4 Czech koruna ........................................ 4 Indian rupee .......................................... 4 Thai baht ............................................... 4 Malaysian ringgit ................................... 4 Saudi riyal ............................................. Other currencies..................................... 90 . 27 2 4 27 15 10 1 2 … … … … … … … … … … … … … … … … … … … 22 82.0 . 39.6 3.8 11.8 23.4 13.6 8.4 3.3 2.5 1.3 1.1 0.3 0.5 0.3 0.3 … … 0.2 … … … … … … … … … … 7.7 83.3 . 36.1 7.9 15.7 24.1 9.4 7.3 3.4 2.7 0.6 0.9 0.2 0.6 0.3 0.2 … … 0.2 … … … … … … … … … … 7.1 87.3 . 30.1 5.1 17.3 20.2 11.0 7.1 3.6 3.1 0.4 1.3 0.4 0.4 1.2 0.5 0.6 0.2 0.3 0.1 0.4 0.3 0.1 0.1 0.3 0.1 0.2 0.0 0.1 8.2 90.4 37.6 . . . 22.7 13.2 6.1 4.5 4.2 2.6 2.3 1.5 1.2 1.1 1.0 0.9 0.8 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 6.7 All currencies........................................ 200 200.0 200.0 200.0 200.0 1 Because two currencies are involved in each transaction, the sum of the percentage shares of individual currencies totals 200% instead of 100%. The figures relate to reported “net-net” turnover, ie they are adjusted for both local and cross-border double-counting, except for 1989 data, which are available only on a “gross-gross” basis. 2 Revised. 3 Data for April 1989 exclude domestic trading involving the Deutsche mark in Germany. 4 For 1992-98, the data cover local home currency trading only. Source: BIS, 2001 144 6/13 Table 4 1 Reported foreign exchange turnover by currency pairs Figure 5.9: Reported foreign exchange turnover by currency pairs Daily averages in April, in billions of US dollars and percentages 1992 Currency pair 1995 1998 2 2001 Amount % share Amount % share Amount % share Amount % share USD/EUR .............. USD/DEM .............. USD/FRF ............... USD/XEU............... USD/OthEMS ........ USD/JPY ............... USD/GBP .............. USD/CHF............... USD/CAD .............. USD/AUD .............. USD/Oth ................ EUR/JPY ............... EUR/GBP .............. EUR/CHF............... EUR/Oth ................ DEM/JPY ............... DEM/GBP .............. DEM/CHF .............. DEM/FRF............... DEM/XEU .............. DEM/OthEMS ........ DEM/Oth................ 3 OthEMS/OthEMS . Other currency pairs....................... . 192 19 13 43 155 77 49 25 18 48 . . . . 18 23 13 10 6 21 20 3 . 25 2 2 6 20 10 6 3 2 6 . . . . 2 3 2 1 1 3 3 0 . 254 51 18 104 242 78 61 38 29 72 . . . . 24 21 18 34 6 38 16 3 . 22 4 2 9 21 7 5 3 3 6 . . . . 2 2 2 3 1 3 1 0 . 291 58 17 176 257 118 79 50 42 172 . . . . 24 31 18 10 3 35 18 5 . 20 4 1 12 18 8 5 3 3 12 . . . . 2 2 1 1 0 2 1 0 352 . . . . 230 125 57 50 47 197 30 24 12 22 . . . . . . . . 30 . . . . 20 11 5 4 4 17 3 2 1 2 . . . . . . 25 3 30 3 31 2 24 2 All currency pairs 778 100 1,137 100 1,430 100 1,173 100 1 Adjusted for local and cross-border double-counting. only. 2 Revised. 3 . The data cover local home currency trading Source: BIS, 2001 145 7/13 REVIEW Table 3 Figure 5.10: Invoice currency Trade Invoiced in Major Currencies Percent of world exports Internationalization ratio Currency 1980 1995 1980 U.S. dollar 56.4 52.0 4.5 3.9 2.1 4.7 0.3 0.6 13.6 13.2 1.4 1.4 6.2 5.5 0.9 1.0 Japanese yen Deutsche mark French franc 1995 British pound 6.5 5.4 1.1 1.1 Italian lira 2.2 3.3 0.5 0.8 2.6 2.8 0.7 0.9 24.6 24.8 NA NA Netherlands guilder Euro-4 NOTE: Euro-4 is the share of the four euro-area currencies listed in the table. No data were available for the other euro-area currencies. World exports includes intra-euro-area trade. The internationalization ratio is the ratio of the share of world exports denominated in a currency to the share of the issuing country in world exports. SOURCE: Bekx (1998, Table 3, p. 8). 2001 tries use thatSource: currencyPollard, to invoice some (or all) of the lower its transaction costs; the lower its transtheir exports.6 action costs, the more likely it is to be accepted. What determines the currency of invoice in Related factors that explain these patterns are world trade? A number of studies including those convertibility and the the expected stability of the • Between developing countries: most likely price good in USD. by Grassman (1973), Page (1981), and Black (1990) currency. As noted above, the use of the dollar as revealed the following patterns. Trade in manufacan invoice currency was prompted by the lack of tured goods among the industrial economies is convertibility of most other currencies in the 1950s. most often priced in the(like currency the exporter. use ofpriced developing Commodities oil,of metals et.c.) The arelimited mainly incountries’ USD. currencies If the exporter’s currency is not used, then the in world trade arose in part because many of these importer’s currency is the most frequent choice. countries restricted (and some continue to restrict) Only rarely is a third country’s currency used. Trade the convertibility of their currencies. Black (1990) between and developing countries is • Is industrial it important which currency isshowed usedthatasthean currency? Yes, shareinvoice of a country’s exports denomgenerally priced in the currency of the industrial inated in its domestic currency declines the greater country that of a reduce third country. Trade between expected depreciation of itsin currency. Thus, it ormight currency risk foris the businesses situated the country developing countries is often priced in the currency the currencies of countries with high inflation are of a third country. When a third country’s currency seldom used in international trade. where thistrade, currency belongs. However, currency might generally is used for invoicing the U.S. dollar is the The mere creation ofrisk the euro as a currency most likely choice. Trade in primary commodities should provide ample incentive for its use as an is almost invoiced in U.S.cheaply dollars because be always removed quite by usinginvoice options orReplacing forward currency. the contracts. currencies of 12 these products are predominantly priced in dollars countries with a single currency reduces the on international exchanges. transaction costs involved in currency exchanges. According to Hartmann (1996), two factors Although only a small number of firms within the • Would it reduce risk if a commodity is priced in the national currency? that explain these patterns are transaction costs euro area have already switched to invoicing in and acceptability. The lower the cost of buying and euros, the advent of euro notes and coins, along Norway oilforeign price risk has two factors: changes in the oil price measellingIn a currency in the exchange market, the more likely is its use for invoicing trade. In 6 An internationalization ratio greater than or equal to 1.0 does not addition, the more currency is for other that all of the homerate country’s between exports are priced in its currency. sured in accepted USD, aand changes in theimply exchange USD and According to data provided in Bekx (1998) in 1995, 92 percent of U.S. transactions, the more likely it is to be used as an exports, 75 percent of German exports, 62 percent of British exports, invoice currency. Clearly these two factors are mutuand 52 percent of French exports were invoiced in their domestic NOK. In onea currency only has oil price risk. However, notice that ally supportive. The the more US accepted is, the currencies. 20 taking two risks instead of one does only imply increased risk if the S E P T E M B E R / O C TO B E R 2 0 0 1 fluctuations of the two assets are positively correlated. In fact there is no reason to believe that the oil price and the USD is positively correlated. In the case of Norway, the volatility of changes in the oil price measured in NOK is not very different from the volatility changes in 146 Figure 5.11: The oil price in NOK and USD from 1998 to 2001. Indexed values, index=100 in January 1, 1998 300 250 200 150 100 50 1/01/98 10/08/98 7/15/99 OILNOKI 4/20/00 1/25/01 OILUSDI Source: Datastream the oil price measured in USD (a standard deviation on daily data from 1990 to the end of 2001 gives 3.58 against 3.60. Notice however that this result will be very sample dependent). Vehicle currency When making a transaction between e.g. NOK and NZD one will have several choices available. One can • buy NZD against the delivery of NOK. This does however assume a 147 coincidence of wants. The bank selling NZD should also want NOK. • buy USD against the delivery of NOK, and then buy NZD against the delivery of USD. • or even more intricate, buy EUR against the delivery of NOK, USD against the delivery of EUR and NZD against the delivery of USD. Why should one choose a strategy involving more than one transaction? Because the transactions costs will depend on the liquidity in each bilateral currency market. E.g. 80 per cent of all spot trade (that is trades to be delivered within two working days) in the Norwegian market is conducted between NOK and EUR. According to table 5.9 in April 2001 91 per cent of all currency trades included the USD. Most trades in NZD is probably conducted against USD. So it might well generate the lowest transaction costs if one makes two or three transactions instead on only one.2 A vehicle currency will emerge each time the indirect exchange costs through the vehicle currency are less than the direct exchange costs between non-vehicle currencies. In Norway (and other small European nations) EUR probably works as a vehicle currency. For most other transactions, the USD is probably the vehicle currency of choice. Store of value—the choice of denomination of financial assets Diversification is an important concept in finance. One wants to diversify one’s portfolio across interest bearing paper and equity, between different 2 This has very real application in the small scale. If you carry foreign currency to e.g. Eastern Europe one would normally find a much lower spread (distance between bid and ask prices—or the sell and buy offers) if one trades with EUR than with NOK. One can often save money if one exchanged NOK to EUR in a Norwegian bank, and only used EUR when travelling. In more developed markets, the cost of using NOK instead of other currencies is however small. 148 REVIEW Figure 5.12: Vehicle currency Table 8 Foreign Exchange Market Transactions Involving Select Currencies (Percent of Total) April 1998 Category U.S. dollar Japanese yen Spot 78.8 24.7 Deutsche mark 42.7 French franc 3.3 Euro area* 56.8 Pound sterling 11.6 Forwards 81.4 26.7 28.0 5.1 50.7 12.3 Swaps 95.2 16.7 20.0 6.5 48.8 10.2 Total 87.4 20.8 29.8 5.1 52.2 11.0 *Euro area includes the currencies of the current member countries plus the Danish krone and the ecu. SOURCE: Bank for International Settlements, Central Bank Survey of Foreign Exchange and Derivatives Market Activity 1998. Basle: BIS, May 1999. Source: Pollard, 2001 kets.” Whereas, the infrequent interventions by the mark and yen taking part in 20 and 17 percent, respectively, of all trades. individual European central banks in securities The use of the dollar in foreign exchange transmarkets “tended to discourage the development of actions was well above its use in international trade private securities markets and foster the predomiissuers of bonds and equity and also between different currencies. However, and debt contracts, indicating its role as a vehicle nance of bank-intermediated finance.” The ECB has currency. The BIS (1999) notes that evidence of the continued this practice of infrequent interventions. the willingness invest markets in a certain currency will on size, openness, dollar’s role as a depend vehicle currency is provided by its In general, it is activeto in securities only use in seven of the ten most heavily traded currency once per week. pairs.stability The report also notescurrency. that it is standard pracFor now U.S. financial markets markets continue to lead and liquidity of financial and the of the tice for the dollar to be used as a vehicle currency the world in both size and liquidity. As a result, the in swaps, which explains the high percentage of U.S. dollar remains the major currency in interThe bond EURmarkets. will only behowever, able tohascompete with USDtheasU.S. the currency ofuse choice swaps involving dollar and the low of national The euro, the yen and mark in these trades. already become a major player in these markets, The use of a currency as a vehicle currency is inand international the European financial markets get the same its use will likelydebt expandmarkets as euro-areaiffinancial determined primarily by transactions costs. Transmarket integration proceeds. The development of actions costs are inversely related to volume in eachon a euro-area capital market the U.S. marketmarkets. size and liquidity assimilar thetoAmerican This will probably depend bilateral currency market.20 This volume is in turn should provide benefits to both economies by determined by a currency’s share in international increasing the options available to borrowers and the levelon of integration in the Europeantrade financial markets. and capital flows. Thus, the use of a currency lenders both sides of the Atlantic. in invoicing international trade, in international Vehicle Currency capital markets, and as a reserve currency lowers the transactions costs associated with the use of The There useareofnoadirect substitute currency data available on vehicle that currency. currencies, but this information can be gleaned from A vehicle currency emerges whenever the the shares of currencies in foreign exchange transindirect exchange costs through the vehicle are less 18 In 1998 the dollar was actions, as shown in Table 8. If there is loss of trust in the national currency, people will trytwo tonon-vehicle exchange than direct exchange costs between involved in 87 percent of all currency exchanges.19 currencies. For example, given the depth of the The euro legacy currencies were involved in 52 exchange market dollars, itLoss may beofless costlycan their holdings of this currency into presumably saferfor assets. trust percent of all exchanges, with the Deutsche mark the most often traded of these currencies. The yen 18 These gathered from a triennialhas survey of foreign exchange e.g. under of hyperinflation, ordataifarethe country an exchange wasoccur used in 21 percentperiods of all currency trades. The markets conducted by the BIS. dollar’s dominance was especially clear in forward 19 Since there are two currencies involved in an exchange, the total and regime swap transactions. The dollar was involved in rate that might break down. share of all currencies traded on international exchanges will equal 81 percent of all forward trades compared with the 200 percent. However, a single currency can, at most, be involved in 100 percent of all exchanges. mark’s and yen’s shares of 28 and 27 percent, respecIn countries with a weak legal system or a weak central bank, large hold20 tively. In swaps the contrast was even greater. The The use of transactions cost theory to explain the rise of a vehicle dollar was involved in 95 percent of all swaps, with currency was developed by Krugman (1980) and Chrystal (1984). ings of currency is often kept in foreign currency. In most countries the 26 S E P T E M B E R / O C TO B E R 2 0 0 1 currency of choice will be the USD. In some Eastern European countries the EUR is more popular than USD, mainly because of the proximity and trade with the EU countries. Montenegro is probably the most extreme case—they have adopted the EUR as the means of payment. 149 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS Table 6 Figure 5.13: Denomination of international debt International Debt Securities by Currency of Issue (Percent) Amounts outstanding Currency 1993 Share of new issues 1998 2000 1998 1999 2000 Total securities U.S. dollar 41.1 45.9 48.7 54.1 45.2 44.0 Japanese yen 13.2 11.3 8.2 5.6 5.3 8.3 Swiss franc 7.3 3.8 2.2 3.3 2.0 1.7 Euro area* 24.8 27.2 30.1 24.6 36.8 33.9 Other E.U.† 7.9 8.5 8.2 8.9 8.0 9.2 7.6 7.9 7.8 8.3 7.7 9.1 Pound sterling Bonds and notes U.S. dollar 38.9 45.3 48.7 51.1 43.8 42.3 Japanese yen 14.0 11.7 8.6 6.3 6.7 11.4 Swiss franc 7.7 3.8 2.2 2.7 1.6 1.4 Euro area* 25.7 27.6 30.0 28.0 38.3 34.2 Other E.U.† 8.1 8.5 8.1 9.0 7.3 8.4 7.8 7.9 7.7 8.2 7.0 8.2 Pound sterling Money Market U.S. dollar 79.4 59.9 49.1 61.0 48.8 47.5 Japanese yen 0.2 2.5 2.3 4.0 1.4 1.9 Swiss franc 1.8 4.5 2.3 4.7 2.9 2.3 Euro area* 8.5 19.2 32.4 17.2 32.9 33.2 Other E.U.† 4.1 8.4 9.5 8.8 9.8 11.0 4.0 8.3 9.3 8.7 9.7 11.0 Pound sterling *Euro area includes the currencies of the 11 original members of the euro area and currency composites, such as the ecu. † Other E.U. includes the currencies of Denmark, Sweden, and the United Kingdom. SOURCE: Bank for International Settlements, Quarterly Review of International Banking and Financial Market Developments, March 2001. the 1950s. By the 1970s, however, the currency Source: Pollard, 2001 denomination of bond issues had become more diversified, as shown in Table 5. Nevertheless, the U.S. dollar has remained the most popular currency choice for issuing bonds in international markets, as shown in Table 6.9 By the 1960s the euro legacy currencies, taken together as a group, had become the second most widely used currency in international bond markets, a status that continues today. The Japanese yen was not used at all until the 1970s, and its share of new issues lags far below that of the dollar or euro. The use of the Swiss franc in international bond markets, which rivaled the Deutsche mark in the 1970s, declined precipitously in the 1990s.10 In international money markets as well, the dollar is the currency of choice, but again its dominance has declined, as noted in Table 6. The increased use of the euro legacy currencies in these markets during the 1990s is particularly noteworthy. In 1993 these currencies accounted for 8.5 percent of the outstanding debt in international money markets. By 1998 this share had increased to 19.2 percent. 9 The data in Tables 5 and 6 rely on different sources and hence may not be directly comparable. 10 Some policymakers in Switzerland were concerned that the creation of the euro might result in a sharp rise in demand for assets denominated in Swiss francs. See Laxton and Prasad (1997) for an analysis of this argument. 150 S E P T E M B E R / O C TO B E R 2 0 0 1 23 REVIEW Figure 2 Figure 5.14: US seignorage revenue Seignorage Revenues from Foreign Holdings of U.S. Dollars Billions of 1996 $ 14 12 10 8 6 4 THE OFFIC INTERNAT 2 0 1973 75 77 79 81 83 85 87 89 91 93 95 97 1999 Source: Pollard, 2001 Percent of federal government expenditures It1.2is estimated that about 55 per cent (!) of the total U.S. currency held by the non-bank public was held outside the US in 1995. The same 1.0 number for the DEM was 35 per cent. The seignorage revenue from foreign holdings is estimated to an average of about 9 billion USD a year over the 0.8 last decade. That is less than one per cent of US government expenditure. However it would amount to between 5 and 7 per cent of Norwegian GDP— 0.6 still a reasonably large sum of money. 0.4 0.2 151 0.0 1973 75 to lag behind Foreign holde ble, secure cu value of the e against the do existence, wi the euro as a If the eur substitute cur ECB will rise. revenues mig demand for s euro and the Emerson et a age revenues a year for the 77 79 81 83 85 87 89 91 93 95 97 1999 SOURCE: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Exchange Under the from 1946 to were tied to t Bretton Wood their currenc their currenc those countri continued to In 1975, 52 m of the Interna their currenc The euro lega popular choic the African F currency use and the Span for the curren Chapter 6 The floating exchange rate 6.1 Introduction Michael Mussa has summarised our understanding of flexible exchange rates in the following way: [T]he largely random character of exchange rate fluctuations under floating exchange rate regimes is explained by the prevalence of “news” in inducing most exchange rate changes; the tendency for nominal and real exchange rates to move in together under a floating rate regime is explained by the contrast between the behavior of nominal exchange rates as randomly fluctuating asset prices and the behavior of national price levels as relatively sluggishly adjusting variables; and with respect to the influence of economic policies on exchange rates, what matters is not simply what policies governments pursue today, but also to an important extent, the policies they are expected to pursue in the future. Despite this progress made over the last 30 years, we still do not have a good understanding of the observed behavior of exchange rates. Jeffrey Frankel and Andrew Rose (1995) state that 152 [t]o repeat a central fact of life, there is remarkably little evidence that macroeconomic variables have consistent strong effects on floating exchange rates, except during extraordinary circumstances such as hyperinflations. Such negative findings have led the profession to a certain degree of pessimism vis-à-vis exchange rate research. 6.2 High expectations During the Bretton Woods era many economist argued in favour of floating exchange rates. Six main claims were made. 1. Real exchange rates would be more stable with floating than fixed exchange rates. The argument was that since the exchange rate could adjust faster than the price level, one should expect a floating exchange rate to allow faster adjustment than a fixed exchange rate, as in the last case all adjustment was left to the domestic price level. Outcome: in fact variability in the real exchange rate has increased considerably with floating exchange rates. Real and nominal exchange rates tend to move together, and nominal exchange rate changes tend to increase the variability in the real exchange rate, not alleviate variability. 2. Adjustments in fixed exchange rates tend to be infrequent, but abrupt and large. They often take a form that can be described as “crises”. Floating exchange rates was supposed to change slowly, smoothly and predictably. Outcome: Flexible exchange rates have been very volatile. Changes are abrupt and fast. Neither are they predictable, as we will see in the 153 discussion of the UIP below. 3. Floating exchange rates were supposed to adjust to insulate the economy against shocks from abroad. Remember the n-1 problem: in a fixed exchange rate regime monetary policy had to be adjusted in all countries if adjusted in one country. Outcome: In fact, correlation between business cycles have tended to increase, not fall, over the last three decades. Even in a floating regime the n-1 problem can not be ignored. If interest rate differentials between economies are allowed to be to high, we experience changes in real exchange rates that are not easily accepted. The result is that real interest rates are highly correlated. 4. In a floating exchange rate the central bank gets complete control over the money supply. Outcome: Even in a floating regime the exchange rate can not be ignored. The exchange rate is probably the most important “price” in every moderately open economy. The stylised example of an independent monetary policy is an illusion. 5. With floating exchange rates, exchange rates would adjust faster to balance the current account, thereby decreasing the political pressure for e.g. tariffs an other measures to reduce trade imbalances. Outcome: if anything, current account imbalances have increased with floating exchange rates. 6. With a floating exchange rate one did no longer need a foreign exchange reserve. These money could be freed for other purposes. 154 Outcome: Foreign exchange reserves are in real terms larger today than in the Bretton Woods era. How come that we have missed the point so completely? Two possibilities: either our models have been just plain wrong, or we did not interpret them correctly. The main problem is probably that floating exchange rates are much more volatile than was expected. However, this is a feature exchange rates share with all asset markets—asset prices tend to fluctuate much more than underlying “fundamentals” should presume. 6.3 “Excess volatility” and some ‘puzzles’ of exchange rate economics In the beginning of this course we made two basic assumptions when we moved from the domestic relationship for money demand to a function for the exchange rate. We assumed that PPP and UIP would hold. PPP implies that given the function P∗ Qt = t, t Pt (6.1) we assume Q to be one, or at least stable over time. The UIP states that Et t+1 1 + it = . t 1 + i∗t (6.2) According to the UIP Et t+1 should be our best guess of t at time t. Table 6.1 give the standard deviations of return for a number of variables. What we can see from this table is that from week to week one should expect very limited volatility in prices. The volatility in interest rates are 10 times the volatility in prices.1 The volatility in the exchange rate is a 100 times 1 Note that as we are looking at the volatility in bond interest rates and not bond prices we underestimate the risk of investing in long term bonds. A one per cent swing in a bond with maturity in 10 years implies a substantial swing in the current price of the bond. 155 that of the interest rate. However, we can notice that exchange rate volatility can only be characterised as “excess” if compared with the volatility of prices and interest rates. Compared with return in the stock market or in a highly traded storable good like oil, volatility is in fact rather low. Table 6.1: Standard deviation of weekly return (weekly change) for different markets. Sample cover 11.1992-03.2002 St.dev. in per cent CPI Norway 0.0003 Germany 0.0002 10 year gov. bond* Norway 0.003 Germany 0.003 3 month interbank* Norway 0.006 Germany 0.004 spread (NOK-DEM) 0.005 Exchange rates NOK/DEM 0.79 DEM/USD 1.37 Stockmarket index Norway 2.79 Germany 3.44 Traded goods oil in USD 5.21 *volatility in i What conclusion can we draw if we combine our results from table 6.1 with the two parity conditions stated above? If price volatility is low, and the nominal exchange rate volatility is high, the volatility of the real exchange rate must be highly correlated with the volatility in the nominal exchange rate. Further, it the volatility in the differential between domestic and foreign interest rates is low, while the volatility of the current spot rate is high, then we should expect a very high correlation between the expected future 156 exchange rate and the current exchange rate as well. These are de facto puzzles. However, they are probably not puzzles only related to the market for foreign exchange. Rather they are related to all asset markets. In general changes in asset prices are not well explained by changes in fundamentals, at least not over a “short time horizon” of say, up to two years. The reason is that asset prices fluctuate so much more than other variables in the economy. This volatility can not be well explained with current economic models. One therefore often hear that asset markets show “excess volatility”. We should add a third problem not reflected in the table above. The real exchange rate tends to fluctuate in long cycles, with a mean reversion time of between 2 and 6 years, depending on the country and the exchange rate regime. This implies that over time fundamentals do seem to explain exchange rates after all. Why is this a puzzle? Because we can not understand why fundamentals should only be reflected in asset prices over a time span of over two years. Most of the explanations given below for the high volatility in exchange rates might give a good explanation for a divergence between fundamentals and the exchange rate for a few months, or maybe a year. However none of the models can explain why exchange rates are mean reverting over 4-6 years... 6.3.1 The FX market vs. the stock market Given the focus on excess volatility in the FX market it is reasonable to compare this market with the volatility of the stock market. Figure 6.1 depict the log of NOK/DEM exchange rate, indexed to 100 in week 47 1992. In the figure we have drawn a trend line over the period.2 Figure 6.2 depict 2 The trend line is calculated as with Hodrick-Prescott filter with a smoothing parameter of 100,000. 157 Figure 6.1: The NOK/DEM exchange rate. Log of index=100 in week 47, 1992. Trend calculated with H-P filter. 4.75 4.70 4.65 4.60 4.55 11/20/92 10/21/94 9/20/96 8/21/98 7/21/00 a similar figure forEURNOKINDEX the Oslo Stock Exchange.HPNOKEURINDE100 In figure 6.3 we depict only the trend lines. We see that the the two graphs have many similar features. Both tend to move in long swings. However, as becomes very clear in figure 6.4, over time the underlying movements in the stock exchange are of much larger magnitude than the long term changes in the exchange rate. Figure 6.5 depict the difference between the actual value and the trend. As we see both series fluctuate considerably around the trend. Also here the two series have substantial similarities. When we take the two series into the same diagram, as is done in figure 6.6, we see that even here the stock exchange has a much higher volatility than the exchange rate. 158 Figure 6.2: Index of Oslo Stock Exchange. Log of index=100 in week 47, 1992. Trend calculated with H-P filter. 5.8 5.6 5.4 5.2 5.0 4.8 4.6 4.4 11/20/92 10/21/94 9/20/96 OSLOINDEX 159 8/21/98 7/21/00 HPTREND09 Figure 6.3: The H-P trend in NOK/DEM exchange rate and the Oslo Stock Exchange. Log of index=100 in week 47, 1992. 4.70 4.68 4.66 4.64 4.62 4.60 4.58 11/20/92 10/21/94 9/20/96 8/21/98 7/21/00 HPNOKEURINDE100 5.8 5.6 5.4 5.2 5.0 4.8 4.6 11/20/92 10/21/94 9/20/96 8/21/98 HPOSLOINDEX100 160 7/21/00 Figure 6.4: The H-P trend in NOK/DEM exchange rate and the Oslo Stock Exchange. Log of index=100 in week 47, 1992. 5.8 5.6 5.4 5.2 5.0 4.8 4.6 4.4 11/20/92 10/21/94 9/20/96 HPNOKEURINDE100 161 8/21/98 7/21/00 HPOSLOINDEX100 Figure 6.5: The difference from H-P trend for NOK/DEM exchange rate the Oslo Stock Exchange. Log of index=100 in week 47, 1992. 0.10 0.05 0.00 -0.05 -0.10 11/20/92 10/21/94 9/20/96 8/21/98 7/21/00 EURNOKINDEXVOL 0.2 0.1 0.0 -0.1 -0.2 -0.3 -0.4 11/20/92 10/21/94 9/20/96 8/21/98 OSLOINDEXVOL 162 7/21/00 Figure 6.6: The difference from H-P trend for NOK/DEM exchange rate the Oslo Stock Exchange. Log of index=100 in week 47, 1992. 0.2 0.1 0.0 -0.1 -0.2 -0.3 -0.4 11/20/92 10/21/94 9/20/96 EURNOKINDEXVOL 163 8/21/98 7/21/00 OSLOINDEXVOL Some tentative conclusions: • The stock market and the FX market reveal many of the same features. They both tend to move in long swings, with substantial volatility around these swings. • However, both the movements in the trend and the volatility around the trend tends to be less for the FX market than for the stock market. • This might indicate that the FX market is slightly more “efficient” than the stock market. If so, this is not a surprising conclusion. After all, as we discussed in Lecture 5, transaction costs are lower and volume is higher in the FX market than in the stock market. Both factors should contribute to a more efficient market. 6.4 Random walk?—the Meese and Rogoff results During the 1970’s much work was done on econometric models for forecasting exchange rates. Some of these models showed promising results. However, in 1983 there was published a study by Meese and Rogoff that summarised the ability of such econometric models to forecast exchange rate changes out-of-sample. The results were devastating. To forecast something in-the-sample tells us about the ability of the model to explain the observations we use in the regression. In out-of-sample forecasts we use the model to forecast time periods that was not included in the actual regression analysis. Meese and Rogoff estimated four different models using monthly data. They had data from March 1973 to June 1981. First they estimated the 164 Table 6.2: Out-of-sample forecasting performance of different exchange rate models—root of mean squared error of forecasts 1, 6 and 12 months ahead. Random walk Monetary Dornbusch Portfolio balance USD/DEM 1 month 3.7 3.2 3.7 3.5 6 month 8.7 9.6 12.0 10.0 12 month 13.0 16.1 18.9 15.7 USD/JPY 1 month 3.7 4.1 4.4 4.2 6 month 11.6 13.4 13.9 11.9 12 month 18.3 18.6 20.4 19.0 USD/GBP 1 month 2.6 2.8 2.9 2.7 6 month 6.5 8.9 8.9 7.2 12 month 9.9 14.6 13.7 14.6 Source: Meese and Rogoff, 1983 models over the period from March 1973 to November 1976. Then they used the parameters estimated to forecast the changes in the exchange rate 1, 6 and 12 months into the future from November 1976. In this forecast they used actual realised values of the “fundamental variables”—taking a very strict assumption of perfect foresight. They then extended the regression with one month, to December 1976, and reported forecasts. They repeated this procedure for the whole period till June 1981. Having made these forecasts, they compared the forecasts with actual outcomes, and reported the squared errors of the forecasts. A summary of their findings is given in table 6.2. Meese and Rogoff had estimated three models with “economic contents”— a monetary equilibrium model, the Dornbusch model and a portfolio balance model. In addition they had estimated a “naive” model with no economic content—i.e. a random walk. A random walk is taking the very simple assumption that the current exchange rate is the best predictor of the future 165 exchange rate, i.e. et+1 = a + et + ut , (6.3) where a is a constant and u is the error term, with the expected normal distribution u ∼ N (0, σ 2 ). As we can see from table 6.2 the random walk was the best predictor in eight out of nine cases. This is really equivalent to stating two things: • Changes in the exchange rate are unpredictable, and • the exchange rate is not mean reverting. This has lead to the idea that exchange rates are in fact following a random walk process. However, one needs to take this with some modifications. • The result is only valid if we talk about purely floating exchange rate between industrialised countries in the short term. • And even here the random walk is not completely satisfying. It shows up that exchange rate returns—an other word for the change in the exchange rate—have fat tails. In other words, returns are not normally distributed after all. What does fat tails mean? While most changes in the exchange rate are small, some changes are very large. We see more large changes than we should expect if the errors were drawn from a normal distribution. • More specific, the exchange rate tends to follow an ARCH/GARCH process. This implies that a period of high volatility is usually followed by more periods of high volatility, and a period of low volatility is followed by periods of low volatility. Volatility in the exchange rate is to some degree predictable. 166 6.5 Equilibrium models Ideally we want to build models that assume rational behavior and complete information. The rational behavior/perfect information case is in the end the only real benchmark we have. We need to gain full understanding of what this framework can tell us before we modify these basic assumptions. The rational behavior/perfect information was our starting point when we derived an exchange rate model in Lecture 2. We concluded that the exchange rate, e, could be expressed as a function of money supply, real output, foreign interest rates and foreign prices, i.e. as s−t ∞ 1 X η et = (ms − φys + ηi∗s+1 − p∗s ). 1 + η s=t 1 + η (6.4) The above framework is known as a “monetary equilibrium model”. In this model all volatility should be a result of new information, “news”, as all history will be reflected in the price at every given point of time. However, given our observations of the very high volatility in the exchange rate compared to the fundamental variables in this equation, it is tempting to conclude that this model is no good. There have been attempts to model exchange rate movements using a reasonable assumption of what is “news”. Such research tend to find that the exchange rate moves as much in periods with no “news” as it does in periods with “news”. So “news” do not seem to explain the exchange rate very well. One should on the other hand not forget that the monetary equilibrium model does seem to to have some explanatory power in the long run. The exchange rate is reverting to fundamentals. It only takes much longer than we are able to explain. We should ask why our model is no good in the short and medium term. Some arguments: 167 • The model specification might be no good. E.g. most tests of the above model are done assuming a linear framework. It is however an established fact that asset prices have a non-linear relationship to fundamentals. One result from research on “chaos models”, as discussed in ch. 9 in De Grauwe, is that in a non-linear framework there might be a relationship between fundamentals and prices even in the short run. A problem has been that such non-linear models are very difficult to make intellectually tractable. • Some of our basic assumptions, like the assumptions of free trade and free capital mobility might not hold. There might also be public interference not captured in the model. • In equation (6.4) we have made the very convenient assumption of no bubbles. However, in the many cases bubbles might be a real problem, i.e. remember our discussion of rational bubbles. • More problematic is the fact that we really do not understand how expectations are formed. This is probably the best explanation of why the equilibrium models do not fit, because it is an explanation that helps us understand why we do not understand asset market in general—the FX market is nothing special. What do we not understand? Perhaps markets are not as rational as this model assumes, or perhaps we do not fully understand what ‘rational behaviour’ really implies. The economic definition of rationality—to be a forward looking and maximise some simple utility function—might not be a good description of reality. Other possibilities exist as well: • In the above model we assume that all variables, i.e. the price level, as everything else is given exogenously, will adjust instantaneously to 168 clear all markets. However, we know that prices might be sticky, at least for periods of up to a year. If we assume that prices take time to adjust, we must take into regard that it takes time to move from one equilibrium to another. The economy will spend time “outside equilibrium”—i.e. the introduction of “disequilibrium models”—the main tool in the “New Keynesian economics”; dominating much of current research in macroeconomics. • When we looked at the FX-market, we saw that different dealers seemed to follow different strategies. This will be the case for many agents in asset markets. E.g. we know for certain that many traders will buy assets based on so-called technical analysis. Technical analysis bases buy and sell recommendations on graphs of historic prices. Such traders will by definition be backward looking—they will not fit our forward looking framework. • An other feature of the FX market was low transparency. This might indicate that we as researchers do not have full control over which information dealers actually use when they set their exchange rates. We might have a “missing variable” problem. In the following sections we will investigate whether these three options can help us understand the “exchange rate puzzle”. 6.6 Disequilibrium models Disequilibrium models come in many forms. We will focus on the assumptions that prices are sticky. How will this affect our discussion of the exchange rate? When we derived the model in equation (6.4) we assumed both the PPP and the UIP to hold at the same time. However, if prices are sticky this can no 169 longer be the case. In the short term either the UIP or the PPP will not hold. We will have a state that differs from the long term stable condition—we will be out of equilibrium. In the model we will present, due to Rudi Dornbusch, we assume that while the UIP will hold at every point of times, although the PPP will not. Assume that there is an unexpected shock to the money supply. Money supply increases. According to the equilibrium model prices should immediately increase and the exchange rate should depreciate, leaving the real exchange rate unaffected. The interest rate would not change. What happens if prices take time to adjust? The long term expectations will be the same as in the equilibrium model. When the price adjustment has taken place, the two models have the same implications. The price level will be higher, and the exchange rate will be higher. However, in the short term only the exchange rate will adjust. Prices do not change. Hence, domestic interest rates must fall. This is necessary to induce people to hold the higher money supply—remember that lower interest rates make people increase their holdings of currency. If prices had risen immediately people would have been be willing to hold more money just because prices were higher, and the interest rate would have been unaffected. If the exchange rate immediately settles at its long term value, while interest rates for a period fall bellow the foreign interest rate, the UIP can not hold. But we have assumed the UIP to hold at every point of time. So what must happen? If the UIP shall hold when domestic interest rates are bellow foreign interest rates, we need to expect the exchange rate to appreciate—as Et et+1 must be smaller than et . This leads to overshooting—when the money shock occurs the exchange rate must change by more than its long term expectations. This is the only 170 way the UIP can hold—because only if the exchange rate depreciates “too much” now, it can be expected to appreciate back to its long term value. 6.6.1 The Dornbusch model Let us assume a real money demand function of the type we used in Lecture 2. We assume the real money demand, m − p is a function of the expected interest rate, i, and real output, y. If interest rates increase, you want to reduce your holdings of currency, so the sign of i is negative. If real output increases you want to increase your holdings of currency, so the sign of y is positive. Further, we assume perfect foresight. We an then write real money demand as m − p = −ηi + φy. (6.5) · Assume that UIP holds, and that et+1 − et = e so that · e = i − i∗ . (6.6) Further, we assume that there are both traded and non-traded goods in the economy. The price of non-traded goods is pd . The price of traded goods is equal to the foreign price level, p∗ . We can define the price level as a weighted average of traded and non-traded goods, p = σpd + (1 − σ)(e + p∗ ). (6.7) You see that when σ = 0 the price level evolves according to the PPP. However, if σ > 0 prices will not adjust automatically to the PPP level. If we substitute for (6.6-6.7) into (6.5) we obtain · m − (σpd + (1 − σ)(e + p∗ )) = −η(i∗ − e) + φy. 171 (6.8) Figure 6.7: The equilibrium model vs. the disequilibrium model e t time p t time i i=i* t time The whole lines give the solution to an unexpected positive monetary shock in the monetary equilibrium model. This is as discussed in lecture 1 and 2. The dashed lines give the movements of e, p and i as is expected in the Dornbusch model. 172 When we reorder we obtain · e= φ σ 1−σ 1−σ ∗ 1 pd + e+ p − i∗ + y − m. η η η η η (6.9) We concentrate about p and e. All other variables are exogenous in this model. For simplicity we define a variable z that includes all exogenous variables: z = (1 − σ)p∗ − ηi∗ + φy − m. (6.10) · We can then write e as · e= σ 1−σ 1 pd + e + z. η η η (6.11) This gives us a first order difference equation for the change in the exchange rate measured in e and p. To complete the model we need a description of the movement in the price level. We can define the real exchange rate, q, as3 q = p − p∗ − e. (6.12) We define the exchange rate that will assure that q = 0 as ê, i.e. ê = p − p∗ . (6.13) If e > ê the exchange rate is undervalued, if e < ê the exchange rate is overvalued. We postulate that the the price level will move up when the exchange rate is undervalued and that the price level will move down when the exchange 3 De Grauwe includes real shocks into the PPP equation. Such shocks do however not affect the results we intend to discuss, so we just ignore them. They make no difference here. 173 · rate is overvalued. The change in prices, p, can be written as · p = δ(e − ê), (6.14) where δ > 0. If we substitute (6.13) into (6.14) we obtain · p = δ(e − p + p∗ ). (6.15) Equation (6.5) describe the domestic price level as a weighted average of traded and non-traded goods. If we substitute (6.5) into (6.15) and rearrange we obtain · p = σδ(e − pd + p∗ ). (6.16) If σ is zero, there will be no over- or undervalued exchange rate, as the PPP will hold at all times. · · We have two first order difference equations, one for e and one for p. We · · now set e = p = 0. From equation (6.11) we obtain pd = − 1−σ 1 e + z. σ σ (6.17) From equation (6.16) we obtain pd = e + p∗ . (6.18) An equilibrium is a situation where variables are stable. Equation (6.17) defines under what conditions the financial markets are in equilibrium. Equation (6.18) defines under what conditions the goods markets are in equilibrium. The financial equilibrium is illustrated in figure 6.8. In the financial market equilibrium we adjust the exchange rate. Assume the price level of non-traded goods is “too high”—i.e. we are at a point above the line defined 174 Figure 6.8: Financial market equilibrium p de=0 e in equation (6.17). For the real exchange rate to adjust towards PPP the nominal exchange rate must depreciate—i.e. the direction of the arrow in the diagram. If prices are “too low”, the nominal exchange rate must appreciate. The goods market equilibrium is illustrated in figure 6.9. In this equilibrium we adjust the price level. If the exchange rate is “too high”—at a point to the right in the figure—the price level must rise for the real exchange rate to adjust. If the exchange rate is “too low”—i.e. we are in the left of the figure—the price level must fall for the real exchange rate to adjust. Together the financial market and the goods market define the economy. If we bring the two equilibrium conditions into one diagram we can identify 175 Figure 6.9: Goods market equilibrium p dp=0 e 176 Figure 6.10: Market equilibrium p dp=0 de=0 e e the equilibrium of the economy. However, outside this equilibrium we have possible unstable situations. How the market is expected to move in the different areas is described by the arrows in figure 6.10. The model has a “saddle point” where the two lines cross. There is only one stable line that leads from disequilibrium to the saddle point, and this path is defined by the “saddle path” in the figure. Every other path than the “saddle path” will lead to increasing deviations from fundamentals. However, as foresight is assumed to be perfect, it is reasonable to believe that the economy will be at the saddle path. Now we can analyse shocks. A money shock is a shock to the financial 177 Figure 6.11: A positive money shock p dp=0 de’=0 de=0 e · market. An increase in the money supply will shift the line for e out. At the same time interest rates must fall to bring prices down. In a phase diagram we will not expect an immediate shift to the new saddle point. Prices will be sticky in our model. So the price level will take time to adjust. In the short term only the exchange rate can move. It will do so by shifting to the right, to the new saddle path. However, this rate will be higher than the rate in the saddle point. Over time the exchange rate must appreciate as it moves towards the saddle point. In parallel interest rates will rise and prices will rise. A new equilibrium will be established with a higher price level and an interest rate equal to the foreign interest rate. 178 The weakness of the Dornbusch approach What is the the problem of the Dornbusch model? The model gained attention because the overshooting result gave a possible explanation for the high volatility in the exchange rate. If the exchange rate tended to overshoot, we should expect exchange rate volatility to be substantially higher than the volatility in underlying fundamentals. Further, the model gives an explanation of why we should expect to see a high correlation between the nominal and the real exchange rate. After all, prices do not move here, while the nominal exchange rate overshoots. This should imply that even the real exchange rate will overshoot for a period of time. However, the model only gives this result in the case of monetary shocks. If there is a shock to de· mand, through e.g. public spending, this will shift the p = 0 equation. Such a shift does not lead to overshooting in this model. Is it reasonable to assume that frequent monetary shocks are the main cause of the high volatility in the exchange rate? Empirically, monetary shock are very hard to distinguish, so this is not an easy question to answer. However, as we pointed out above, the high volatility in the FX market is a feature it shares with almost every other asset market. It is fairly certain that monetary shocks does not explain why other asset markets are so volatile. Probably the Dornbusch model is to specific to give any good understanding of the high volatility in exchange rates. It is however still important as a benchmark for much of the current literature in exchange rate economics. 6.7 Chartists and noise traders The monetary equilibrium model assumes that all traders are using the same strategy. They have estimated a model for the exchange rate that they are 179 continuously updating, based on expected fundamental underlinings for the exchange rate. If the exchange rate is “overvalued” compared with their expectations they sell, it the exchange rate is “undervalued” they buy. However, different traders might be using different strategies. E.g. most surveys of traders active in the FX market reveal that at least 30 per cent tend to use chartist methods to forecast the exchange rate. A chartist will use historic values of the asset price to predict future movements in the asset price. They are assumed to use rules that are extrapolative, like “buy when the 1-week moving average crosses above the 12-week moving average.” Milton Friedman argued in 1953 that non-fundamental speculators would over time lose money. However, it has been shown by a number of studies that one can make money using a chartist strategy. Therefore it might be perfectly rational to be a chartist, although this implies a trading strategy that does not care about “fundamentals”. If the exchange rate only reverts to fundamentals in the long term, much money can be made following the short term trends. Feedback trading can also be rationalised if one assumes that the availability of information is limited. If we assume some traders to have more information than others, the less informed will have to observe the trading process, as the actual trading is a source of how other agents are behaving. If many traders are operating as chartists, this might increase the probability for the exchange rate to move in long swings. If the value of a currency is appreciating, chartist strategies would probably indicate to buy the currency, thereby fuelling the trend. One the other hand, if this trend is moving away from fundamentals, should not “fundamental traders” force the rate back? At some point they will. However, their total force might not be big 180 enough to do so before the exchange rate has deviated quite substantially from the underlying rate. Some potential problems: • There is actual uncertainty about the future. Unless the discrepancy between the rate and fundamentals become “too large”, there can always occur some unexpected “news” that would justify the current rate. The fear of such events might hinder a rational investor from short-selling to bring the exchange rate back. • Even if the rate is currently overvalued, there is no guarantee for when the trend will turn. Hence, if you sell today, while the rate continues to move away from fundamentals, you will miss out on an even bigger profit opportunity tomorrow. • Even if you base your predictions on fundamentals, you are never certain that your model is a 100 per cent correct. The noise trader paradigm is a continuation of the chartist-fundamentalist approach. A noise trader is defined as someone who responds to random price movements. Experiments tend to show that investors are overconfident about their own predictive abilities. Other studies have shown that many traders believe a large change in the exchange rate to be the most important “news” over the course of a day—rather odd, given that “news” should be something generated outside the market. Such findings might indicate that actual behaviour does not fit the monetary equilibrium model’s definition of “rational”. Describing noise traders is however difficult. Recent theoretical studies tend to model noise trading by assuming that noise traders behave like chartists. 181 6.8 Microstructure theories In Lecture 5 we discussed the institutional framework of the FX market. We saw, among other things, that the FX market tended be distinguished by high volume and low transparency compared with other markets. The microstructure theory is a sidetrack of exchange rate economics that investigate how institutional factors influence the pricing process in the market. There have been two lines in the literature. The traditional approach has been to see whether the trading process, e.g. the use of different trading system, will have a price impact. These studies are generally restricted to looking at very short term price fluctuations, mainly basing their findings on tick-by-thick data, or the continuous flow of orders in the market.4 A more recent strain of the literature focuses on the the lack of transparency. The argument is that different investors will have different information. This information will be reflected to the market through their trading. One measure of trading is “order flow”. Order flow is defined as net initiated purchases of foreign currency. If a customer calls a dealer and asks for 10 EUR in the SEK/EUR market, this implies an order flow of 10. If the customer asks for 10 SEK, this implies an order flow of -10. Order flow reflects “excess demand” in the market. What is “excess demand”? Should not always demand equal supply? Well, the demand curve might shift. Excess demand reflects the direction of shifts in the demand curve. How does this differ from the equilibrium models? In the monetary equilibrium model demand is determined by the current value of a number of fundamental variables. The models assume that everyone has the same information, and that everyone uses the same model to interpret this information. 4 A ‘thick’ is a single trade. 182 However, “fundamental variables” are mostly reported only with a lag. E.g. the inflation rate is reported only once a month, and with at least one month lag. Real output is reported at a quarterly basis, with several months lag. The numbers are often revised several times after that. At every given point of time there exists no consensus of what real output is in exactly this point. Further, it is no reason to believe that every investor uses the same model to evaluate the information available. It is however reasonable to assume that investors’ beliefs about current fundamentals will be reflected in their trading. So if investors demands more of a currency, this might imply that there are reasons for the exchange rate to appreciate. The main proponent of this approach, Richard Lyons, argues that actual dealers hardly care about “news” when they are setting prices. He claims that dealers mainly observe the amount of incoming trade, and adjust prices as a result of this. If so, order flow will be the determinant of much of the price fluctuations we can observe in the data. Figure 6.12 depicts accumulated customer order flow in the Swedish market and the SEK/DEM exchange rate. As the order flow has a negative number, we see that customers are net buying SEK. On the opposing side must be either Sveriges Riksbank, or the reporting banks—the Riksbank or the dealers must be accumulating DEM if customers shall be able to accumulate SEK. As we see there is a fairly strong correlation between the customer order flow and the exchange rate. Table 6.3 reports regression results when we include order flow in regressions on the exchange rate. As we see, including order flows in the regressions improve the R2 quite considerably compared with regression only including “fundamental variables”, like interest rates and the stock exchange. 183 184 Note1: Estimated with OLS Note2: * - 5 per cent, ** - 1 per cent Note3: We include 5 lagged values of return in this regression. Only the fourth lag is significant. Table 6.3: Estimating daily returns—01.01.1998 to 06.30.1998 returns (1) t-stat (2) t-stat (3) Constant 0.000 0.576 0.000 0.984 0.001 Total customer OF 7.72E-07 3.987 ** Swedish customer OF 6.61E-07 Foreign customer OF 6.11E-07 Dealer-dealer flow -1.94E-07 Change in for. reserves -3.63E-06 Interest dif., d(rdif ) 0.002 0.173 -0.002 -0.151 -0.006 Stock index return, d(lOM XC) -0.054 -2.472 * -0.051 -2.437 * -0.055 Lagged return (4) Adjusted R2 0.03 0.14 0.18 DW 2.09 2.02 2.05 S.E. of regression 0.003 0.003 0.003 2.979 2.951 -0.637 -3.026 -0.507 -2.695 t-stat 2.776 2.880 3.442 -0.594 -3.194 -0.035 -2.689 2.445 t-stat 0.001 2.798 6.24E-07 7.06E-07 -1.76E-07 ** -3.78E-06 0.000 ** -0.053 0.195 0.30 2.15 0.001 ** ** ** (4) ** * ** ** ** ** Chart1 Figure 6.12: Accumulated customer order flow in the SEK/DEM market and the SEK/DEM exchange rate, January 1, 1998, to June 30, 1998 0 2.19 1 log(SEK/DEM) 2.18 -5000 2.17 -10000 2.16 2.15 -15000 2.14 -20000 2.13 2.12 Customer order flow -25000 2.11 -30000 6.9 2.1 Page 1 The uncovered interest rate parity (UIP) In Lecture 5 we discussed the covered return to investing one krone in the foreign money market. We argued that this return should equal the return of investing one krone in the Norway. From this we derived the CIP, or Ft 1 + it = . t 1 + i∗t (6.19) ft − et = it − i∗t . (6.20) In log form this can be written The uncovered return to investing one krone in the foreign money market will be (1 + i∗t )Et t+1 , t 185 (6.21) or in logs i∗t + Et et+1 − et . (6.22) As described in Lecture 2 the UIP is the idea that if expectations are rational, then the the expected uncovered return of this investment should equal the return of investing one krone in Norway. Arbitrage should assure that the uncovered excess return should be zero on average. We should expect Et (i∗t + Et et+1 − et − it ) = 0. (6.23) There are three interpretations of this equation. 1. The expected depreciation rate equals the interest rate differential. Let us define expected depreciation as Et dt+1 = Et et+1 − et . If we insert this into (6.23) we obtain Et dt+1 = it − i∗t . (6.24) 2. Forward interest rates are unbiased predictors of future spot rates. If we insert (6.20) into (6.23) we obtain ft − et = Et et+1 − et , (6.25) ft = Et et+1 . (6.26) or 3. The international Fisher relationship. From previous courses you should be familiar with the term “real interest rate”, ir . The real interest rate is defined by the Fisher equation that states that the real interest rate is the differential between the nominal interest rate and expected in- 186 flation, irt = it − Et π t+1 ⇒ it = Et π t+1 + irt (6.27) Similar, we must have i∗t = Et π ∗t+1 + ir∗ t (6.28) If we substitute equations (6.27) and (6.28) into (6.24) we obtain Et dt+1 = (Et π t+1 + irt ) − (Et π ∗t+1 + ir∗ t ). (6.29) The PPP states that et = pt − p∗t . (6.30) Et et+1 = Et pt+1 − Et p∗t+1 . (6.31) We should also have that So the PPP implies that Et et+1 − et = Et pt+1 − Et p∗t+1 − (pt − p∗t ). (6.32) This can be rewritten as Et dt+1 = Et π t+1 − Et π ∗t+1 . (6.33) So if the PPP holds we must have that r r∗ Et π t+1 − Et π ∗t+1 = (Et π t+1 + irt ) − (Et π ∗t+1 + ir∗ t ) ⇒ it = it . (6.34) The real interest must be equal between countries. 187 6.9.1 Testing the UIP The ‘expectations hypothesis’ or the ‘efficient market hypothesis’ is built on the idea that if there are free capital flows and rational expectations we should expect ft = Et et+1 (6.35) to hold if markets are efficient. It is reasonable to try to test whether this hypothesis holds in empirical data. To do so we define a forecast error, u, as et+1 = Et et+1 + ut+1 ⇒ Et et+1 = et+1 − ut+1 . (6.36) The forecast error is the difference between the realised exchange rate in period t + 1 and the expected exchange rate. If we substitute (6.36) and the CIP into the the UIP equation we obtain et+1 − ut+1 − et = ft − et . (6.37) From (6.37) we can obtain the following testable equation dt+1 = a + b(ft − et ) + vt+1 , (6.38) where a is a constant and v is an error term. This is equivalent to testing the equation dt+1 = a + b(it − i∗t ) + vt+1 . (6.39) According to the UIP hypothesis we should expect a to be zero and b to be 1. Figure 6.13 reports the finding of this regression for five different markets. As we see b is not close to one in any of the five reported regressions. In fact b is significant and negative. This implies that the interest rate differential is negatively correlated with depreciation of the currency. An investor who 188 holds funds in a high yield currency not only benefits form higher yields, but also tends to benefit from an appreciation in the long run. You simply get a double dividend. But how can such excess returns exist? We should notice that although the UIP does not seem like a good idea, it is not certain that one can make money on doing the opposite of the UIP. Even if the t-ratios of the b-parameters are significant, the R2 of the equations are very low, indicating a poor fit of our model. It is reason to doubt whether one can make money on trading against the UIP in the long run. However, one certainly can make money trading against the UIP in the short run. Figure 6.14 depicts the interest differential between Norwegian and German three month interbank rates and the NOK/EUR exchange rate. In this case Norway has over 3 per cent higher interest rates than Germany. According to the UIP we should expect NOK to depreciate substantially vis-à-vis the EUR. However, during the last months NOK has appreciated. Lending in EUR, investing in NOK has given a double dividend—both a substantial interest differential and an appreciation of NOK. Such cases are difficult to explain using the UIP. We are certainly missing out one something here. Notice that when we set the expected future exchange rate equal to the forward rate we leave out any discussion of risk. However, most investors are risk averse. We should probably take this into regard in our calculations. Fama decomposed the forward premium, ft − et into two parts: ft − et = (ft − Et et+1 ) + (Et et+1 − et ). | {z } | {z } rt (6.40) dt where r = the risk premium and d as before is expected depreciation. One implication of the above regression results is that r certainly must be different from zero. However, here, as in many other parts of the asset pricing litera189 Forward and Eurocurrency Markets 4. UIP Regression results Figure 6.13: Regressions on the UIP Currency a b Standard Error R2 British Pound -0.0067 -2.306 (0.0028) (0.862) 0.0322 0.0344 Canadian Dollar -0.0027 -1.464 (0.0009) (0.581) 0.0120 0.0247 French Franc -0.0026 -0.806 (0.0032) (0.928) 0.0326 0.0015 German Mark 0.0032 -3.542 (0.0043) (1.348) 0.0333 0.0287 Japanese Yen 0.0084 -1.813 (0.0032) (0.719) 0.0334 0.0201 Source: Backus, Foresi and Telmer (2001) “Affine Models of Currency Pricing” http://bertha.gsia.cmu.edu 18 190 Figure 6.14: The interest differential between Norwegian and German three month interbank rates and the NOK/EUR exchange rate 4 3 2 1 0 10/26 11/30 1/04 2/08 3/15 NOK3-DEM3 2.09 2.08 2.07 2.06 2.05 2.04 2.03 10/26 11/30 1/04 2/08 LNOKEUR 191 3/15 ture, it is difficult to interpret the risk premium implicated by our findings. If the risk premium was constant this should have been reflected in the finding that a 6= 0, however that is not clear from the regressions in figure 6.13. If the UIP shall match the data, the risk premium must fluctuate extensively. This does not seem credible.5 Several explanations of the rejection of the UIP build on the presumption that expectations are not perfectly rational. The peso problem is the idea that investors expect a large correction of the exchange rate at some time, they are however not certain when the correction will take place. If this correction did not take place in the sample used to test the UIP, the UIP will not hold. In the regression (i−i∗ ) is known today while the actual value of e will first be known in the future. The idea that expectations are an unbiased predictor of future exchange rates will just hold if the environment is stable. If the environment is unstable, one must expect investors to continuously update their expectations. This ongoing learning process will create problems if we try to test for the UIP. Researchers have substituted actual data with expected depreciation rates, as is reported in surveys from the financial markets. It shows up that if one uses survey data instead of actual data, b tends to be close to one, and a is significantly different from zero. This implies that on survey data the UIP holds if one takes into regard a constant risk premium. People might indeed act according to the UIP, however their expectations are not the best unbiased prediction of the future. 5 In the stock market one has attempted to use risk premiums as an explanation for the high returns in equity compared with risk free assets. However, to make the model match the data one must assume an incredible degree of risk aversion. The data simply does not square at reasonable parameter assumptions. 192 Chapter 7 Portfolio choice, risk premia and capital mobility 7.1 Introduction The first six lectures have focused on how we should understand the exchange rate from a macroeconomic point of view. If investors are rational and forward looking, we should expect the exchange rate to be determined by the expectations of future values of certain economic variables, so-called fundamentals. We have discussed how the government would want to influence the trade-off between an independent monetary policy and a stable exchange rate, and investigated the limitations the government faces when it tries to stabilise the exchange rate. Further we have looked at some institutional factors of the exchange rate market. In the last lecture we discussed how the equilibrium approach could be adjusted to better understand the actual experience with floating exchange rates. In this lecture we will turn to the investor. In the equilibrium model all investors will be similar—everyone uses the same model, and has the same expectations of the future. In Lecture 6 we made some attempts to modify these assumptions. We looked at the possibility that agents might form their 193 expectations independently. In this lecture we will focus on the fact that investors have different national affiliation. National affiliation must not be understood as “citizenship”. Affiliation is decided by the the denomination of costs and income. If your operating costs are paid in NOK, and your sales are paid in NOK, how should you then adjust your currency holdings to maximise your financial income? 7.1.1 Some notes on methodology In economics one has tended to focus on utility maximisation when analysing decisions under uncertainty. An economist is expected to work with as general specifications of the utility function as possible. The set up is as follows: You control a number of variables, so-called choice variables. In addition there is a number of factors you can not control, so-called state variables. Let the choice variable be how much you will sow on a field. The state variable will be the amount of rain that falls in the following months. The payoff in the next period will depend on both factors. The more you sow, the higher expected output. But output will be different for each different state—it will depend on how much rain that falls. When you decide how much to sow you must first make up your mind about the likelihood of different states, e.g. the possibility of much rain, little rain or no rain. Then you must calculate expected profits under each state. Having done this, you can make a decision about how much to sow.1 This set up is of course also applicable to financial decisions. The statepreference framework concludes that the fundamental object of choice in financial decisions are payoffs offered at different states of nature. However, 1 Just to point out how complicated this can get: assume that how much you can sow next year depends on how much you do sow this year. In this case you must not only calculate the possible outcomes for all states this year, you must also calculate the outcomes for all possible states next year, and the year after that, and ... . 194 it is extremely difficult to list all payoffs offered at different states of nature. As a result, the state-preference theory is almost without empirical content— it is impossible to test it, as we can not characterise the objects of choice. In finance this problem is solved by assuming that investors indifference curves are defined in terms of the means and variance of asset return. It is clear that this is only a very special case of the utility maximisation approach.2 However, in financial economics the possibility of empirical testing is seen as more important than the generalisation of the theory. In this lecture we will use the mean-variance analysis to derive demand functions for foreign currency. The main idea behind the portfolio approach to exchange rates is that assets in the home country and in the foreign country are not perfect substitutes. This is an important difference from the monetary approach analysed in the previous lectures. In the monetary approach all assets are perfect substitutes, and the uncovered interest parity is supposed to hold by assuming arbitrage. However, if similar assets at home and abroad are not perfect substitutes the UIP will not hold—this leads to the introduction of the concept of risk premium. 7.2 Demand for foreign currency In the mean-variance analysis, the investor is assumed to maximise a utility function, U , of the form 1 U = E(π) − Rvar(π), 2 (7.1) where π is real rate of return on the portfolio, E is an expectation operator, and R is the coefficient of relative risk aversion. We assume R > 0. The higher R, the higher the risk aversion. High risk aversion implies that the 2 See appendix. 195 investor is willing to sacrifice more in the form of lower return if she can reduce her risk. Risk is measured as the variance of return. In the currency market risk is a factor because of uncertainty about depreciation and inflation. The investor is assumed to hold two types of assets: domestic currency, B, and foreign currency, F . Total real wealth, W , denominated in local currency will be W = B F + , P P (7.2) where is the exchange rate. The share of total wealth the investor chooses to hold in foreign currency is F . PW f= (7.3) The model treats f as the the choice variable. Given f , one can compute F = f P W and B = (1 − f )P W . Expected real return on the portfolio will be given by · · · · · π = (1 − f )(i − p) + f (i∗ + e − p) = (1 − f )i + f (i∗ + e) − p, · · (7.4) where i is the interest rate, p=rate of inflation, e=rate of depreciation and ∗ denotes foreign values. · We assume that p is a stochastic variable with the distribution · p ∼ N (µp , σ pp ). (7.5) µp is the expected mean of a change in inflation, and σ pp is the expected standard deviation around the mean. Similar, we assume that · e ∼ N (µe , σ ee ). · · (7.6) The correlation between p and ee is σ ep . There is no uncertainty about the 196 interest rate, as it is observable today. Given this, and using the rules for expectations and variances of linear combinations of stochastic variables, we obtain E(π) = (1 − f )i + f (i∗ + µe ) − µp , (7.7) var(π) = f 2 σ ee + σ pp − 2f σ ep . (7.8) and3 If we substitute into equation (7.1) we obtain 1 U = (1 − f )i + f (i∗ + µe ) − µp − R f 2 σ ee + σ pp − 2f σ ep . 2 (7.9) If we maximise with regard to f we obtain δU 1 = −i + (i∗ + µe ) − R [2f σ ee − 2σ ep ] = 0. δf 2 (7.10) Solving (11.84) for f leaves us with f= σ ep 1 + (i∗ + µe − i). σ ee Rσ ee (7.11) We see that local investors demand for foreign currency increase as the foreign interest rate increases, and decrease as the domestic interest rates increases. Note that in the monetary model we assume the UIP to hold, which implies that i∗ + µe − i = 0, as µe is just expected depreciation, Et (et−1 − et ). In this model we assume that there is a risk premium on domestic currency, r, that is given by r = i − i∗ − µ e . (7.12) r is the extra return needed to hold domestic currency. Note that r can be 3 Remember that if z = αx + βz, and x and y is normally distributed, var(z) = α σ xx + β 2 σ yy + 2 · αβσ xy . 2 197 negative—it might be that the risk is on the foreign currency. Using the definition of r we can restate (11.48) as f= σ ep r − . σ ee Rσ ee (7.13) We see that the holdings of foreign currency can be divided in two terms. The first term, σ ep , σ ee is called the minimum-variance portfolio, fM . This is the share of foreign currency that minimises the variance of the return. The second term, − Rσree , is the speculative portfolio, fS . 7.2.1 The minimum-variance portfolio In this model we have no risk free asset, as the real rates of return in both assets, i.e. domestic and foreign currency, are uncertain. It will only be optimal to hold no foreign assets in the case when the correlation between inflation and depreciation is zero. If the correlation is negative, one should short-sell foreign currency. However, it is most reasonable to assume that σ ep is positive. It would therefore be optimal to hold some foreign currency in the minimum-variance portfolio. One example can be to assume that PPP holds. Then we have that · · · e = p − p∗ . If domestic and foreign inflation is uncorrelated (σ pp∗ = 0), the PPP implies that σ ee = σ pp + σ p∗ p∗ , and σ ep = σ pp . We can then write the share of foreign currency in the minimum-variance portfolio as fM = σ pp , σ pp + σ p∗ p∗ (7.14) and the share of domestic currency in the minimum-variance portfolio as 1 − fM = σ p∗ p∗ . σ pp + σ p∗ p∗ (7.15) Note that if the variance of inflation in the home country goes to infinity, 198 e.g. because of hyperinflation, it would be optimal to hold only foreign currency. If there is no inflation risk in one of the two countries, an investment in that country would be equal to a risk-free investment. The investor would minimise risk by only holding that currency. In general the investor should divide her portfolio in inverse proportion to the variance in inflation in the two countries. An implication is that we should expect currency substitution in high inflation countries. If inflation is spiraling out of control, domestic residents should shift their holdings to foreign currency. This is actually what we observe. In most high inflation currencies people tend to prefer to hold USD. Domestic currency is only held in small amounts for transaction purposes. In some hyperinflation countries people have actually substituted the local currency with foreign currency as a means of payment. If we instead assume that there is no correlation between prices and the exchange rate we have σ ep = 0. In this case holding foreign currency would only add risk, and the minimum-variance portfolio will only contain domestic currency. In general deviations from PPP will create a preference for the domestic currency in the minimum-variance portfolio. 7.2.2 The speculative portfolio The speculative portfolio, − Rσree , depends on three parameters: the risk premium, the risk aversion and the variance of the exchange rate. First, observe that the sign is negative. This is due to the fact that we define the risk premium as the risk premium of investing in domestic currency. Remember that the risk premium is defined as i − i∗ − µe . If this risk premium is positive one would optimise the speculative portfolio by increasing the exposure in domestic currency. This can be done by borrowing 199 in foreign currency and investing at home. We see that the exposure to foreign currency will decrease as the risk premium rises. Second, the effect on the speculative portfolio of a change in R or σ ee will depend on the sign of r. If risk aversion increases, the speculative portfolio will be reduced in size. If risk premium is negative, one will reduce the exposure to foreign currency. However, if risk premium is positive one will increase the exposure to foreign currency, as one reduces the speculative exposure to domestic currency. The same argument holds for increased volatility in the exchange rate. Capital mobility is the ability of capital to move freely across borders. A high degree of capital mobility means that differences in expected return have a strong effect on the supply of foreign currency. That should imply that the share of foreign holdings in the investor’s portfolio should increase if the risk premium decreases. The smaller the value of R and σ ee , the more does a change in r affect the optimal currency portfolio. There will be perfect capital mobility, fS → ∞, if risk aversion is zero, or it there is no exchange rate risk (σ ee = 0). In this case all capital will flow to the country with highest return. This should lead to the elimination of all risk premia, implying a speculative portfolio of zero. 7.2.3 Empirical calculations Let us take a look at Norwegian data for the period from January 1993 September 2001. Over this period we find • σ ep = −1.85 ∗ 10− 5, and • σ ee = 0.003850. 200 Note that these are results on monthly data. For the exchange rate we use NOK/EUR (DEM before 1.1.99). This tells us that fM should be very small in the Norwegian market—there is no reason to hold foreign currency to hedge against inflation risk. It is a general finding that the minimum-variance holdings of foreign currency should be small for industrialised countries with stable inflation rates. However, for countries with high inflation, this changes radically. Over a high inflation period in Argentina it was found that the optimal holdings of USD in the minimum-variance portfolio of an Argentinean investor was 86 per cent. As a comparison, the optimal holdings of USD for a German investor was found to be 9 per cent. Calculating the speculative portfolio is more difficult, not least because we do not know the actual coefficient of the risk aversion. However, it is usual to assume this to be around 2. Note that if the risk aversion is very high, capital mobility becomes very low. A simple estimate of the risk premium is to take realised interest rates and return in the exchange market over the period we investigate. This is obviously not the correct measure of the risk premium, as this depend on expected values. However it should be reasonably close if we assume rational expectations. I the case of Norway vs. Germany we find that over the period from 1993 to 2001 we have • i − i∗ = 0.0156 · • e = −0.00034 The interest differential is the annualised value of the three month rates. We · use the mean of e as a measure of the expected depreciation.4 This leaves · 4 One should however be aware that the distribution of e is severely skewed (it is not normally distributed), so the mean might not be appropriate here. The median is as a 201 us with a risk premium, measured as an annual return, of r = 0.0156 ∗ −(−0.00034) ∗ 12 = .0198. Investing in NOK has over the last 9 years been a purely win-win situation—you have got a higher interest rate than abroad, and in addition the positive return from an appreciating currency. The optimal speculative holdings of foreign currency by a Norwegian investor is found to be fS = −0.0198 = −0.214. 2 ∗ 0.00385 ∗ 12 (7.16) Norwegian investors should have negative holdings of EUR. Norwegians should borrow in foreign currency, and invest in Norway. In other words, they should go short in foreign currency. In fact this is what we see—Norwegian banks borrow extensively abroad to finance loans in NOK. And to a growing extent, Norwegian households do the same. Note that foreigners should choose to hold Norwegian currency. 7.2.4 Heterogenous agents Capital mobility depends not just on the risk aversion, but also on how much wealth, W , is actually invested. Assume e.g. that wealth is held by two groups, households and professional investors. One would usually expect that a household has a much higher coefficient of risk aversion than a professional investor. Assume only professional investors are active in the market, and that these have a low R. Then even a small change in r or σ ee can lead to large movements in the portfolio holdings of a currency. This can explain the movements of currencies under speculative attacks. If a country has held a high interest rate to attract foreign investors, we can expect these investors comparison 0.00046—however both values are close to zero. 202 to hold mainly short term, liquid funds. If expected σ ee change, e.g. due to a change in international circumstances, large funds might be extracted over night. One should also note that a the proportion of investors that take active positions in the currency market might vary over time. If there is a cost of obtaining information about the risk of investing in foreign currency, small investors might prefer domestic currency. However, this will only be true up to a certain point. If expected return in foreign currency increases beyond the cost of investing, a large share of investors will shift from being “passive” to being “active”. Such shift can be induced by dramatic movements in interest rates, exchange rates or reserves. This might be one explanation for contagion of currency crises, as we discussed in Lecture 4. One should be aware that high R or high costs of information might not be the only reason for not taking speculative positions in foreign currencies. Many banks and insurance companies must fulfill regulations that often stipulate a limit for currency risk. That will regulate their ability to speculate in the currency markets. An other factor might be credit constraints. If f is outside the interval [0, 1] the investor must borrow money to obtain the optimal portfolio. 7.2.5 Aggregate behaviour Before we proceed we must understand the balance sheet of the economy. Assume that we can divide the economy in three sectors, • domestic government (superscript g), • domestic private, and • foreign (superscript *). Note that ‘foreign’ here will include both for203 eign private investors and the foreign government. We retain the assumption of only two assets; domestic currency, B, and foreign currency, F . We are only looking at financial assets. Net financial holdings of an asset summed over all sectors in the economy must be zero—investments made by one group must be reflected as loans taken up by another group. In other words: one agent’s assets are the liabilities of another agent. A currency is the liability of the government. Net outstanding liabilities on the government must equal total holdings of domestic currency by domestic private and foreign investors. We must have that B g + B + B ∗ = 0. (7.17) This must also hold for foreign currency. We must have that F g + F + F ∗ = 0. (7.18) Real financial wealth in for the private domestic sector, measured in domestic currency, will be W = B + F . P (7.19) Likewise, the real financial wealth of the foreign sector, measured in foreign currency, will be ∗ W = B∗ + F∗ , P∗ (7.20) where P ∗ is the foreign price level. If we use equation (11.53) and substitute that into (10.29) we obtain the demand for foreign currency by domestic private investors, PW σ ep r PW F =f = − . σ ee Rσ ee 204 (7.21) Likewise we know that foreigner’s holdings of domestic currency, b∗ , which from the point of view of the foreigner will be holdings of foreign currency, will be b∗ = − r σ ep∗ + . σ ee Rσ ee (7.22) Note that we change signs, as the currency is defined as the price of foreign currency in domestic currency. From the point of view of the foreigner a depreciation of the domestic currency becomes an appreciation of the currency of his home currency, and vice versa. The demand for foreign currency by foreign residents will then be σ ep∗ r F = (1 − b )P W = 1 + − P ∗W ∗. σ ee Rσ ee ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ (7.23) Supply of currency to the central bank If we insert equations (7.19-11.52) into (7.18), we obtain σ ep r − F =− σ ee Rσ ee g B +F ∗ σ ep∗ r B ∗ − 1+ − + F . (7.24) σ ee Rσ ee This can be restated as σ ep F =− σ ee g ∗ B σ ep∗ B r B + B∗ ∗ ∗ +F − 1+ +F + +F +F . σ ee Rσ ee (7.25) This gives us the supply of foreign currency to the domestic central bank. If we e.g. think about the NOK/EUR market, this will be the supply of EUR to Norges Bank. How Norges Bank reacts to a change in supply of foreign currency depends on the exchange rate regime. In a floating rate regime F g is given exogenously, and the right hand side of (7.25)) will determine the exchange rate, as the exchange rate adjusts to clear the market. If the exchange rate 205 is fixed, F g must be adjusted to clear the market. This will be done through interventions from the central bank. If we draw a diagram with on the y-axis, and foreign reserves on the x-axis, we tend to assume that supply of foreign currency to the central bank will increase if the domestic currency fall in value,as we have done in figure 7.1.5 In other words, we expect δF g δ > 0. This will hold if ∗ δF g σ ep B σ ep∗ B r B + B∗ = + 1+ − > 0. δ σ ee 2 σ ee 2 Rσ ee 2 (7.26) This can be rewritten as δF g =f δ ∗ B B ∗ + (1 − b ) > 0. 2 2 (7.27) The condition will always be satisfied if both domestic and foreign investors hold a positive amount of both currencies. We can bring our understanding a little further. Let us make the convenient assumption that σ ep = σ ep∗ = 0. That is similar to a statement that the PPP does not hold. We know that this implies that the minimum-variance portfolio should contain no foreign currency. This is not unreasonable as a short term description of a floating exchange rate. Given this, we have that b∗ = −f . We also know that B = −B ∗ − B g . If we substitute this into (11.59) we can solve for the condition of δF g δ > 0 by solving f (−B ∗ − B g ) + (1 + f )B ∗ > 0. (7.28) B∗ > f. Bg (7.29) We obtain 5 This is equivalent to assuming that demand for domestic currency rise as domestic currency get cheaper, an assumption we used when drawing supply and demand for foreign exchange in previous lectures. 206 We also know that B ∗ = −f P ∗ W ∗ , from which we obtain P ∗W ∗ < −1. Bg (7.30) B g is domestic currency issued by the central bank. As money is a liability on the government, it must be assumed to be a negative number. (7.30) will be equivalent to P ∗W ∗ > 1. −B g (7.31) P ∗ W ∗ is foreign wealth denominated in domestic currency. B g is domestic currency issued by the domestic central bank. This will be a proxy for the size of the domestic economy. The implication is as follows: as long as foreign wealth is larger than the domestic economy, δF g δ > 0. In other words, if the foreign economy exceeds the local economy, a reasonable assumption for most countries, the foreign reserves will increase with a higher (weaker) exchange rate. However, note that the slope of the line will depend on the ratio of foreign wealth to the domestic economy. The smaller the domestic economy, the steeper the slope. The intuition might be as follows: if the foreign currency reserves of the domestic central bank increases, the holdings of domestic currency among private domestic and foreign residents must increase. That follows from the asset sheet of the central bank. Foreigners will hold more domestic currency if this asset becomes cheaper—if it depreciates. Locals will retain more of their earnings in domestic currency if it becomes more valuable—if it appreciates. If both groups are equally large, the price of the currency need not adjust for the market to absorb the increased supply of domestic currency. However, if foreigners are the largest group, the price must depreciate. If locals are the largest group, the price must appreciate, and the line will have downward slope. 207 Figure 7.1: Supply of foreign currency to the central bank and the exchange rate e Monetary policy, fixed rate Supply of foreign currency to the central bank Monetary policy, floating rate Fg 208 What can we bring of this? A reasonable question is how the holdings of F ∗ is affected by a shift in f . If we retain the assumption of σ ep = σ ep∗ = 0, we can rewrite equation (11.57) as F g = −f PW − (1 + f )P ∗ W ∗ . (7.32) Maximising with regard to f we then obtain that δF g PW =− − P ∗ W ∗ < 0. δf (7.33) An increase in f will shift F g inwards in the diagram in figure 7.1. A fall in f will shift F g out in the diagram in figure 7.1. If the central bank holds the foreign currency reserves fixed, the central bank supply function is a vertical line. Note that this gives an interesting application if we compare a small country with a large country. In a small country the line is expected to be steep. In a large country is almost horisontal. An implication will be that a similar shift in f will cause quite different effects depending on whether we are in a large country or a small country. In a small country the exchange must adjust much more to balance the market than what is the case in a large country. In previous lectures we have discussed the fact that small countries and developing countries have tended to be sceptical to a freely floating exchange rate. This might give an additional explanation of this fact. In a country with a small economy small shifts in investor sentiment might cause much larger impact on the exchange rate than what is the case in rich and large countries. A current account surplus A current account surplus is the same as a shift in wealth from foreigners to domestic private residents. A transfer of wealth shall not affect the spec209 Figure 7.2: Implications for how much the exchange rate much change to clear the market if f change—small vs. large country Small/poor country e Fall in ”f” Effect, large/rich country Effect, small/poor country Large/rich country Fg ulative portfolio, only the minimum-variance portfolio. A positive current account will increase the central banks holding of foreign currency if the share of foreign currency is higher in the minimum variance portfolio of foreigners than of domestic residents, i.e. that there is home bias in currency preferences. Mathematically speaking this can be expressed as 1+ σ ep∗ σ ep > . σ ee σ ee (7.34) This seems like a fairly reasonable assumption, not least given the empirical numbers reported above. A country with a positive current account, like Norway, will accumulate foreign reserves. However, countries with substantial negative current accounts shall, according to this rule, lose foreign reserves. In our figure a current account surplus should lead to and outward shift in F g . In a floating exchange rate regime a current account surplus should lead to an appreciation of the domestic currency. However, as in the above 210 examples, the effect will depend on the relative size of the economy. A current account surplus or deficit will presumably have less effect on the exchange rate in a large countries like the US or Japan, than in small countries, like Norway or Sweden. One should note the following special case. If the PPP holds, we have that σ ep∗ = −σ p∗ p∗ , σ ep = σ pp and σ ee = σ p∗ p∗ + σ pp . This would imply that 1+ σ ep σ ep∗ = , σ ee σ ee (7.35) as σ p∗ p∗ + σ pp σ p∗ p∗ σ pp − = . σ p∗ p∗ + σ pp σ p∗ p∗ + σ pp σ p∗ p∗ + σ pp (7.36) When the PPP holds, the minimum-variance portfolio share should depend only on the difference in inflation volatility between the two countries. Deviations from the PPP create a preference for the domestic currency. Current account movements make no difference. To understand the full effect on the government’s position one needs to include government debt. If a country has a current account deficit there will a drain of foreign reserves from the central bank. If it in addition has a fiscal deficit it needs to finance this by issuing new debt. However, there is no demand for domestic currency. So debt cannot be financed through domestic currency bonds. The government has two choices: • either it reduces foreign reserves, or • it must borrow in foreign currency. The first possibility is a short term solution. The second option might be extremely expensive. A developing country with both substantial debts and a current account deficit is not seen a especially creditworthy. If foreigners 211 doubt the long term prospects of the country, the demand for debt might dry up. Many developing countries are not able to finance their debt in long term contracts. Much of the debt is short term. This implies that developing countries are in the market for new loans not just to pay for a current deficit, but also to refinance previous debts. If the borrowing possibilities in world markets dry up, the country has to choose between depletion of the foreign reserves or asking for a moratorium, i.e. a default on the foreign debt. This is the story we see in countries like Russia in 1998, Brazil in 1999 and Argentina in 2002. Equilibrium risk premium Let us restate equation (7.25) as g F = −fM PW − (1 − b∗M ) (P ∗ W ∗ ) r + Rσ ee PW ∗ ∗ + P W . (7.37) If we solve for the risk premium, r, we obtain r = Rσ ee fM P W + (1 − b∗M )P ∗ W ∗ −F g − P W + P ∗ W ∗ P W + P ∗ W ∗ (7.38) Note that as F g = −F − F ∗ , the last term can be written as −F g (F + F ∗ = . P W + P ∗ W ∗ P W + P ∗ W ∗ (7.39) This is the share of foreign currency of total wealth held by private domestic and foreign residents. Let us define this as f . As one can just hold two assets, the share of total wealth held in domestic currency, b, must be f = 1 − b. 212 (7.40) The term fM P W + (1 − b∗M )P ∗ W ∗ P W + P ∗ W ∗ (7.41) gives the share of the minimum-variance portfolio of foreign currency of total wealth. This tells us how much foreign currency investors will hold just to minimise risk. Let us define this share as fM . Using the same argument as above, we must have that fM = 1 − bM . (7.42) This implies that we can simplify equation (7.38) to r = Rσ ee b − bM . (7.43) We see that the risk premium is a product of three factors: R, σ ee and fM − f . Risk premium will be high if risk aversion or exchange rate volatil ity are high. This is a result of low capital mobility. b − bM tells us to which extent investors are taking more exchange rate risk in the domestic currency than the minimum that would optimise their portfolio. If “excessive risk” goes up, the risk premium increases. b > bM implies that the market is “oversupplied” with domestic currency, so the risk premium must be positive to make supply meet demand. This is an equilibrium condition. We have previously defined r as · r = i − i∗ − e. (7.44) Interest rates and the expected depreciation must adjust to assure that equation (7.43) holds. 213 7.3 The collapse of a currency board In previous lectures we have discussed the role of currency boards. A currency board is an institution that guarantees to exchange the domestic currency in a foreign currency at a given parity. The board is supposed to control an mount of foreign currency that at least equals the amount of domestic currency in circulation. On paper a currency board should be a fully credible institution if the rules are followed. The risk of depreciation should be zero. If the UIP holds there should be no risk premium on the country with the currency board. However, when we discussed the case of Argentina in Lecture 3 we found that (i − i∗ ) > 0 for the whole period since the currency board was imposed in 1991. 7.3.1 Risk premium and the need for capital In Argentina the trust of the government has been low for a long time. Even with a currency board, it was reasonable to keep much of private holdings in foreign currency. Foreigners would probably only place their money in Argentina if it was for speculative purposes. So bM was probably low. However, Argentina is a developing country with need for capital investments. There was need for b > bM to fulfill these needs. If this conditions was to be satisfied, the equilibrium risk premium had to be positive. Both Argentineans and foreigners would take advantage of this risk premium. As a result Argentines held a negative speculative portfolio of foreign currency— they borrowed money abroad and invested them in ARP assets. 7.3.2 Risk premium and expected depreciation We need to give a short comment on the risk premium at this point. Expected depreciation is not an easy term to handle. Even if domestic interest rates 214 are higher than foreign interest rates, the risk premium might be zero or negative if expected depreciation exceeds the interest rate spread. This makes it important to distinguish between risk premium at different time horizons. In most fixed exchange rate regimes it is only a small probability that a devaluation will take place tomorrow. The probability of a devaluation over the time frame of one week, or even one month is still relatively small. However, the longer the time span, the higher the probability of an adjustment within that time span.6 In the case of Argentina, it was clear that the commitment to the currency board was strong. The chance of a devaluation over night was considered small. So if iARP > iU SD we should expect the short term risk premium in Argentinean pesos to be positive. However, few believed the currency board would exist for ever. So for long term investments the risk premium was probably much smaller. Note one implication for short term vs. long term capital flows: if we believe the above argument, the risk premium tend to be higher in the short run than in the long run in a fixed exchange rate regime. This encourages the stream of short term capital over long term capital. A floating exchange rate might increase the risk of adjustments in the exchange rate in the short term. This will discourage short term flows. One often assume that a country wants to attract long term capital. Long term capital tends to be invested in firms with a long term horizon. This might have give more utility for the home country than short term capital flows. It is not clear whether expected depreciation over the long term will be higher in a fixed or a floating exchange rate regime. If fundamentals are important in the long run, it probably should make no difference. However, 6 This is the same argument as is applied in the “Peso problem” discussed in Lecture 6. 215 fixed exchange rate regimes often break down during periods of speculative attacks. Speculative attacks tend to increase macroeconomic uncertainty for some period of time. It might actually be that a fixed exchange rate regime will discourage long term flows. 7.3.3 Effects of a fall in risk premiums So what made the situation in Argentina unstable? Notice that if doubts are created about the currency board, two things happen simultaneously: · 1. Expected r will fall as expected depreciation, e rises. 2. σ ee rises as uncertainty rises. It was clear that the competitiveness of Argentina had been eroded over a long time. This was due to two factors: • the USD was appreciating compared to other currencies. As a result the ARP was appreciating compared to other currencies. In addition, a Brazilian devaluation in 1999 had further worsened the competitiveness of Argentine exporters. • The fiscal deficit of Argentina created uncertainty about the long term viability of the regime. One option was to change the parity of the board. But the Argentine government repeatedly stated that the currency board would not be fiddled with. However, in the middle of 2001 the Minister of Fiance, Domingo Cavallo, openly suggested that leaving the currency board was an option. Over night, the argument for taking speculative positions in the ARP vanished. One held ARP because the risk premium was high. The risk premium was high because one believed the currency board to be credible. 216 In the new situation everyone wanted to re-balance their portfolios with less risk in ARP and more risk in USD. Everyone went to the bank to exchange currency holdings of ARP into USD. At the same time they wanted to close their ARP deposits. Remember that people had loans denominated in USD and deposits denominated in ARP. According to the rules of a currency board, the board should be able to redeem every currency note in circulation at parity. However, in this case the currency in circulation was increasing fast, as everyone were withdrawing deposits in exchange for currency. So possible demands on the currency board far exceeded the amount of USD actually held by the board. Further, the banking system was on the verge of collapse. The banks had most of their assets in the form of long term USD loans. They did not have sufficient reserves in ARP to cover all ARP deposits. The banks were not able to redeem their holdings of ARP since they did not have the money in their vaults. In this case the speculative attack on the currency was at the same time a speculative attack on the banking system. The government had two choices: 1. They could devalue over night. However, as most Argentineans had loans in USD, and the cost of these loans would increase dramatically if the currency collapsed, this option would certainly lead to immediate social unrest. Indeed the government probably hoped they could retain the currency board. 2. They could restrict the currency in circulation. The way of doing so was to restrict the amount one could withdraw from the banks. The hope was that this could give the government time to restore credibility. If the amount of currency in circulation was restricted, it was possible to 217 redeem the currency that was in circulation into USD, thereby showing that the system worked. At the same time one avoided a collapse of the banking system. The problem was that this system was both unfair and very problematic. (a) It was unfair because they who had redeemed their money before the restrictions now seemed to get a better deal—they could exchange their money at parity. Those who had trusted the system got screwed. (b) As we all know, most of us depend on the possibility to take money out of our accounts every week if we shall be able to pay our bills. Over night this possibility was restricted. Many middleclass Argentineans found themselves in grave liquidity problems. On top of this the Argentinean government needed to borrow money. Argentina had both a fiscal and a current account deficit. Foreigners were of course doubtful about the long term prospects of Argentinean debt, not least because the country was asking for a moratorium on existing debt. The Argentinean government had to borrow at home. But nobody wanted to hold domestic currency. The only way to solve the problem was to force people to hold government debt. State wages were paid in government bonds. State debts were paid in government bonds. This further undermined the credibility of the system. On the one side the government tried to reduce the amount of ARP in circulation to strengthen the credibility of the currency board. On the other side they issued something looking very much like new money in everything but the name. Argentina became a country with many currencies. State bonds were used as means of payment, although they were accepted to much under their face value. 218 Argentina was de facto experiencing inflation out of control. The system could not work over time. People went on the streets demanding their money. The currency board was abolished, and the ARP depreciated with about 50 per cent against the USD. To sweeten the pill people were allowed to exchange their USD loans in Argentinean banks into ARP loans at the old parity, at an unidentified cost to the government. Argentina declared that they were unable to repay foreign debts. The country went into a state of total disarray from which it has yet, as of May 2002, to emerge. 7.4 Empirical applications of the portfolio choice model There are two main problems if we want to test the above theory. 1. We have made very simplistic assumptions of monetary policy. The most reasonable would be to assume a central bank reaction function that was neither horisontal nor vertical, but downward sloping. The actual slope is probably difficult to identify. 2. In practice we can observe the flow of private, government and domestic holdings of foreign currency. However, we can not observe the stocks involved. In the science of accounting it is by no means certain that flows and stocks are compatible. However, one can perhaps argue that observing flows might be sufficient if the focus of the analysis is on the change in the exchange rate—not the level of the exchange rate. One of the results above was that one should expect portfolio shifts to have more impact in small than in large countries. One implication might 219 be that small floating currencies are more volatile than large floating currencies. That is not an obvious result from empirical data. Testing equality of variance in daily returns on EUR/USD, SEK/USD and NOK/USD from 01/01-1999 to 04/01-2002 we find that there is no difference in the variance when we compare EUR/USD and SEK/USD. However, the variance in NOK/USD is significantly lower than for the two other exchange rates. It is very difficult to evaluate whether this is a result of our theory being wrong, or if the Norwegian and Swedish governments make a stronger effort to sterilise the effects of changes in currency flows on the currency than the Federal Reserve does. This might be the case even though both Norway and Sweden claim to have a freely floating exchange rate. Norway provides an interesting example. Although there has been no “intervention” since the beginning of 1999, Norges Bank is continuously active in the market, accumulating foreign exchange that is invested in the government controlled “Petroleum Fund”. It is hard to identify the actual effects on the exchange rate from these activities. Likewise, we observe that Svenska Riksbanken is de facto accumulating reserves in periods of current account surplus. Is this just a random event, or the results of a conscious strategy? 7.5 Appendix 7.5.1 Mean-variance vs. state-preference The mean-variance approach will match the state-preference utility maximisation if: 1. Preferences are time separable—the utility of consumption in the next period does not depend on the current level of consumption. 2. The relative risk aversion is constant over time. 220 Figure 7.3: ARP/USD exchange rate 1998-2002 4 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 01.05.02 01.03.02 01.01.02 01.11.01 01.09.01 01.07.01 01.05.01 01.03.01 01.01.01 01.11.00 01.09.00 01.07.00 01.05.00 01.03.00 01.01.00 01.11.99 01.09.99 01.07.99 01.05.99 01.03.99 01.01.99 01.11.98 01.09.98 01.07.98 01.05.98 01.03.98 01.01.98 0 3. Both the price level, P , and the exchange rate, , follow Wiener processes, or Brownian motions. This implies that that level of return in · · the two variables, p and e, are normally distributed and independent over time. 4. Expectations, variances and covariances are constant over time. 7.5.2 The exchange rate The most simplistic way to write equation (7.25) will be g F = −f PW − (1 − b∗ ) (P ∗ W ∗ ) . (7.45) If we solve this for the exchange rate we obtain = −f P W . F g + (1 − b∗ )P ∗ W ∗ 221 (7.46) In previous lectures we have stated that in a floating exchange rate regime the central bank will hold no foreign reserves. We simplify by setting F g = 0. We then obtain = −f W P . (1 − b∗ ) W ∗ P ∗ (7.47) Remember that the PPP states that the exchange rate is given as = P . P∗ (7.48) In this framework one ratio will differentiate the exchange rate from the PPP rate: the ratio of nominal wealth held in the foreign currency unit. If this fraction is shifting over time, we should expect to see the nominal exchange rate changing, and we should also expect a correlation between the real and the nominal exchange rate. 222 Chapter 8 The real exchange rate and capital flows 8.1 Some notes on research strategy Modern macroeconomics is built on analysing the maximising behavior of agents in a general equilibrium multi period setting. Although this research has been going on for some time—the book of Obstfeld and Rogoff from 1996 is probably the best summary of this kind of analysis in an open economy framework—many questions remain unsolved. However, interesting questions can now be analysed in such a framework. Not least, this framework allows to discuss questions in a more dynamic setting than what is possible in the traditional models, like the Swan diagram or the Mundell-Fleming model. 8.2 Some empirical observations We remember that the real exchange rate, Q is defined as Q= P∗ . P 223 (8.1) Figure 8.1: The real exchange rate. DEM/USD 2 1.8 1.6 1.4 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 jul.98 jul.97 jul.96 jul.95 jul.94 jul.93 jul.92 jul.91 jul.90 jul.89 jul.88 jul.87 jul.86 jul.85 jul.84 jul.83 jul.82 jul.81 jul.80 jul.79 jul.78 jul.77 jul.76 jul.75 jul.74 jul.73 0 Real exchange rate calculated using CPI. A central assumption in the monetary equilibrium model was the purchasing power parity—the belief that arbitrage would assure that the real exchange rate is constant over time. However, if we use the consumer price index as a proxy for the price level, and calculate the real exchange rate, we find that for most countries this is certainly not constant. Two examples are given in figures 8.1 and 8.2. Using the CPI for such measurement is not unproblematic. The weights of goods in the CPI will differ between countries, and they will change over time. Relative prices will change with changes in tariffs or taxes. However, the findings illustrated in figures 8.1 and 8.2 are fairly representative for the results reported in numerous empirical studies of the PPP. For countries at about the same level of productivity, the PPP seems to hold over time, although the real exchange rate tends to move in long swings, with a mean reversion of about 3-6 years. The length of this cycle has been described 224 Figure 8.2: The real exchange rate. JPY/USD 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 jul.01 jul.00 jul.99 jul.98 jul.97 jul.96 jul.95 jul.94 jul.93 jul.92 jul.91 jul.90 jul.89 jul.88 jul.87 jul.86 jul.85 jul.84 jul.83 jul.82 jul.81 jul.80 jul.79 jul.78 jul.77 jul.76 jul.75 jul.74 jul.73 0 Real exchange rate calculated using CPI. as a “puzzle”, given that the most reasonable explanation for swings in the real exchange rate, sticky prices, should imply a mean reversion of about 1 year—in other words much faster than what is observed. For countries with more marked differences in technical development the PPP does not seem to hold. A general result is that countries with high economic growth tend to experience real appreciation over time. This is clearly illustrated in the case of Japan in figure 8.2. 8.2.1 Differences in the price level Implicit in the assumption of purchasing power parity is the assumption that over time the ratio of price levels will be one if measured in the same exchange rate, i.e. = P . P∗ The implication is that the price level should be the same across countries. Price levels are very difficult to measure. The standard measure of prices 225 published by statistical bureaus is the consumer price index, the CPI. However, the CPI does not measure the price level, only relative change in the cost of a basket of consumption goods. The best measure of actual price levels is provided in the Penn World Tables, where prominent economists have done empirical estimates of the relative price of comparable goods baskets for a number of countries. These tables are only available with a lag of many years—the most recent numbers are from the mid-1990’s. However, what is clear from these data is that the price level is not the same across countries. In general one finds that the price level is much higher in countries with high income per capita. An interesting test of this result can be found if we compare the numbers in the renown “Big Mac index” published by The Economist in the end of April every year. The Economist collects the price of a Big Mac sold by MacDonalds in a number of countries. It calculates the price in USD at the current exchange rate. If absolute PPP holds, the price of one Big Mac should be the same as in the US. Of course, there are a number of problems using a Big Mac as an indicator of the price level. This is one very specific good, not very representative of “normal” consumption. One the other hand it is a very standardised good. We are in fact pretty certain that we compare identical items across boarders. The item contains both tradable parts, like beef and bread, and non-tradable parts, like labour input. Table 8.1 gives the price of a Big Mac measured in USD for seven different countries. We can summarise some stylised facts from the table: • The price is clearly much higher in the five industrialised countries than in China and Russia. • The prices are fluctuating over time. 226 • With the exception of Russia the price has moved towards the US price from 1995 to 2002. This might be an indication that price levels over time tend to converge. Table 8.1 also illustrates how difficult it is to compare welfare when we compare gross domestic product per capita using the nominal exchange rate. If a Norwegian earn 30,000 USD a year, he can purchase 7,300 Big Macs... However, in China, a wage of only USD 9300 will suffice to get the same amount of food. To get a true picture of the purchasing power in Norway and China income per capita must be adjusted for differences in price levels. These are so-called PPP-adjusted per capita output numbers. Table 8.1 gives a very simplified shoot at such estimates. Of course, one should be cautious when interpreting such numbers.1 However, the table clearly illustrates that output per capita measured in actual exchange rates is not a good measure of the welfare of nations. Norway might be one of the richest countries in the world. That does not necessarily imply that Norwegians are the people best of—in fact purchasing power of Norwegians is (at best) in line with the purchasing power of other Western European countries. 8.3 Accounting for what we do not know about the real exchange rate The data does not match with the assumptions used in previous lectures. To understand what we do not understand, it can be useful to make a short 1 E.g. the GNI numbers and the Big Mac prices are not transferred into USD at the same exchange rate. The GNI numbers use the World Bank method of the average rate over three years (in this case 1999, 2000 and 2001), and adjust for inflation differences to the the average of the inflation level in the G5 countries (USA, Japan, Germany, France and Great Britain). The Big Mac price is calculated in USD at the spot exchange rate as of April 2002. This probably leads to an overestimation of the “welfare” in Japan, and an underestimation of the “welfare” in Europe compared to the US. 227 228 Sources: The Economist and The World Bank. The first two columns give the the price of a Big Mac in seven different countries. Measured in USD at current market exchange rate. Ratio is the country price price relative to the US. GNI per capita is numbers for 2000, measured at the “Atlas method”, a three year average exchange rate. The PPP adjusted GNI per capita is the GNI adjusted with the relative cost of BigMac in 2002. Table 8.1: Price levels and welfare. Relative price level measured as price of a Big Mac in 1995 and 2002 1995 2002 Ratio GNI per capita Ratio to US PPP adj. GNI per capita Ratio to US Norway n.a. 4.09 0.61 33650 0.98 20486 0.60 Switzerland 5.20 3.81 0.65 38120 1.11 24913 0.73 USA 2.32 2.49 1.00 34260 1.00 34260 1.00 Germany 3.48 2.37 1.05 25050 0.73 26318 0.77 Japan 4.65 2.01 1.24 34210 1.00 42380 1.24 China 1.05 1.27 1.96 840 0.02 1647 0.05 Russia 1.62 1.25 1.99 1660 0.05 3307 0.10 summary. First, let us restate the covered interest rate parity, a parity we know will hold with certainty. The CIP can be written as et = i∗t,T − it,T + ft,T . (8.2) when we it,T is the interest rate over the period from t to T . Further, we can define the premium for bearing exchange rate risk—taking the chance on buying the exchange rate spot at time T instead of securing the price today by buying the exchange rate forward to ft,T —as the risk premium, r, which can be defined as rt,T = ft,T − Et (eT ). (8.3) If we substitute (8.2) into (8.3) we obtain et = i∗t,T − it,T + rt,T + Et (eT ). (8.4) Let us define the real interest rate, ir , as irt,T = it,T − (Et (pT ) − pt ). (8.5) If we substitute (8.5) into (8.4) we obtain ∗ ∗ r et = (ir∗ t,T + Et (pT ) − pt ) − (it,T + Et (pT ) − pt ) + rt,T + Et (eT ). (8.6) The real exchange rate, q, is defined as qt = et + (p∗t − pt ). (8.7) Reordering, and using (8.7) we obtain r qt = ir∗ t,T − it,T + rt,T + Et (qT ). 229 (8.8) The real exchange rate is given as the real interest differential, the expected risk premium and the expected future real interest rate. In theory this should be valid for any choice of T , but generally q is assumed to move towards some equilibrium value over time, so the equation is probably most interesting when analyzed over some time horizon. But what does this actually tell us? Variability in the real exchange rate can be transmitted through three channels: • variability in the real interest differential, • variability in the risk premium, and • variability in the expected real exchange rate. Empirical evidence suggests that the real interest rate does not explain much of the variability in the real exchange rate. This leaves us with the risk premium and the expected real exchange rate. The effects of variability in the risk premium was discussed in lecture 8. In general risk premiums will be of most interest if we assume that there are some kind of imperfect substitution between holding domestic versus holding foreign assets. As we saw, such differences might explain substantial swings in capital flows. In this lecture we will focus on the variability in the expected real exchange rate. Analysis of the expected real exchange rate must be seen together with the concept of “external balance” in the economy. 8.3.1 External balance Defining external balance is not obvious. In more classic models, like the Swan-diagram that analysis the relationship between “internal” and external balance, external balance is a balanced current account, and and internal 230 balance is an unemployment rate equal to the long term non-inflation accelerating rate of inflation (NAIRU). However, external balance need not mean a balanced current account in a dynamic framework; at least not in the short or medium term. External balance will generally be achieved if the current account is consistent with “desired capital flows”. But what is “desired capital flows”? First note that if the economy is in “equilibrium”—population is stable and capital intensity is according to the “golden rule” and there is no unexpected changes, just to mention three requirements—then the current account probably should be zero. These are not realistic assumptions. Different measures will affect long term prospects: • If there is any sort of “consumption smoothing” in the economy, it will be optimal to try to spread the effects of shocks between periods. If there is a negative shock today, and we expect this to be temporary, we would borrow today to smooth the consumption pattern. However, on the national level borrowing is reflected as a current account deficit. • “Structural shocks”: if a country finds e.g. natural resources, the structure of the economy must be expected to change to take advantage of these opportunities. Very simplified such an economy can be expected to venture through three periods: 1. An investment period, where income from production is low, and costs are high. 2. A period of collecting rent from the resource. 3. A period of restructuring, as the fields are emptied. From beginning to end the current account should accumulate to zero. However, over the time from the source is found until it has been fully 231 extracted, we should expect the current account to be negative in the initial period, positive in the producing period, and negative again as saved income is used to build new industries. • Imbalances in demographic developments should probably be reflected in long periods with a current account different from zero, without this reflecting an imbalance in the economy. E.g. the USA has a demographic profile very different from other developed nations, a fact that can probably explain much of the US current account deficit. Most developed countries must save to finance the increase of pensioners relative to the working part of the population. The US will not experience this for many years, and can therefore for the time being focus on investments instead of saving. In fact, modern economics is still searching for models that can describe the external balance over time. It is clear that our current knowledge does not give a full description of how we should expect the current account to behave in a dynamic framework. This also affects our ability to understand the real exchange rate. 8.4 Explaining long term shifts in the real exchange rate Note: section 4 is not required reading in GTA1333/6607. You should however be familiar with the main conclusions, as summarised in De Grauwe, ch. 5.3. When we looked at figures 8.1 and 8.2 we saw that the behaviour of the real exchange rate seemed to differ quite markedly in the case of DEM/USD 232 and JPY/USD. In the first case the real exchange rate was fluctuating around 1. In the second case, we clearly see a consistent downward trend. The assumption of PPP builds on the law of one price, that states that the price of a good that is traded between countries should be equal between countries, give or take transportation costs between the two destinations. If the law of one price, arbitrage should increase demand where the good is expensive, and reduce supply where the good is cheap. However, empirical analysis only find support for the law of one price in the case of storable, highly traded goods, like corn, metals and oil. For most goods the law of one price does not hold. Possible causes might be • transportation costs, • trade barriers, and • non-competitive market structure. For some goods transportation costs are so high that they are hardly traded at all. These are non-tradable goods. One should not forget that all goods sold will have contents that are not tradable across boarders, like the cost of handling in the import country. The role of non-traded goods is important if we want to understand structural shifts in the real exchange rate. 8.4.1 The Balassa-Samuelson effect The Balassa-Samuelson effect is an attempt to explain why poor countries tend to experience real appreciation. The building block is that countries with higher productivity in tradables compared with non-tradables tend to have a higher price level. High growth is accomplished through high growth in tradables. As productivity in the traded sector rise, the wage level in 233 this sector rises. However, if there are inter-sector labour mobility, this will cause a rise in the wage level in the sector producing non-traded goods. To compensate increased wage levels at a constant productivity, the price of non-traded goods must rise. It follows that countries with high growth will experience a rise in the price level, and thereby a real appreciation. The price level in a two sector economy The driving force in the following results will be our assumptions about the movement of capital and labour. We assume that capital can move freely between countries. We look at a small country. This assures that the real interest rate, here denoted as i, will be the at home and abroad. The interest rate is given exogenously. Labour is not mobile between countries. However, it is assumed to be freely mobile between sectors in the economy. As a result the average wage level, w, will be the same in all sectors.2 This is only a realistic assumption if we look at the economy over time—this must be perceived as a description of long term price adjustments. The exogenous interest rate and the equalisation of the wage level between sectors give the domestic economy a certain flexibility to meet shocks to demand and supply. An increase in domestic demand should increase the price level of non-traded goods. However, at the same time, an increase in demand should lead to more capital and labour employed in the non-traded sector. It can be shown that our assumptions of capital and labour mobility is enough to assure shocks to domestic demand will not affect the relative price of non-traded goods in this economy. Note that we focus on the real effects to the real exchange rate. This implies that we disregard money. All prices will be measured relative to the 2 The way to think about this is that two persons with the same education and background will receive the same wage in both sectors. 234 price of a traded industrial good, Pi , a price we set equal to 1. This implies that in the following analysis we assume • no nominal rigidities, • no feedback from money, and • no risk premium. These assumptions are not credible in the short term. This implies that the models are best fitted to explain medium or long term movements in the real exchange rate. The economy has two sectors. The traded sector is producing two goods, industrial goods and a natural resource, e.g. oil. The price of industrial goods is set to 1. We assume that extraction of oil returns a rent of τ in excess to the price of industrial goods. The amount of oil produced make up a share γ of total production of industrial goods. We then have that the average income from one good sold in the traded sector must be (1 − γ) · 1 + γ(1 + τ ) = 1 + γτ . (8.9) The price of non traded goods is measured in quantities of industrial goods. The price is set to Pd . The production function of the traded sector is given as At F (Kt , Lt ), where At is the level of productivity in the traded sector, Kt is the level of capital stock, and Lt is the labour employed in this sector. The production function in the non-traded sector is Ad G(Kd , Ld ), where d denotes the non- traded sector. Both production functions have constant returns to scale. Total supply of labour, L, must be the labour employed in the traded and non-traded sector combined, L = Lt + Ld . There is no unemployment in this economy, and prices are fully flexible. 235 Over time excess profit must be zero in both sectors. This gives us two equilibrium conditions. For the traded sector we must have that ∞ X s=t 1 1 + is [(1 + γ s τ s )At,s F (Kt,s , Lt,s ) − ws Lt,s − is Kt,s ] = 0. (8.10) For the non-traded sector we must have that ∞ X s=t 1 1 + is [(Pd,s Ad,s G(Kd,s , Ld,s ) − ws Ld,s − is Kd,s ] = 0. (8.11) If there are no unexpected shocks, these conditions are expected to hold in every period. Under this assumption we can remove the time notation, and state that (1 + γτ )At F (Kt , Lt ) − wLt − iKt = 0, (8.12) Pd Ad G(Kd , Ld ) − wLd − iKd = 0. (8.13) and In macroeconomics we often state output as a fraction of employment. Let us define capital per employee in the traded sector as kt = Kt . Lt (8.14) As the production function has constant returns to scale, we have that F (Kt , Lt ) = Lt F Kt L t , Lt Lt = Lt f (kt ). (8.15) Likewise, we have that kd = Kd , Ld (8.16) and G(Kd , Ld ) = Ld G Kd L d , Ld Ld 236 = Ld g(kd ). (8.17) We can no restate equations (8.12) and (8.13) as (1 + γτ )At f (kt ) − w − ikt = 0, (8.18) Pd Ad g(kd ) − w − ikd = 0. (8.19) and These are equilibrium conditions. But what happens if there is a marginal change in one of the variables? If we take the total differential of equation (8.18) we obtain τ At f (kt )dγ + (1 + γτ )f (kt )dAt + (1 + γτ )At f 0 (kt )dkt − dw − idkt = 0, (8.20) As i and τ are given exogenously, so we hold them constant. Note that if you take the differential of equation (8.10) with regard to Kt you obtain that (1 + γτ )At FK (Kt , Lt ) = i, (8.21) δF (Kt , Lt ) . δKt (8.22) where FK (Kt , Lt ) = From this we know that (1 + γτ )At f 0 (kt ) = i, (8.23) as FK (Kt , Lt ) = Lt 1 0 f (kt ) = f 0 (kt ). Lt (8.24) We can then restate equations (8.20) as τ At f (kt )dγ + (1 + γτ )f (kt )dAt + idkt − dw − idkt = 0. (8.25) It is easier to interpret this equation if we look at percentage changes. If dx 237 is the change in x, then dx x is the percentage change in x. Further we want to look at percent of total output in the traded sector, (1 + γτ )At f (kt ). If we divide (8.25) by (1 + γτ )At f (kt ) and rearrange we obtain w γτ dγ dAt dw + − = 0. (1 + γτ ) γ At (1 + γτ )At f (kt ) w (8.26) Let us define labour’s share of total output in the traded sector as µLt = wLt . (1 + γτ )At F (Kt , Lt ) (8.27) As (1 + γτ )At Lt f (kt ) = (1 + γτ )At F (Kt , Lt ) we can restate equation (8.26) as dγ dAt wLt dw γτ + − = 0. (1 + γτ ) γ At (1 + γτ )At F (Kt , Lt ) w (8.28) Rearranging, we obtain µLt dw γτ dγ dAt = + . w (1 + γτ ) γ At (8.29) If we turn to the non-traded sector, we find that the total differential of equation (8.19) as Ad g(kd )dPd + Pd g(kd )dAd + Pd Ad g 0 (kd )dkd − dw − idkd = 0. (8.30) We know that Pd Ad g 0 (kd ) = i, (8.31) Ad g(kd )dPd + Pd g(kd )dAd − dw = 0. (8.32) so (8.30) can be simplified as As above, we can define labour’s share of output in the non-traded sector as µLd = wLd . Pd Ad F (Kd , Ld ) 238 (8.33) Dividing by total output in the non-traded sector, and rearranging, we obtain dw dAd dPd = µLd − . Pd w Ad (8.34) We have obtained an expression for the price level of non-traded goods. However, the wage level must be the same in both the traded and the nontraded sectors. This implies that there must be a relationship between the two sectors. From equation (8.29) we can obtain an equation for dw . w If we subsitute this into (8.35) we obtain dPd µLd γτ dγ dAt dAd = + − . Pd µLt (1 + γτ ) γ At Ad (8.35) The fraction of labour’s share of output in the non-traded over the traded sector, µLd , µLt can be assumed to be bigger than one. In general the non-traded sector is more labour intensive than the traded sector. If productivity in traded goods rise while productivity in non-traded goods remains constant, the price of non-traded goods will rise. We also see that a higher share of “high rent” products in the traded sector will rise the price of non-traded goods. The intuition is simple: more high rent products lead to a rise in the wage level in the traded sector. This puts pressure on the wage level in the non-traded sector, and forces up the price of nontraded goods. Norway, a country that has experienced a substantial change in the composition of traded goods over the last 30 years, is a good example. The increase in the share of high rent products in Norwegian exports have put pressure on wages in other sectors in the Norwegian economy, raising Norwegian prices. This is one explanation for the high Norwegian price level documented in table 8.1. 3 3 As noted above, the price level in non-traded goods does not depend on domestic demand for non-traded goods in this model. 239 In general one assumes that productivity growth is higher in the traded than in the non-traded sector. This is the so-called Baumol-Bowen Paradox. The reasoning is that the non-traded sector is dominated by services. These are labour intensive, with low capital input per worker. Many examples of services, like hair cutting, health care or cultural activities, depend on high input of manual labour. Quality of such services can be made better by machines, but only to a limited degree. It is a general assumption that rich countries are rich because of their high productivity in traded goods. An implication is that rich countries should be expected to have a higher price level than poor countries. Again, this is in line with the empirical facts stated above. The price index and the real exchange rate The real exchange rate is the ratio of national price levels. In this case the price level will be the cost of some representative basket of consumption good. The terms of trade is the ratio of relative prices of exports to the relative prices of imports. The terms of trade tells us something about the competitiveness of the national economy. Let us assume that the price index is made up of traded and non-traded goods. For simplicity, let us assume that the price of non traded goods is Pd , and the price of traded goods in local prices is Pt . The weight of non traded goods is σ, and the weight of traded goods is (1 − σ). If we assume that the price index, P , is made up as geometric average, P is given as P = Pdσ Pt1−σ . (8.36) For simplicity we assume the relative consumption of traded and non-traded good to be the same between countries. The foreign price index, P ∗ , is then 240 given as ∗(1−σ) P ∗ = Pd∗σ Pt . (8.37) We assume the exchange rate between the two countries to be fixed at 1:1. The ratio of home-to-foreign prices become Pdσ Pt1−σ P = . P∗ Pd∗σ Pt∗(1−σ) (8.38) However, it is reasonable to assume that the price of traded goods will be the same—eventual price differences will just be traded away. So we can simplify equation (8.38) to P = P∗ Pd Pd∗ σ . (8.39) This has an important implication for the real exchange rate. If we ignore shocks to the nominal exchange rate, changes in the real exchange rate will depend on the relative prices of non-traded goods. If we take the total derivative of equation (8.39) we obtain 1 −Pd σ dPd + ∗2 dPd∗ ∗ Pd Pd σ−1 = 0. (8.40) = 0. (8.41) If we rearrange, we obtain Pd dPd Pd dPd∗ σ − Pd∗ Pd Pd∗ Pd∗ σ−1 This can be rewritten as dPd dPd∗ − ∗ Pd Pd σ−1 = 0. We have already obtained an expression for 241 dPd . Pd (8.42) If we substitute in from equation (8.35) we obtain ∗ σ∗ −1 γτ dγ dAt dAd µLd γ∗τ dγ ∗ dA∗t dA∗d µLd + − − + ∗ − ∗ = 0. µLt (1 + γτ ) γ At Ad µ∗Lt (1 + γ ∗ τ ) γ ∗ At Ad (8.43) We make two simplifying assumptions. We focus on differences in productivity, and assume that γ = 0 for both countries. Further, we assume that µLt and µLn is the same in both countries. We can then rewrite (8.44) as σ∗ −1 dAd dA∗d µLd dAt dA∗t − ∗ − − ∗ = 0. µLt At At Ad Ad (8.44) Changes in the real exchange rate will depend on the relative changes in the traded and non-traded sectors. Countries with relatively higher growth in the traded sector will experience a real appreciation as the price level of non-traded goods in these countries increase relative to the price level of non-traded goods in the other countries. 8.5 Fluctuations in the real exchange rate and capital flows The following model is an example of an intertemporal approach to modelling the real exchange rate. This is a two country-two goods model, assuming that each country are producing separate goods, and that all goods are traded. Even in this “simple” framework we can achieve some interesting implications about how shocks to the economy should be expected to affect the real exchange rate, and how capital flows and trade patterns might influence the the movement in the real exchange rate. 242 8.5.1 Model of two countries and terms of trade shocks We are in a two-country world, where each country produce a single good. The home country produces good H, and the foreign country good F . Each good has the price of unity measured in the local currency. The relative price of the two goods, which is the same as the real exchange rate, Q, will be measured as the price of one unit of foreign good denominated in home currency, Q= PF . PH (8.45) This is in line with the definition of the exchange rate used in this course. A higher Q implies a real depreciation, a lower Q a real appreciation, when seen from the home country. Total consumption in the home country of good H is CH , and total con∗ sumption of good F is CF . Foreign consumption is CH and CF∗ . Consumption ∗ of good H, CH and CH , is denominated in home currency, and consumption of good F , CF and CF∗ , is denominated in foreign currency. Total production of the home country is Y = H, and total production of the foreign country is Y ∗ = F . The net capital inflow of the home country is B. B will equal the negative of the current account, B = −CA, (8.46) as we have that the capital account=the current account, and a current account surplus must give a capital outflow. B reflects capital mobility. If B is zero, there is no capital mobility. Note that there might still be trade. However, the trade balance must always be zero. The rate of absorption, A, is the total consumption and investment in 243 the home country. In standard terms we have that Y = C + I + G + CA, (8.47) where C is total consumption, I is investment, and G is government consumption. Absorption is then given by A = C + I + G. (8.48) For convenience we set I and G equal to zero. We then see that A = Y − CA = Y + B. (8.49) A∗ = Y ∗ + B ∗ . (8.50) Similarly, we have that Notice that B∗ = −B , Q (8.51) as B ∗ is measured in foreign currency, and capital inflow in one country by definition must equal capital outflow in the other, as we have only two countries. We make the convenient assumption of Cobb-Douglas utility functions. That implies that the utility function are given by U= 1−m (QCF )m , CH ∗ U = ∗ CH Q m∗ ∗ (CF∗ )1−m . (8.52) where m reflects the share of foreign goods in home consumption, and m∗ is the share of home goods in foreign consumption. Further, it is natural to assume that 1 − m > m∗ , 244 (8.53) which implies that foreigners have a weaker preference for good H than the residents of the home country themselves. We now have the two maximisation problems. For the home country we have 1−m (QCF )m s.t. A = Y + B = CH + QCF , M ax U = CH (8.54) and for the foreign country ∗ M ax U = ∗ CH Q 1−m∗ ∗ (CF∗ )m s.t. A∗ = Y ∗ − B C∗ = H + CF∗ . Q Q (8.55) To solve these equations, we use a standard Lagrange function: 1−m L = CH (QCF )m + λ (Y + B − CH − QCF ) . (8.56) The choice variables are CH and CF . We obtain δL −m = (1 − m)CH (QCF )m + λ = 0, δCH (8.57) δL 1−m = mQm (CF )m−1 CH + Qλ = 0, δCF (8.58) δL = Y + B − CH − QCF = 0. δλ (8.59) and Equation (11.81) can be reformulated as 1−m m(QCF )m−1 CH + λ = 0. (8.60) Setting (8.57) equal to (8.60) we obtain −m 1−m (1 − m)CH (QCF )m = −λ = m(QCF )m−1 CH , 245 (8.61) which implies that (1 − m) QCF = CH . m (8.62) If we insert (8.62) into (8.59) we obtain that (1 − m) QCF = Y + B − QCF m ⇒ CF = m Y +B . Q (8.63) This gives us a function for home country consumption of the foreign good, CF . Inserting (11.62) in (8.62) we obtain the function for consumption of the home produced good, CH = (1 − m)(Y + B). (8.64) The similar procedure can be applied to the the consumption problem of the foreign country. We will then find that ∗ CH = Qm∗ (Y ∗ − B ), Q CF = (1 − m∗ )(Y ∗ − B ). Q (8.65) We have now identified the optimal consumption structure for both countries. Market clearing demands that ∗ CH + CH = Y, CF + CF∗ = Y ∗ , (8.66) as total consumption by definition must equal total production. If we insert (8.64) and (11.66) into (11.70) we get (1 − m)(Y + B) + Qm∗ (Y ∗ − B ) = Y. Q (8.67) Here Y , Y ∗ , m and m∗ are assumed to be given exogenously. However, Q and B must adjust to clear markets. Our main focus is on the real exchange rate. Taking B as given, we can use (8.67) to calculate the market-clearing 246 level of the exchange rate as Q= (1 − m − m∗ )B mY − . m∗ Y ∗ m∗ Y ∗ (8.68) The real exchange rate has two parts: one is the result of the relative preference for the demand of good H as a share of output in the two countries, and the other is a result of capital flows between the two countries. If capital flows are zero, the real exchange rate will only be a product of relative demand for home and foreign goods in the two countries. It is interesting to look at how Q is affected by changes in Y , Y ∗ and B. We find that δQ m = ∗ ∗ > 0. δY mY (8.69) This implies that if there is a positive supply shock to the domestic economy, the exchange rate will depreciate. A positive supply shock implies that there is an increase of domestic goods offered in the market—a supply shock here is by definition an increase in production. The real exchange rate must weaken to induce increased demand for domestic goods in the foreign country. We also find that δQ mY − (1 − m − m∗ )B 1 Q = − = − ∗ < 0. ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ δY mY Y Y (8.70) A positive supply shock in the foreign country will lead to a real appreciation. This time the exchange rate must adjust to increase demand for foreign goods in the home country. A real appreciation will increase the purchasing power of domestic residents. Last, we have that δQ (1 − m − m∗ ) =− < 0. δB m∗ Y ∗ 247 (8.71) The result follows from equation (11.68), as we know that (1 − m − m∗ ) > 0. The real exchange rate appreciates if there is increased capital inflow to the home country. An example of such inflows might be increased lending due to a positive demand shock. Increased lending increases the total amount available for purchases in the home country. As more of this is used to purchase domestic goods than foreign goods, the price of domestic goods rise more than the price of foreign goods, leading to a real appreciation. However, there will normally be a relationship between a shock to Y or Y ∗ and B. Let us assume that there is a shock θ that affects all three variables. To analyse the effect of θ we can take the total differential of Q.4 Assume that Y = Y (θ), Y ∗ = Y ∗ (θ) and B = B(θ). The total differential of Q with regard to θ will then be given by δQ dY δQ dY ∗ δQ dB dQ = + + . dθ δY dθ δY dθ δY dθ (8.73) Inserting the results from equations (8.69-8.71) we obtain dQ m dY Q dY ∗ (1 − m − m∗ ) dB = ∗ ∗ − ∗ − . dθ m Y dθ Y dθ m∗ Y ∗ dθ We can simplify the notation be setting and dB dθ dQ dθ = ∆Q, dY dθ = ∆Y , (8.74) dY ∗ dθ = ∆Y ∗ = ∆B. Further, we assume that the initial trade balance is zero. This implies that m∗ Y ∗ = mY , Q (8.75) as m∗ Y ∗ is the fraction of foreign output denominated in foreign currency 4 What is the total differential? Assume that we have a function F = (X(θ), Y (θ)). The differential of X with regard to θ, X 0 (θ) = dX dθ . From the product rule we know that dF δF dX δF dY = + . dθ δX dθ δY dθ This gives the total differential of F with regard to θ. 248 (8.72) that foreigners use to purchase good H. If there is a trade balance this must equal the fraction of home output used to purchase good F , denominated in foreign currency, namely mY Q . Also note that if we assume a trade balance, we implicitly assume that B = 0 in the initial period. If we insert (11.69) into (8.74) we obtain ∆Q = Qm Q Q(1 − m − m∗ ) ∆Y − ∗ ∆Y ∗ − ∆B. mY Y mY It is easier to interpret changes in ∆Q Q than in ∆Q, as ∆Q Q (8.76) represent the percentage change in Q. If we divide (8.76) by Q, we get ∆Y ∆Y ∗ (1 − m − m∗ ) ∆B ∆Q = − − . Q Y Y∗ m Y (8.77) We here have expressed the percentage change in the real exchange rate as a function of the effect of a relative change in home output, the relative change in foreign output and the relative change in capital inflow as a percentage of home output. Analysing the effect of shocks Let us discuss some specific cases. • Assume a symmetric shock to the two countries, and that B is zero. We see that in this case the real exchange rate will be unaffected. • Assume that there is a negative shock to home output only, and that there is no capital mobility. Then the real exchange rate will appreciate equiproportionate to the change in home output: ∆Q ∆Y = . Q Y (8.78) • Assume that there is full capital mobility, but that the shock to home 249 output, Y , is perceived to be permanent. It would not be rational to borrow in the international markets to compensate for a permanent shock. Optimal behavior would suggest that the most effective way to behave if the shock is permanent is to adjust absorption immediately to the new long term sustainable level. This implies a change in the real exchange rate of ∆Q ∆Y = . Q Y (8.79) If there is capital mobility and shocks are perceived to be temporary, there will be a relationship between ∆B and ∆Y that depends on the rate of capital mobility and the cost of borrowing abroad. Let us assume that that people care about future generations just like they care about themselves. If there is a temporary negative shock to Y the effect on current absorption can be limited if one borrows in the international markets. The possibility to borrow will be given by x and the cost of borrowing will be set to the international real interest rate, r. Assume that we can repay the loan over an infinite number of periods, so we can disregard repayments. The cost of the loan in each period will be the interest paid on the loan, rB. We postulate that the economy in this case will choose to borrow according to the rule ∆B = −∆Y · x − r∆B, x ≥ 0. (8.80) This implies that if borrowing is possible (x > 0) how much one will borrow will depend on both the opportunity to borrow, x and the cost of borrowing, r. Inflow will be positive is the shock to output is negative, therefore we have a negative sign on ∆Y . The loan will be repayed by all future generations at 250 the cost of rB. From this we can derive the optimal ∆B, which is given by ∆B = −∆Y x . 1+r (8.81) If the shock is temporary and we assume consumption smoothing, it would not be optimal to let the present generation bear the whole cost of the shock. To alleviate the negative shock the country will borrow in the international markets and let ∆B = −∆Y x . 1+r If so we have ∆Y (1 − m − m∗ ) x ∆Y ∆Q = + . Q Y m 1+r Y where we know that (1−m−m∗ ) m (8.82) ∈ [0, 1i . The effect under a temporary shock will depend on four variables: x, r, m and m∗ . We can show that δ( ∆Q ) Q δx δ( ∆Q ) Q δr and = =− δ( ∆Q ) Q δm 1 (1 − m − m∗ ) ∆Y > 0, 1+r m Y (8.83) x (1 − m − m∗ ) ∆Y < 0, (1 + r)2 m Y (8.84) x (1 − m∗ ) ∆Y = > 0. 1+r m2 Y (8.85) The effect of a supply shock on the real exchange rate will be higher the higher the capital mobility and the more international trade. However, the effect will decrease with the cost of borrowing. Note one important implication: freer capital flows will enhance the effects of a real supply shock on the real exchange rate. What is the intuition behind such a result? If there is no capital flows, the real exchange rate must adjust to clear the markets. A negative supply shock will lead to a fall in supply of good H, and a relative in the price of H, thereby leading to a 251 real appreciation. If the shock is alleviated by capital inflow, such inflow will increase the relative demand for good H over good F , as we assume the consumers of the home country to have a higher share of H in their consumption than the share of F . This will put further pressure on the price of H, leading to an even stronger real appreciation. Assume output is back to its long term value in the next period. Even if the shock only lasts for one period, the country is now left with a net debt. This debt must be repaid. There is a capital inflow of ∆B = ∆Y x 1+r in the period of the shock, and a capital outflow of ∆B = −rB for all future periods. Absorption must fall to a new level in the period of the shock, and remain at this level for all future—or at least to the next shock. The capital outflow, giving a negative value of ∆B, must affect the real exchange rate as well. The real exchange rate will no depreciate to a level above its value before the shock, as absorption now will be below absorption before the shock. Capital flow will not only enhance the effect on the real exchange rate in the period of the shock, it will enhance the change in the following periods as well. The case of a negative supply shock is illustrated in figures 8.4 and 8.3. Figure 8.4 show the effect on Y and Q. Figure 8.4 is a more complex diagram. If there are no capital flows A = Y and the economy must be at the 45 degree line all the time. However, in every point we can adjust absorption through capital flows. This will lead to an adjustment of Q according to the rule ∆Q (1 − m − m∗ ) ∆B =− . Q m Y (8.86) This is the downward sloping line in the diagram. Note that with our “rule” absorption will settle at a new long term value in the period of the shock. 252 Figure 8.3: The effect on the real exchange rate of a temporary negative supply shock (a) Y time Q Free capital flow No capital flow time 253 Figure 8.4: The effect on the real exchange rate of a temporary negative supply shock (b) dQ/Q =(dY/Y)+-[1/(1+r)]*[(1-m-m*)/m]*(dY/Y) Full capital mobility (x=1). All future periods. Q Y1 Y0 , Y2 45 degree line. Defines B=0 In Y=45 degree line, Y=A Absorption=output, before shock dQ/Q =(dY/Y)+-[1/(1+r)]*[(1-m-m*)/m]*(dY/Y) Full capital mobility (x=1).Period of shock dQ/Q=dY/Y No capital mobility. r*B, current account surplus for all future Y Current account deficit in period of shock, optimal policy. A 1,1 : Absorption in period of shock if no capital mobility. A 0 : Absorption before shock A 1,2 : Absorption in all future periods if full capital mobility and ”optimal policy” Lines given by: dQ/Q -[(1-m-m*)/m]*(d B/Y) 254 This policy is only one of many policy options available. The actual lending in response to a negative supply shock might not follow the rule described above. If actual lending is less than described in this rule, absorption will fall more in the period of the shock. However, it will bounce back to a level higher than under the described policy for all future periods, as repayment costs are less. The real exchange rate will appreciate less in the period of the shock. It will however also depreciate less in the following periods. A demand shock will not affect the levels of Y or Y ∗ . If there is no capital mobility, the demand shock must be compensated through an adjustment of the national price level, and a similar adjustment of the nominal exchange rate, leaving the real exchange rate unaffected. However, if there is capital mobility, a positive demand shock will lead to capital inflow, and an appreciation of the real exchange rate, given by (1 − m − m∗ ) ∆B ∆Q =− . Q m Y 8.6 (8.87) The importance of capital flows for consumption smoothing There are short term and long term capital flows. Short term flows will be in the form of interbank flows, i.e. flows between banks, and purchases of money market instruments, such as Treasury bills, i.e. government bonds with less than one year from issuance to maturity, or other commercial paper. Long term flows will be in the form of purchases of bonds or equity, either as portfolio investment or for the purpose of direct control. For consumption smoothing long term flows are of most importance. Given our discussion above, it is of some interest to measure the degree of mobility of long term capital. 255 Feldstein and Horioka, in a paper published in 1980, argued that if capital mobility is high one should expect zero or low correlation between national saving and investment, as countries would use the current account to smooth consumption. They tested this proposition by estimating the equation I S =α+β + ui,t , Y i,t Y i,t (8.88) where I/Y is the investment rate and S/Y is the savings rate. If capital mobility is high, β is expected to be close to zero. However, on data from 1961 to 1980, what they found was I S = 0.035 + 0.89 (0.018) (0.074) Y Y R2 = 0.91, (8.89) where numbers in parenthesis are standard errors. Instead of β close to zero, they were not able to reject β = 1 at a 95 per cent level. This results is now known as the “Feldstein-Horioka puzzle”. 8.6.1 Explaining the Feldstein-Horioka puzzle There are two ways to react to this result. Either you try to explain why capital mobility is so low, or you argue that the estimation does not really estimate capital mobility. After all, our intuition on this question is not really clear. One the one hand we do see substantial flows of capital between countries. One the other hand, one finds that many types of investment, and especially high risk investments like venture capital, tend to be national more than international. There is a good argument for why we should not expect β = 0 even if capital is mobile. In the model in section 8.5 we argued that if shocks were permanent, it would be optimal to adjust absorption immediately. In the life-cycle theory of consumption, sustained shocks to e.g. productivity or 256 demographics that will affect investments should also be expected to affect savings. So if shocks are mainly perceived as permanent we would expect a high correlation between savings and investments even with full capital mobility. However, there are also good reasons to assume that capital mobility is, or has been limited: 1. Currency risk. Financial firms usually state their liabilities, i.e. deposits, in the national currency. Investing abroad means taking a currency risk. For long term investments such risk is difficult and/or expensive to hedge. An indication of how importance currency risk is can be found be comparing capital flows between countries and capital flows between regions within countries. Generally, one finds little or no correlation between savings and investment in studies of inter-country data. The implementation of the euro will in a few years provide a very strong test of the importance of currency risk. 2. Until recently, government regulations on capital flows were widespread, even in developed countries. Only in the last ten to twenty years have restrictions on capital flows been fully removed. The Feldstein-Horioka result might therefore just reflect that capital restrictions were in fact effective. More recent studies tend to find that the estimate of β is getting smaller as new observations are added. β is however still significantly larger than zero. In line with the Feldstein-Horioka puzzle, it is generally found that countries do not tend to smooth consumption as much as the theory would expect. Why this is so, and whether this impression will change as (or if) we see more 257 Figure8.5: 1: Conjecture? Stylized View of mobility Capital Mobility in Modern History Figure Stylized A view of capital in modern history High 2000 Gold Standard 1880–1914 1914 1900 Float 1971–2000 1929 1880 Bretton Woods 1945–71 1860 1925 1918 1971 1960 Interwar 1914–45 1945 Low 1860 1880 1900 1920 1980 1940 1960 1980 2000 Source: Obstfeld and Taylor, 2002 Source: Introspection. for exchange-rate flexibility inflation targeting. global integration in the comingcoupled years,with is uncertain. One should however note In the 1990s, the term “globalization” has became a catch-all to describe the that international mobility of factors is aand rather recent world feature of theone postphenomenon of an increasingly integrated interdependent economy, that exhibits supposedly free flows of goods, services, and capital, albeit not of war world. andhype, Taylor (2002) argue thatthat as we late in cautious 1980 capital labor.Obstfeld Yet for all the economic history suggests be aaslittle in how amazing this development really is. We will show that a period of mobilityassessing was still lower than in the early years of the Gold Standard. Only impressive global integration has been witnessed before, at least for capital markets, the turn of the twentieth about ashift hundred years ago.mobility Of course,between that over theatlast 20 years have wecentury, seen ajust radical in capital earlier epoch of globalization did not endure. As the above discussion suggests, countries. According to to Obstfeld we did notinreach if we were roughly sketch outand the Taylor implied movements capitalpre-World mobility, weWar would chart an upswing from 1880 to 1914; this would be followed by a collapse 1 levels to of1945, capital mobility yearrecovery 2000. during Their the “introspective” view is though perhapsbefore with a in minor brief reconstruction of the gold standard in the 1920s, between the autarky of World War One and the given in figure 8.5. Two conclusions from this illustration might be that Depression; we would then think of a gradual rise in mobility after 1945, becoming faster after the demise of Bretton Woods in the early 1970s. Formobility illustrative is purposes, let us make the tenuous assumption that international 1. capital nothing new, and capital mobility or global capital market integration could be measured in a single parameter. Suppose we could plot that parameter over time for the last century or so. 2. making assumptions of high capital mobility in data from the period 6 1945-1990 is probably not reasonable. 258 Chapter 9 International capital flows, the IMF and monetary reform 9.1 Topics • History of capital mobility • The Eurodollar market • International debt • Interbank lending and bank regulation • International bonds and national defaults • The IMF • Taxation of capital flows 9.2 Capital flows • International bank lending – lending to customer 259 Figure 1: Conjecture? A Stylized Capital Mobility in Modern History Figure 9.1: Stylized view of View capital of mobility in modern history High 2000 Gold Standard 1880–1914 1914 1900 Float 1971–2000 1929 1880 Bretton Woods 1945–71 1860 1925 1918 1971 1960 Interwar 1914–45 1945 Low 1860 1880 1900 1920 1980 1940 1960 1980 2000 Source: Obstfeld and Taylor, 2002 Source: Introspection. for exchange-rate flexibility coupled with inflation targeting. In the 1990s, the term “globalization” has became a catch-all to describe the phenomenon of an increasingly integrated and interdependent world economy, one that exhibits supposedly free flows of goods, services, and capital, albeit not of labor. Yet for all the hype, economic history suggests that we be a little cautious in assessing how amazing this development really is. We will show that a period of impressive global integration has been260 witnessed before, at least for capital markets, at the turn of the twentieth century, just about a hundred years ago. Of course, that earlier epoch of globalization did not endure. As the above discussion suggests, if we were roughly to sketch out the implied movements in capital mobility, we would chart an upswing from 1880 to 1914; this would be followed by a collapse Table 9.1: International capital In billion USD Total stocks, 1997 % of Lend. to final user: from bank 5285 bonds and notes 3358 money market 184 Total: 8827 Interbank dep. 5098 FX-reserves 1732 Direct for. invest. 3000 FX-trading per day 1600 flows total 0.60 0.38 0.02 1.00 – interbank • Securities – money market instruments – bonds and notes • Portfolio investments • Direct investments “Eurobanking”—banking services provided in a currency that is not the currency of country where the bank is located “Eurodollars”—USD deposited in banks outside US. There exists “Euro markets” for most currencies. Note: • Commercial banks: hold their reserves as cash or deposits with a central bank. • Eurobanks hold all reserves as deposits with commercial banks. In the end every dollar in the Eurobank system will be a liability on a commercial bank in the US. 261 Figure 10: Did9.2: Capital Flowflows—poor to Poor Countries? Versus 1997 Figure Capital vs. rich1913 countries Share of world stock of foreign capital 50% 1913, gross stocks 1997, gross stocks 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% <20 20–40 40–60 60–80 >80 Per capita income range of receiving region (U.S.=100) Sources: The 1913 stock data are from Woodruff (1967) and Royal Institute for International Affairs (1937), incomes from Maddison (1995). The 1997 data are from Lane and Milesi-Ferreti (2001), based on the stocks of inward direct investment and portfolio equity liabilities. Source: Obstfeld and Taylor, 2002 they are today, so it is all the more remarkable that so much capital was directed to countries below theHalf 20 percent and 40inpercent EvolvedatinorLondon. the market Europe,income rest inlevels Asia(relative and taxto the U.S.). Today, a much larger fraction of the world’s output and population is havens. located in such low productivity regions, but a much smaller share of global foreign History: investment reaches them.69 As we have noted, capital is discouraged from entering poorer countries by a host1.of avoid factors, and some of wereflows, less relevant a century ago. Capital controls restrictions onthese capital persist in many regions. The risks of investment may be perceived differently after2.a century exchange risks, expropriations, and defaults. Domestic policies invest inofUSD without investing in the US. that distort prices, especially of investment goods, may result in returns too low to attract any capital. conditions makeina difficult much worse. 1957: capital These restrictions imposed UK. UKsituation residents wanted to Poorer avoid countries must draw on foreign capital to a greater extent than they do at present if restrictions by investing in USD. 1958: several European currencies made they are to achieve an acceptable growth in living standards. That is a fundamental reason why reform andUSD liberalization in the developing world, despite the setbacks convertible, making investments possible. of the late 1990s, are likely to continue, albeit hopefully with due regard to the Russia in need of in USD, did however painful lessons learned the recent past. not want deposits in US in fear of 69 See Clemens and Williamson (2001) for a detailed analysis of the determinants of British retaliation. capital export before 1914. New growth in the 1970’s: OPEC got income in USD, did however not want to invest in US. 60 262 Easy access for third world countries. Main market for international debt. Eurodollar market generally offers lower spreads than domestic commercial banks—Eurobanks have higher deposit rates and lower loan rates. How? • Little or no regulation in the Euro market. Until recently the US banking market was heavily regulated. – Regulation Q—maximum deposit rates – Interest Equalisation Tax and Voluntary Foreign Credit Restraint Guidelines: imposed to reduce US lending to foreigners. However, today little regulations in the US market. – No minimum reserve requirements. – Economics of scale—used to deal in large loans. Credit multiplier: do the existence of Eurobanks affect the liquidity in the USD market? Supply of USD, M : M = Mp + ME , (9.1) Mp = dollars held by private sector excluding Eurobanks, ME = USD held by Eurobanks with domestic US banks as reserves. Liquid assets held by the private sector, L: L = Mp + E, E = the public’s holding of Eurodollar (deposits in Eurobanks). 263 (9.2) How does the existence of Eurobanks affect L? We see that L Mp + E = . M Mp + ME (9.3) L can be expressed as L = M ME : E Mp +1 E Mp + MEE E . (9.4) Reserve to deposit ratio in the Eurobank system. Expect to be low. Mp : E Ratio of holdings of dollars outside the Eurobanks to the holdings in the Eurobanks. Expect to be high. ⇒ should probably expect that L M ≈ 1. Eurobanks have only a marginal effect on liquidity in the USD-market. 9.3 The international debt market Makes it possible to finance current account deficits over long periods of time without any automatic stabilisation effects ⇒ same countries remain deficit countries over long periods of time. ⇒ “ballooning” of debt for some countries. Assume three regions: US, Latin America and Europe. Only trade between Latin America and US, between US and Europe, not trade between Europe and Latin America. US trade surplus of 100 with Latin America, deficit of 100 with Europe. US: trade balance. Europe: surplus of 100. Latin America: Deficit of 100. 264 Latin America finance deficit by borrowing 100 in Eurodollar market. Europe accumulates assets of 100 as deposits in Eurobanks. If pattern continues, Latin America will accumulate debt, Europe accumulate assets. Eurodollar market continue to grow as long as balance of payments deficit persists. Why no automatic stabilisation? – Growth of euro-dollar market is non-inflationary as for each amount borrowed there is an equal amount saved. Money base does not change here. – Balance-of-payments surpluses “recycled”, world aggregate demand remains unchanged. – Note that the ballooning of USD debt is created although the US have a balanced current account. What is driving this? Europe willing to hold USD. Latin America needs USD, not EUR. If Europe not willing to hold USD, US would have to use foreign reserves to finance deficit with Europe. The US money base would be reduced. US competitiveness would grow, US imports fall. At the same time, Latin America would not get USD to finance US imports—would have to improve own competitiveness. Result: more US exports to Europe, more Latin American exports to US. With Eurobanks: Latin America can postpone reform of exporting sector. Imbalances not corrected. 265 Latin America is the debtor of the Eurobanks. Eurobanks are the debtors of Europe. So Latin America owes its debt to Europe? No—and yes. Europe has deposits in banks—seemingly a safe investment. However, if Latin America defaults the bank will default, and Europe will not get any money. Why is this a problem: – In many cases the creditors of banks believe banks to be “safe”, because they believe banks will not be allowed to default. So bank deposits are sometimes made with a “wrong” perception of risk. – Assume “Europe” is a number of smaller investors. If Latin America defaults on its debt this will lead to losses for a potentially large group of people. – As pointed out above, debt allows Latin America to postpone reform. However, if they can just default and get rid of debt, do they ever have incentive to reform? Inter-bank market: loans and transactions between banks – To satisfy (short-term) needs to fulfill regulation criteria in resident country. – Banks obtain deals at different times—continually need to balance their accounts. – Utilise opportunities for niche specialisation—banks specialise in lending, and obtain financing through the interbank market. – Arbitrage trades. 266 Bank interdependence Because of the interbank lending, there is interdependence in the capital markets: if one bank defaults other banks might default as well. Some problems associated with banks: – Information asymmetries. Depositors know little about the bank, the bank has little knowledge of its debtors. Both the bank and the final borrower might have incentive to take excess risk. – Risk asymmetries. Depositors believe their deposits to be covered by deposit insurance or a central bank lender of last resort function. Have little incentive to reduce risk taking in the bank. – “Lender’s trap”. If you have borrowed a firm a large sum of money, and the firm is on the edge of default, should you borrow it a little more to let this firm avoid default? – “Race to the bottom”. To increase profits banks can reduce the bank capital. However, this makes them more vulnerable for loan losses. – If lending and borrowing is international, but regulations of capital requirements is national ⇒ potential instability. The structure of the banking business seems to imply that aggressive banks get the upper hand. However, this seems to be the result of a market failure where banks not fully internalises the cost of default in the banking industry. If we accept this reasoning, there is an argument for regulation of the banking industry. 267 If the industry has a global scope, and the costs of failure are of an international character, then regulation should be international. ⇒ The Basel Capital Accord. Agreement on capital adequacy measurement and standards. Defines 1. eligible capital elements, 2. variable risk weights applicable to several main categorises of onand off-balance sheet exposure, 3. set overall minimum capital ratio to 8 per cent of risk weighted assets, and 4. set overall “core capital” to at least 4 per cent. Agreement implemented in 1992. It imposed a substantial increase in capital requirements for some banks. However, many problems remained unsolved: – Interbank lending was seen as low risk. However, as discussed above interbank lending is not risk free. – Many banks were able to take considerable risk within this accord, e.g. as seen under the Asian crisis in 1997. Currently discussions about “Basel 2”. Main changes from “Basel 1”: – Risk will be measured with “value-at-risk” models. As banks often have the best models of this kind, risk will be measured by the banks own models. – Ratings from rating agencies—like Moody’s or S&P—may be used to assess the riskiness of the bank’s entire portfolio. 268 New accord to be implemented in 2006. However, already much discussion of how this will work in practice. The international bond market – Foreign bonds: bonds issued by foreign corporations or countries in the domestic capital market of another country. Normally sold by a host-country investment bank, and traded in the host financial market. Subject to host country laws. – Eurobonds: bond issued in a country that does not use the currency as domestic currency, e.g. USD denominated bond issued in London. Usually issued by a syndicate of underwriters, and issued in a number of countries simultaneously. Annual new eurobonds run about twice the rate as new foreign bonds. Why direct finance instead of finance through banks? – Potential asymmetry problems in direct finance. Banks are supposed to be able to generate superior information, and therefore have an information advantage. – However, for large companies this is less the case. Should expect more direct finance. – The easier to collect information, the more direct finance. Information problems might be a problem for small and/or developing countries when obtaining loans. International agencies, like the World Bank, work as intermediaries in the bond market. People will rather buy a World Bank bond than say, an Indian government bond. Use of the international bond market. Why borrow in a currency different form the domestic currency? 269 – Profit on risk premiums. – Diversify risk. International business cycles are not perfectly correlated. Return is less correlated between countries than within countries. – Hedge currency risk, especially if costs and incomes are denominated in different currencies. – Finance current account deficits. If state companies finance new investments aborad, they reduce demand for capital at home. Implicitly this takes pressure away from the foreign reserves. – If local markets are illiquid, international borrowing might be the only option. – The foreign banking industry might be more efficient, and therefore offer better rates than the domestic industry. – Tax adjustments and use of tax havens. Government vs. national debt (1) Balance of payment (BOP)= current account surplus + capital account surplus = ∆F g (increase in foreign reserves) (2) Capital account surplus = net long term private capital inflow + government foreign borrowing - gross short-term capital outflow Combine (1) and (2): (3) Government foreign borrowing = current account deficit + ∆F g + gross short-term capital outflow - net long term private capital inflow Note: net national indebtness is determined only by current account deficit. 270 Government indebtness will increase even if current account is zero if large short term outflow of capital. What determines short-term capital outflow? This was discussed in Lecture 8—the speculative portfolio. Lender’s trap Why do international banks continue to make loans to countries on the verge of default? Problem for the banks: either make new loans so the country can service payments on old debt, or declare the borrower insolvent, and write off the loan. Expected benefit from lending: E(B) = (P0 − P1 )D. (9.5) P0 = probability of default before new loan is made. P1 = probability of default after new loan is made. D = debt outstanding before new loan. Expected cost of new loan: E(C) = P1 L. (9.6) L = value of new loan. Net benefit of new loan as percentage of outstanding debt: L E(B) − E(C) N (B) = = P0 − P 1 1 + . D D Give new loan if N (B) > 0. 271 (9.7) 9.4 Can a country default? Many poor countries heavily indebted. – African countries: mostly debt to foreign governments. – Latin America: mostly debt to foreign banks. 1982: Debt crisis. Mainly caused by the rising cost of imports due to OPEC 2 rise in oil prices. Many debtors de facto insolvent—debt forgiveness necessary. Important ratio: debt payment to export earnings. What happens if a country can not service its debts? Problem: as a creditor your debt becomes more worth if other creditors are willing to reduce their claims. ⇒ tragedy of the commons. No one has incentive to move first. Search for agreement that is binding across different asset classes and jurisdictions. Possible solutions: – International bankruptcy court – Majority action clauses in debt contracts: allows a majority of the creditors to agree on changes in the debt contract that affects all creditors. – Increase IMF power. Current discussion: – IMF: proposes to allow majority voting, overseen by the IMF. 60-70 per cent of creditors should be enough to determine restructuring. 272 – US Treasury: borrowing countries should add clauses to debt contracts that describe what happen if the country gets into trouble, like how a default will be initiated et.c. Introducing such clauses should be condition for receiving IMF loans. 9.5 The role of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) When confronted with a member with a balance of payment deficit: restore equilibrium. But how? Role: – “to promote the adjustment process”, – “restore viability of balance of payment in the context of price stability and sustained economic growth, without resort to measures that impair the freedom of trade and payments.” Earlier: much emphasis on fiscal deficit. Later years: take more country specific considerations, look more at long term prospects and structural reform process. Policy choices – Monetary policy; usually setting ceiling on the rate of domestic credit growth. – Devaluation of fixed exchange rate. – Reduce price distortions, e.g. ∗ by reducing subsidies, 273 ∗ eliminate interest rate ceilings, or ∗ by trade liberalisation. – Freeze wages. – Target the growth of net foreign indebtness. “Demand management”. Important IMF policy: Domestic absorption must be constrained to a level consistent with the level of domestic production plus any sustainable net capital inflows, otherwise the balance of payments deficit is unsustainable. To assure a permanent solution to balance of payment problems: – Improve resource allocation to lessen the constraint on the level of domestic demand imposed by a given availability of resources. Policies include: ∗ exchange rate adjustments, ∗ interest rate adjustments, ∗ reducing subsidies. – Structural reform. If problem is high imports of expensive oil, increase domestic energy production, reduce energy vast. As pointed our above, there is a close connection between domestic banks and international capital flows. This has been important factors in recent financial crises, like in Asia 1997. Should international financial stability be on the agenda of IMF? IMF: much focus on the importance of reducing asymmetric information. Elements: 274 – Increased disclosure of information. Arrange common reporting standards. – Requirements for bank capital. – Modification of creditor rights (as discussed above), so as to stop “grab-races”, attempts to cash in, and therefore force insolvency on an illiquid, but solvent debtor. – Reduce short-term capital flows if such flows have negative externalities. IMF can force compliance to international standards by conditioning lending on such compliance. Does the IMF create moral hazard? IMF works like a lender of last resort for countries. Reduce incentive to balance your own books, as the IMF will rescue the government if balance of payment deficit becomes unsustainable. Is the economy better of without a lender of last resort? Might be less irresponsible behaviour. However, crisis will still exist. How large will the cost of such crisis be without a lender of last resort? For countries of strategic importance: Someone will step in anyway (?) By setting conditions for loans, phase out payments, and have close surveillance of results, the IMF seeks to reduce moral hazard. The monetary approach IMF: – Balance of payments deficits tend to have a common cause. 275 – The policies mentioned above are mostly sufficient to correct such imbalances. Argument: in developing countries money used to finance public deficits. No “wall” between the government asset sheet and the central bank asset sheet Budget deficit ⇒ increase in money supply ⇒ inflation ⇒ the public want to increase holdings of foreign currency, dishoard domestic currency (as in lecture on portfolio choice) ⇒ foreign reserves fall, country must finance deficit by borrowing abroad. The country experience a real appreciation because of the increase in the domestic price level. To retain domestic production tariffs introduced. Frequent devaluations might alleviate the problem for short periods of time. However, if government deficit persists, the spiral continues. When debt level no longer sustainable, IMF called in. Situation: – Not able to service debt. – Domestic economy distorted by trade restrictions. – Financial markets distorted by “financial repression”, means used to make domestic markets accept domestic government debt. The IMF’s approach: adjustment requires a fundamental change in economic and financial conditions. Budget deficit reduced, distortions reversed. Main target: stop dishoarding of local currency. 276 Question: should change be gradual or rapid? Historically IMF has favoured rapid reform. Has taken more flexible approach in later years. The New Structuralist debate Critique: IMF approach should be expected to work well in developed countries. However, developing countries have different structure, need different approach. There exists no “common cause”, and no singular solution. Examples: – Reducing money supply could increase inflation if “interest cost push” strong—lower money supply would push up interest rates, higher interest rates might push up prices. – Devaluation might be negative if ∗ the cost of necessary imports so much that domestic supply will fall. ∗ the fall in the spending power of wages fall so much that aggregate demand falls, leading to lower growth. ∗ if much of domestic debt is denominated in foreign currency, leading to higher cost of debt servicing. ∗ if tariffs are measured in per cent, a devaluation, leading to higher import prices, will at the same time mean higher taxes, i.e. contractionary fiscal policy. – Reduction of subsidies might decrease local demand, leading to slower growth. – If deficits have non-monetary causes, like recession in export markets, IMF strategy will be counterproductive. 277 These arguments depend on assumptions of import dependence and resource immobility. Example: Asian crisis in 1997 IMF advice: increase interest rates to stop dishoarding of domestic currency. Balance public deficits. Problem: these countries were in recession. Increased interest rates made could make this recession even deeper. Reducing fiscal deficits in periods of recession is pro-cyclical, not counter cyclical policy. Empirical evidence: not much support for one nor the other. IMF policies stabilise the situation, but “sustainability” is not guaranteed. However, most countries do not fully implement IMF policies. New structuralist’s claims about devaluation not supported. IMF and Argentina IMF sceptical to currency board from the start. However: IMF focus on “national adoption of policies”—the country must be presented with alternatives and get to make a choice. IMF tried to make Argentina leave the board in 1997-98. At this time Argentina was doing well. Probably only small effects if board had been changed. However, the board was very important as a symbol of new brooms in Argentinean politics. August 2001: IMF still supported Argentina. Damned if you do, damned if you don’t... Now IMF is stating requirements: – Restore the confidence in the banking system. (But how?) 278 – Change legal structure to protect creditors—current system favours debtors. – Reign in spending by the provinces. 9.6 Capital controls in Chile History: Introduced in June 1991. Initially: 20 per cent reserve requirement on portfolio investments to be deposited in central bank at no interest. For maturities under one year it applied for the whole period, for maturities over one year, it applied for one year. In July 1992: changed to requirement of 30 per cent for ne year, independent of maturity of investment. Extended to trade credits and loans to FDI. In June 1998 reduced to 10 per cent, and abolished in September 1998. Intentions: – Slow down volume of capital flowing into the country. – change composition of flows to longer maturities. – Allow the Central Bank to maintain a higher interest differential between domestic and foreign interest rates. – Reduce vulnerability to international financial instability. Effects: – Ratio of long term flows to short term flows increased. – However, so did “residual flows”—there is some evidence of evasion. 279 – Some evidence of increased “independence” in monetary policy. – However, measures of international vulnerability shows mixed results: ∗ Almost no reaction to the Mexican crisis in 1994, ∗ however, a more marked reaction to the Asian crisis than what was felt in the rest of Latin America. ∗ Further, financial stability was restored in 1999, after the reserve requirements were abolished altogether. In the end however, Chile probably remained stable because economic policy as a whole was stable during the 1990’s. Potential problems: – Increases the cost of capital, especially for small and mid-sized firms. – Always the temptation to turn such measures into permanent policies. – Policymakers might become overconfident, neglecting the needs for more general reform. 280 50 Table 2 : Capital (gross)inflows to Chile: Millions of US$ Figure Inflows 9.3: Capital to Chile Year Short term Percentage Long term Percentage flows of total flows Total Deposits* of total 1988 916,564 96.3 34,838 3.7 951,402 -- 1989 1,452,595 95.0 77,122 5.0 1,529,717 -- 1990 1,683,149 90.3 181,419 9.7 1,864,568 -- 1991 521,198 72.7 196,115 27.3 717,313 587 1992 225,197 28.9 554,072 71.1 779,269 11,424 1993 159,462 23.6 515,147 76.4 674,609 41,280 1994 161,575 16.5 819,699 83.5 981,274 87,039 1995 69,675 6.2 1,051,829 93.8 1,121,504 38,752 1996 67,254 3.2 2,042,456 96.8 2,109,710 172,320 1997 81,131 2.8 2,805,882 97.2 2,887,013 331,572 * Deposits in the Banco Chile due to reserve requirements. Source: Edwards, 2000 281 59 Figure 9.4: The tax equivalent of the Chilean reserve requirement 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.00 90 91 92 TAX180 93 94 95 TAX1YR 96 97 98 TAX3YRS Stay of 3 months, 1 year and 3 years. Source: Edwards, 2000 Figure 2: Tax Equivalent of Capital Controls: Stay of 180 days, 1 year and 3 years 282 Chapter 10 Exercises Lecture 1 1. Gresham’s law (a) Gresham’s law states that bad money always will drive good money out of circulation. People will choose to use the bad money for transactions, and store the good money. Explain why. (b) Assume a system where two types of coins circulate in the economy. Some coins are of silver, and some coins are of gold. Discuss possible problems that can arise in such a system if there is discovered a huge deposit of silver. Will silver or gold coins dominate circulation? Will silver or gold dominate as a store of value? (c) Assume that one has a currency that is backed by a two-metal standard. Assume that for 35 units of currency one can claim 1 ounce of gold or 35 ounces of silver at the central bank. Assume gold supply increases three-fold, while supply of sil- 283 ver remains constant. How will this affect the central banks holdings of gold and silver? Will this currency be “stable”? 2. Fiat money and free banking... (a) Assume that the Norwegian government allows everyone to print Norwegian kroner on their own colour printers. What would do you think would happen to the Norwegian money supply? What will happen to the Norwegian price level? (b) At the islands Yap in the Pacific Ocean people used large, heavy round stones with a hole in the middle as currency. One stone took two men approximately one week to make. These stones worked as both unit of account, means of payment and store of value. However, as they were difficult to carry, the islanders did not care to carry them around. Instead they issued legal titles to the stones. These legal titles were used for trading. Note that the stones only had value as currency. They had no value as a commodity. i. What is the difference between the stones on Yap and the ability to print your own money? ii. Explain the fact that inflation on Yap was stable. iii. What would happen to the price level on Yap if the islanders got a new technology that would reduce the time to make a new stone from one week to one day? Should this have any effects for the real economy on Yap? 3. Seignorage 284 (a) Seignorage is given by Seignoraget = Mt − Mt−1 . Pt (10.1) We know that real money demand can be written as Mt = Et Pt Pt+1 Pt −η . (10.2) Assume perfect foresight. Further, assume that the central bank can commit to a fixed rate of money growth for all future, µ, so that Mt = 1 + µ. Mt−1 (10.3) Use this information to show that the rate of money growth, µopt , that will maximise seignorage revenue is equal to η1 . (b) Average growth in Norwegian M1 over the period from December 1992 to January 2002 has been 9.48 per cent on a yearly basis. Assume that Norges Bank behaves according to the rule of optimal seignorage. Find η. (c) Assuming constant money growth, the formula for seignorage can be written Seignoraget = µ(1 + µ)−η−1 . (10.4) Calculate seignorage for Norway. (d) We want to find seignorage as a percentage of public expenditure. Note that in equation (11.4) seignorage is measured as a fraction of the price level. For our purposes it is reasonable to approximate the price level with the money stock in the last period. In January 2002 Norwegian M1 was 382.6 billion 285 NOK. The public expenditure for 2001 was expected to be 487.9 billion NOK. Calculate seignorage as a percentage of government expenditure for Norway. Compare your number with the numbers in Box 8.1 in Obstfeld and Rogoff, ch. 8.2. Lecture 2 In its simplest form, a currency board is a money printing rule. We will consider Argentina, where the domestic currency is the Argentinean peso (ARP). The currency board arrangement says that (a) the ARP/USD exchange rate is 1.00, and (b) for every peso in circulation the currency board must hold USD 1.00 in reserve. Figure 10.1 gives a simple example. Mark that all units are ARP. The financial system are characterised by two key ratios: 1. The public’s deposit-to-cash ratio. Here that ratio is 12 (9000/750). This reflects the optimal amount of ‘liquidity’ which the public demands, relative to the size of their bank deposits. What ‘liquidity’ means here is ‘cash required to facilitate purchases of goods and services.’ The ratio of 12 reflects a tradeoff. On the one hand, the more cash held, the easier it is to transact. One the other hand, the more cash held, the more is given up in foregone interest income. 2. The banking system’s deposit-to-reserve ratio. Here that ratio is 60 (9000/150). This reflects a tradeoff which underlies good banking practice. The banker needs some cash in the vault in order to satisfy customer withdrawal demands (and prevent a bank run). 286 287 8,850 900 900 150 8,850 Pesos Net Worth Deposits Net Worth 900 0 Liabilities Pesos Loans Currency Board Assets Loans Net Worth USD (cash or securities) 9,000 750 Liabilities (i) The public’s deposit-to-cash ratio is 12. This reflects the optimal amount of ‘liquidity’ which the public demands, relative to the size of their bank deposits. What ‘liquidity’ means (here) is ‘cash required to facilitate purchases of goods and services.’ The ratio of 12 reflects a tradeoff. On the one hand, the more cash held, the easier it is to transact. On the other hand, the more cash held, the more given up in foregone interest income. 9,000 0 Commercial Bank Assets Liabilities What characterizes this simple financial system are two key ratios: Deposits Pesos Assets Public Figure 10.1: Example of a currency board In its simplest form, a currency board is a money printing rule. We’ll consider Argentina, where the domestic currency is the Argentinean peso (ARP). The currency board arrangement says that (a) the ARP/USD exchange rate is 1.00, and (b) for every peso in circulation the currency board must hold USD 1.00 in reserve. Here is a simple example. All units are ARP except the assets of the currency board. PART A However, the more cash in the vault the fewer loans made, which in turn reduces interest income. The balance sheets in figure 10.1 represents ‘equilibrium’ in that the amount of deposits, cash and reserves are consistent with the two above ratios—i.e. we assume by definition that these two ratios characterise equilibrium. For more on a monetary equilibrium, see the appendix. 1. Here are two definitions: – Money supply=currency held by the public plus deposits held by the public. – Monetary base=total currency in circulation plus commercial bank reserve deposits held at the central bank (the latter are zero here). This is called high powered money. It is also called the liabilities of the central bank. Note that the monetary base is what is exogenous in the above system of balance sheets. That is, given the monetary base and the two above ratios, everything else is determinate. This will be clearer as we go along. Given the data in figure 10.1, compute the values of the money supply and the monetary base. 2. Next, assume that the Argentinean real exchange rate appreciates vis-a-vis USD. Provide one or two sentences to say what this means. This question should be answered abstractly, without references to the above data. Your answer should be expressed in intuitive terms, using plain, jargon-free language. 3. Now suppose that, because of the ARP real appreciation, an Argentinean importer wants to import some U.S. goods. Specifically, 288 she wants to import 18 dollars worth of machines. This means that she needs to obtain USD 18. (a) First, suppose the importer goes to her commercial bank and asks for USD 18. The commercial bank turns to a trader in an American bank, and asks him to sell it USD 18 in return for ARP 18. Assume the trade goes through, and the importer receives USD 18 from its bank in return for ARP 18. What is the effect on the Argentinean monetary base? (b) Second, suppose that, because of the overvaluation, the trader at the American bank will not sell USD for ARP at 1:1. He might sell each USD for 1.2 ARP, but if he did then the fixed exchange rate would have de facto collapsed. The good news for the Argentinean importer is that the currency board is obliged to sell her USD at 1:1. The commercial bank will trade ARP 18 for USD 18 by sending a request to the currency board. What is the currency board supposed to do with the pesos it receives for these USD? If the currency board does this, what is the effect on the Argentinean monetary base? (c) According to the quantity theory of money, money (M ) times the number of transactions conducted with money (velocity, V ) should equal the price level, P , times the number of transactions in the economy, T , or M · V = P · T. (10.5) We can simplify by assuming that velocity is constant, and that T can be set equal to to total production in the economy, 289 Y. Do you think the actions by the currency board described above will alleviate the overvaluation of the Argentinean peso? Why? (d) What will happen if, for some reason, this process continues? That is, what will happen if Argentineans try to convert all their ARP-denominated bank deposits into USD? 4. Given the transaction by the Argentinean importer, what will happen to the Argentinean current account once this transaction occurs? Will there be change in the direction of trade flows? How will capital flows be affected? 5. Once the Argentinean importer has obtained the USD 18, you should find that the system of balance sheets are no longer ‘in equilibrium’. That is, the two ratios discussed above are no longer 12 and 60. Use the four linear equations described in the appendix to compute the new equilibrium. What is the new money supply? Is this new value for the money supply consistent with alleviating the overvaluation problem? 6. The money multiplier is defined as the ratio of the reduction in the money supply to the reduction in the monetary base. The money multiplier tells us how fast the supply of money grows if another unit of monetary base is created. What is the money multiplier here? If the central bank prints one more piece of currency, how much will the total money supply grow, and therefore how much will the price level increase (if V and Y is constant)? The important point in the example above is to show that a currency 290 board has a ‘self-correcting’ aspect to it. Excessive inflation (relative to the reserve country) and/or real exchange rate overvaluation should be corrected if the currency board does what it is supposed to do. In addition, the example points out that a county with a currency board has effectively given up any sort of active monetary policy. Monetary policy becomes a currency printing/burning robot. Policy questions: 1. Look at attached reading and what you have learned above and in class, and make a table which briefly outlines the pros and cons of a currency board for a country like Argentina. 2. Pretend that you are an economic advisor to the Argentinean president Carols Menem and his Minister of Finance, Domingo Cavallo, in 1991. With the befits of knowing what has happened up to today (April 2002), make a recommendation to them regarding the type of exchange rate mechanism which Argentina should adopt. Appendix The essence of a ‘monetary equilibrium’ is that the the public’s depositto-cash ratio must equal 12 and the banking system’s deposit-to reserve ratio must equal 60. This, in addition to the accounting definitions inherent in the balance sheets, imply the following system of linear equations must hold: 291 H = R+C 60 = R+L R 12 = D C D + C = L + H, where – H≡the monetary base (number of pesos in circulation). – R≡reserves of the banking system (cash in the vault). – L≡loans. – C≡currency held by the public. – D≡deposits held by the public at commercial banks. In a currency board H is given from outside the system, by market forces. Given H, the above four equations are linear in 4 unknowns, D, C, L and R. Attached readings (Included in separate file) – Kurt Sculer: “Introduction to currency boards”, (http://users.erols,com/kurrency/intro.htm) 292 – “The ABC of currency boards”, The Economist, October 1997 – “Dollar mad?”, The Economist, October 2001 – “A decline without parallel”, The Economist, March 2002 Lecture 3 1. What do we mean with the n-1 problem in a multilateral exchange rate system? 2. In the European Monetary System (EMS) a number of European countries had agreed to fix their currencies to the European Currency Unit (ECU). ECU was defined as the value of a basket that contained a weighted average of the currencies of the member countries. In the early 1980’s the EMS was a fairly flexible system, with frequent adjustments. However, as a first step on the road towards a common currency in the EU, it was in 1987 decided to let the currencies be fixed to ECU, and to avoid adjustments. After the opening of Eastern Germany in 1989, and the introduction of DEM in the eastern territories in the summer of 1990, Germany experienced an economic boom. To avoid inflation, the Bundesbank responded to this growth by tightening money supply. A result was that German interest rates rose. At the same time a number of other members of the EMS, including France and Great Britain, experienced an economic slowdown. These countries wanted a loser money supply to reduce interest rates. 293 Assume that the UIP holds. Use the n-1 problem to illustrate the strains put on the EMS-system. If possible, use diagrams to illustrate the problem. 3. In a meeting in 1991 Germany suggested to revalue the DEM inside the EMS system (increase the value of DEM relative to the other currencies in the system). Could this have alleviated the strains on the system? 4. France vetoed the German suggestion. Discuss why. Lecture 4 From your former lessons in macro, you know the concept of a Phillips curve. The Phillips curve implies a relationship between unemployment and inflation. In “modern macroeconomics” one thinks about the Phillips curve as a fluctuations around a “non-accelerating-inflationrate-of-unemployment” (the NAIRU). The NAIRU is seen as the longrun rate of unemployment. In the short term unemployment can be higher or lower than the NAIRU, depending on whether inflation is higher or lower than expected inflation. If we call unemployment for u, the NAIRU for un and inflation for π, and we let π e be expected inflation, we can express the Phillips curve as u = un + a(π e − π). (10.6) If inflation exceeds expected inflation, the unemployment rate can for be less than the NAIRU. However, one can not expect inflation to exceed expected inflation over time. We assume that the government has two policy goals: to keep inflation 294 stable, and to keep unemployment low. In fact, the government has as a goal to keep unemployment at a level u∗ < un . This can be rationalised if one think there are some sort of inefficiencies in the labour market that lead to an increase in the NAIRU rate. As a second best policy the government target an unemployment rate below the NAIRU. We specifically assume that u∗ = σun , (10.7) where 0 < σ < 1. The government minimises a loss function, L, that contain these two elements: L = π 2 + b[u − u∗ ]2 , (10.8) where b (assumed to be > 0) is the weight on holding unemployment at u∗ . If we substitute in for the equations (11.85) and (11.86), we obtain L = π 2 + b[(1 − σ)un + a(π e − π)]2 . (10.9) 1. Assume the PPP to hold, i.e. et = pt − p∗t , (10.10) where et is the exchange rate in period t, and p∗ is the foreign price level. Assume that the foreign price level is fixed at p∗ = 0, and that foreign inflation, π ∗ , is zero. Discuss the relationship between domestic inflation, π, and the depreciation of the exchange rate, · e, under these assumptions. 2. We assume that the government focuses on the exchange rate instead of the price level. Give some arguments for why a government could choose to focus monetary policy on a stable exchange 295 rate instead of controlling the money supply. 3. Assume that the exchange rate is fixed, so that et = e. This · implies that e = 0. If the government adjusts the fixed rate this will have the cost of C. As long as the regime is fixed at et = e, C = 0. If the rate is adjusted, C > 0. The loss function can now be written as ·2 ·e · · L = e + b[(1 − σ)un + a(e − e)]2 + C e, (10.11) ·e where e is expected depreciation. Explain why C might be positive. 4. Assume that the fixed exchange rate is credible and the government does not adjust the exchange rate. Calculate the loss of the government. 5. Assume that the fixed exchange rate is credible. Discuss under which circumstances the government might have incentive to change the exchange rate. What is the role of C? 6. Assume that the fixed exchange rate is not credible. Assume the market expects the government to devalue the exchange rate, i.e. ·e assume e > 0. How would this affect optimal government policy? 7. In the light of the above results, discuss the term “self-fulfilling speculative attacks”. Lecture 5 1. The Krugman model Country A is a developing country with a long history of high 296 inflation. The money demand is given by mt − pt = −η(Et pt+1 − pt ). (10.12) Assume that PPP holds, so that the exchange rate on log-form, e, is given by et = pt − p∗t . (10.13) For simplicity we set p∗ = 0, and assume that foreign inflation is zero. If we assume perfect foresight, and use continuous time notation, so that · et+1 − et = e, (10.14) we can write the money demand function as · mt − et = −η e. (10.15) Money supply, M (remember that m = log(M )) reflects the central bank asset sheet. We remember that the central bank has two main types of assets, foreign reserves and domestic government bonds. We can therefore write M as M = D + R, (10.16) where D is domestic bonds, and R is foreign reserves. The central bank only hold foreign reserves when the exchange rate is fixed. The exchange rate is fixed at a level e = e. This implies that the money supply is fixed at a level m = m. However, assume that the central banks holdings of domestic bonds grow at a rate µ. 297 The size of domestic credit at time t will be given by dt = d0 + µt. (10.17) (a) If domestic credit grows at a speed µ and the exchange rate shall remain fixed, what must happen to the money supply? Which implication will this have for the level of foreign reserves, R? Assume that domestic credit grows by 20 per cent a year, so that µ = 0.2. Assume that initial domestic credit is D0 = 10 and initial foreign reserves are R0 = 90. At what time will R = 0 if this policy is not changes? (b) If we use the above model, and assume money supply growth at a fixed rate µ, we find the following expression for the exchange rate: et = mt + µη. (10.18) The “shadow exchange rate”, ee, is defined as the exchange rate that would have been the actual exchange rate if a speculative attack had already happened. Assume that the government continues the policy of fixed growth in domestic credit forever. Identify the shadow exchange rate given our definition of M . (c) According to the Krugman model a speculative attack will happen in the point T , when the fixed exchange rate equals the shadow exchange rate, or e = ee. Illustrate the paths of e and ee. Explain why a speculative attack must happen at T . (d) Assume that η = 2. Find T . 2. Tobin tax 298 Assume that we have a fixed exchange rate. The rate is fixed at 1:1. The economy fluctuates between three ‘states’—high output, intermediate output and low output. Assume that the government believes the costs of a devaluation will be high. However, if there is a speculative attack, the government will devalue the currency. How much will depend on the state of the economy. In the low output state the new exchange rate will be 1.5:1. In the intermediate state the exchange rate will be 1.25:1. In the good state the government will not make a shift. The central bank has committed 10 million domestic currency units to defend the exchange rate. There are two traders in the market. Each controls 5 million domestic currency units. If the trader sells his domestic currency to the central bank he obtains foreign currency at the rate 1:1. If there is a devaluation, he can exchange back at the new rate. If there is no cost of speculation his profit will be the amount of foreign currency times the change in the exchange rate. Example: sell 4 million, exchange rate devalue to 1.5:1. Profit: (1.5-1)*4=2. (a) Assume that the cost of speculation is 1. Calculate the profit of each trader if he sells and the other holds, and if he holds and the other sells, and if both hold and both sell for all three states of the economy. Organise your findings in three two by two matrixes. Identify Nash equilibria for all three cases. (b) Let the cost of speculation increase from 1 to 1.5. Will any of the above Nash equilibria change? How? Discuss the consequences. 299 (c) Discuss whether or not this is a good argument for introducing a Tobin tax. Lecture 6 1. Assuming no transaction costs, suppose GBP=USD 2.4110 in New York, USD=FRF 3.997 in Paris, and FRF=GBP 0.1088 in London. How could you take advantage of these rates? 2. The media frequently report that ”the dollar’s value strengthened against many currencies in response to the Federal Reserve’s plan to increase interest rates.” Explain why the dollar’s value is expected to appreciate, and why the rate may change even before the Fed affects interest rates. 3. The following quotations are available to you. (You may either buy or sell at the stated rates.) Hong Kong Shanghai Bank: FRF/USD=4.8600 Dredsner Bank: DEM/USD=1.4200 Banque National de Paris: FRF/DEM=3.4400 Assume that you have an initial USD 1,000,000. Is triangular arbitrage possible? If so, explain the steps and compute your profit. 4. You plan to spend one month at the luxurious Nusa Dua Hotel in Bali, Indonesia, a year from now. The present charge for a suitable suite plus meals is Rps 28,800 per night or USD 800 at the present exchange rate of INR/USD 36. (a) The Nusa Dua Hotel tells you that next year’s charges will increase with Indonesian inflation, which you expect to be 16 300 per cent. U.S. inflation is currently 4 per cent per annum. You believe implicitly in the theory of purchasing power parity. How many U.S. dollars will you need one year hence to pay for your 30-day vacation? (b) The forward rate on a one year contract is INR/USD=40. How many dollars do you need one year hence if you enter into a forward contract today? (c) On a one year instrument, the US rate of interest is 8 per cent. What is the rate of interest on a similar instrument in Indonesia? 5. The United States and France both produce Cabernet Sauvignon wine. A bottle of Cabernet Sauvignon sell in the United States for USD 18. An equivalent bottle sells in France for FRF 100. (a) According to purchasing power parity, what should be the U.S. dollar/French franc spot rate of exchange? (b) Suppose the price of Cabernet Sauvignon in the US is expected to rise to USD 20 over the next year, while the price of a comparable bottle of French wine is expected to rise to FRF 118. What should be the one-year forward U.S. dollar/French franc exchange rate? (c) Given your answers to (a) and (b) above, and given that the current interest rate in the United States is 6 per cent for notes of one-year maturity, what would you expect current French interest rates to be? 6. Suppose today’s spot exchange rate is USD/DEM=0.51. The six-month interest rates on dollars and DM are 13 per cent and 301 6 per cent respectively (these are annualised rates). The sixmonth forward rate is USD/DEM=0.5273. A foreign exchange advisory service has predicted that the DEM will appreciate to USD/DEM=0.54 within six months. (a) How would you use forward contracts to profit in the above situation? (b) How would you use borrowing and lending transactions to profit? 7. In the 1950s and 1960s many influential economists like Milton Friedman and Harry Johnson were in favour of floating exchange rates. Johnson argued that floating exchange rates normally would ”move only slowly and fairly predictably.” (a) Explain the reasoning behind such a statement. (b) With the benefit of hindsight we know that exchange rate fluctuations have been anything but slow and predictable, at least in the short run. Explain. Lecture 7 The starting point of the monetary equilibrium model is the real money demand function, given as mt − pt = −ηit+1 + φyt . (10.19) From this we can derive an expression for the price level, given as s−t T ∞ 1 X η η pt = (ms − φys + ηis+1 ) + lim pt+T . T →∞ 1 + η s=t 1 + η 1+η (10.20) 302 If we assume PPP and UIP to hold at all times, and we assume perfect foresight, we can obtain an expression for the the exchange rate: s−t T ∞ η η 1 X ∗ ∗ et = (ms −φys +ηis+1 −ps )+ lim et+T . T →∞ 1 + η s=t 1 + η 1+η (10.21) 1. Define the real exchange rate, Q. What assumption do we make about the real exchange rate when we assume PPP to hold? 2. Write the assumptions of the uncovered interest rate parity in mathematical terms. Explain the intuitive argument behind the UIP. If the PPP holds at all times, and expected depreciation is zero, what are the implications for the relationship between domestic and foreign interest rates? 3. Both equation (11.42) and (11.43) contain two elements. The last element is on the form lim T →∞ η 1+η T et+T . (10.22) et+T 6= 0? (10.23) (a) What is the implication if lim T →∞ η 1+η T (b) Explain the term “rational bubbles”. (c) One often assumes that lim T →∞ η 1+η T et+T = 0. Explain why this is reasonable. Discuss. 303 (10.24) 4. Assume that the price level is given by s−t ∞ 1 X η pt = (ms − φys + ηis+1 ), 1 + η s=t 1 + η (10.25) and that the exchange rate is given by s−t ∞ 1 X η et = (ms − φys + ηi∗s+1 − p∗s ). 1 + η s=t 1 + η (10.26) Hold i∗ , p∗ and y constant. Assume that m is fixed at m until time t. At time t therei s an unexpected, permanent contraction in the money supply. m falls to m0 . (a) What will be the effect to e and p? Illustrate. (b) What is the effect to inflation? Illustrate. (c) What is the effect to the interest rate? Illustrate. 5. In the Dornbusch model one assumes that prices are sticky. The PPP does no longer hold at every point of time, although it does hold in the long run. However, the UIP still holds. (a) Making the assumptions of the Dornbusch model, illustrate the effects to e, p and i of a contractionary shock to money supply. (b) Explain the term overshooting. Why does overshooting arise in this model? 6. What is a chartist? How does the behaviour of a chartist differ from the behaviour assumed in the monetary equilibrium model? 7. Read the enclosed article by J. Frankel and K. Froot. Explain the possible role of chartist during the appreciation of the USD from 1980 to 1985. 304 Lecture 8 Domestic investors are assumed to hold two types of assets: domestic currency, B, and foreign currency, F . Total real wealth, W , denominated in local currency will be B F + , P P W = (10.27) where is the exchange rate. The share of total wealth the investor chooses to hold in foreign currency is f= F . PW (10.28) We treat f as the the choice variable of the domestic investor. Given f , one can compute F = f P W and B = (1 − f )P W . Similar, foreign investors hold currency of the home country1 , B ∗ , and foreign currency, F ∗ . Total real wealth held by foreigners, W ∗ , denominated in foreign currency will be W∗ = B∗ F∗ + . P ∗ P ∗ (10.29) The share of total wealth the foreign investor chooses to hold in domestic currency is B∗ b = . P ∗ W ∗ ∗ (10.30) We treat b∗ as the the choice variable of foreign investors. Given b∗ , one can compute B ∗ = b∗ P ∗ W ∗ and F ∗ = (1 − b∗ )P ∗ W ∗ . Expected real return on the portfolio of a domestic investor will be 1 The home country is the same throughout the exercise—it is the country of the domestic investor, not the foreign investor. 305 given by · · · · · π = (1 − f )(i − p) + f (i∗ + e − p) = (1 − f )i + f (i∗ + e) − p, (10.31) · · where i is the interest rate, p=rate of inflation, e=rate of depreciation and ∗ denotes foreign values. Expected real return on the portfolio of a foreign investor will be given by · · · · · π = (1 − b∗ )(i∗ − p∗ ) + b∗ (i − e − p∗ ) = (1 − b∗ )i∗ + b∗ (i − e) − p∗ . (10.32) · We assume that p is a stochastic variable with the distribution · p ∼ N (µp , σ pp ). (10.33) µp is the expected mean of a change in inflation, and σ pp is the expected standard deviation around the mean. Similar, we assume that · p∗ ∼ N (µp∗ , σ p∗ p∗ ), (10.34) and · e ∼ N (µe , σ ee ). · (10.35) · The correlation between p and ee is σ ep , and the correlation between · · p∗ and ee is σ ep∗ . There is no uncertainty about the interest rate, as it is observable today. Last, define the risk premium, r as r = i − i∗ − µ e . 306 (10.36) 1. Investors maximise function of the form 1 U = E(π) − Rvar(π). 2 (10.37) We assume R to be the same for all investors. Find the optimal f and b∗ . 2. Explain the risks of holding a currency in this model. As you have found, f and b∗ can both be written as two terms: one that depends on r and one that does not depend on r. Give an interpretation of these two terms. Explain how a fall in r affects f and b∗ . What is the effect for currency flows? 3. In addition to domestic investors and foreigners there is a domestic central bank. The holdings of the central bank is denoted as B g and F g for domestic currency and foreign currency respectively. Explain why we must have that B g + B + B ∗ = 0, (10.38) F g + F + F ∗ = 0. (10.39) and 4. Start with the condition F g + F + F ∗ = 0. Insert your findings for F and F ∗ . Show that δF g >0 δ (10.40) if all investors have positive holdings of both currencies. 5. Draw a diagram with on the y-axis, and F g on the x-axis. Insert the equilibrium condition of F g using the assumption above. Explain how F g will change with a change in f , assuming 307 (a) a fixed exchange rate, and (b) a floating exchange rate. 6. Illustrate the effect of fall in r. Use three graphs: (a) first assume a fixed exchange rate, (b) second assume a floating exchange rate, (c) then assume that the rate is fixed until the foreign reserves reach a certain level F g . At this point the rate is allowed to float. Lecture 9 We are in a two-country world, where each country produce a single good. The home country produces good H, and the foreign country good F . Each good has the price of unity measured in the local currency. The relative price of the two goods, which is the same as the real exchange rate, Q, will be measured as the price of one unit of foreign good denominated in home currency, Q= PF . PH (10.41) A higher Q implies a real depreciation, a lower Q a real appreciation, seen from the home country. Total consumption in the home country of good H is CH , and total ∗ consumption of good F is CF . Foreign consumption is CH and CF∗ . Total production of the home country is Y = H, and total production of the foreign country is Y ∗ = F . The net capital inflow of the home country is B. B will equal the 308 negative of the current account, B = −CA, (10.42) as we have that the capital account=the current account, and a current account surplus must give a capital outflow. B reflects capital mobility. If B is zero, there is no capital mobility. Note that there might still be trade. However, the trade balance must always be zero. The rate of absorption, A, is the total consumption and investment in the home country. We assume no investment and no public sector. Absorption will then be given as A = C = Y − CA = Y + B. (10.43) Similarly, we have that A∗ = Y ∗ + B ∗ . (10.44) Notice that B∗ = −B , Q (10.45) as B ∗ is measured in foreign currency, and capital inflow in one country by definition must equal capital outflow in the other, as we have only two countries. There were some sources of confusion in the lecture held May 28. The questions bellow should help you to resolve these... 1. The following was stated in the Lecture on May 28: “We have two maximisation problems. For the home 309 country we have 1−m M ax U = CH (QCF )m s.t. A = Y + B = CH + QCF , (10.46) and for the foreign country ∗ M ax U = ∗ CH Q 1−m∗ ∗ (CF∗ )m s.t. A∗ = Y ∗ − B C∗ = H +CF∗ .00 Q Q (10.47) From these two maximisation problems we derived consumption functions. For the home country we found CH = (1 − m)(Y + B), CF = m Y +B , Q (10.48) and for the foreign country ∗ CH = Qm∗ (Y ∗ − B ), Q CF = (1 − m∗ )(Y ∗ − B ). Q (10.49) The four consumption functions are correct. However, the maximisation problem for the foreign consumers is not. Given the four consumption functions, make the necessary adjustment of the maximisation problem. 2. Given what you find above, is it reasonable to assume that 1 − m > m∗ ? (10.50) 3. Explain why m∗ Y ∗ = mY Q (10.51) will imply a trade balance of zero. 4. Using the consumption functions above, and the market clearing 310 clearing condition of ∗ CH + CH = Y, (10.52) and inserting the consumption functions, we derive the market clearing real exchange rate as Q= mY (1 − m − m∗ )B − . m∗ Y ∗ m∗ Y ∗ (10.53) Find the effect on Q of a change in Y ∗ . What does this imply for the welfare of the home country? Is a positive supply shock abroad good or bad for the home country? 5. We want to illustrate the effect of a temporary shock in Y , and how different capital flows affect Q differently. Use the equation for Q stated above. Assume Y ∗ = 20, m = 1/3 and m∗ = 1/3 in all periods. Ignore the existence of interest on debt. We look at 4 periods. In period 0 Y is 20, debt is zero, and the current account is zero. In period 1 output fall from 20 to 10. In period 2 output bounces back to 20, and remains constant in period 3 and 4. Note that the results are not in line with what was presented during the lecture... (a) Assume no capital flows. Illustrate the paths of Y , Q, A, B and total debt. (b) Assume that the country does not allow A to change in period 1. However debt accumulated in period 1 is to be repaid with equal amounts in period 2, 3 and 4. Illustrate the paths of Y , Q, A, B and total debt. 311 (c) Assume that the country adjusts absorption in period 1, but with the goal of having the same absorption in period 1, 2, 3 and 4. In the end of period 4 total debt should be zero. Illustrate the paths of Y , Q, A, B and total debt. Lecture 10 Solve the following problems: 1. Given Seignoraget = (1 − 1 )(1 + µ)−η = µ(1 + µ)−η−1 , 1+µ (10.54) find δSeignoraget . δµ (10.55) L = π 2 + b[(1 − σ)un + a(π e − π)]2 , (10.56) δL . δπ (10.57) 2. Given find 3. Given 1−m L = CH (QCF )m + λ (Y + B − CH − QCF ) , (10.58) find δL . δCF (10.59) 4. Given 1 U = (1−f )i+f (i∗ +µe )−µp − R f 2 σ ee + σ pp − 2f σ ep , (10.60) 2 312 find δU . δf (10.61) Other questions 1. The Barro-Gordon model (45 %) We can express the Phillips curve as u = un + a(π e − π). (10.62) Here u is the unemployment rate, un is the “non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment”, or NAIRU. π is the observed rate of inflation, and π e is the expected rate of inflation. If inflation exceeds expected inflation, the unemployment rate can for a short period be less than the NAIRU. However, one can not expect inflation to exceed expected inflation over time. We assume that the government has two policy goals: to keep inflation stable, and to keep unemployment low. In fact, the government has as a goal to keep unemployment at a level u∗ < un . We specifically assume that u∗ = σun , (10.63) where 0 < σ < 1. The government minimises a loss function, L, that contain these two elements: L = π 2 + b[u − u∗ ]2 , (10.64) where b (assumed to be > 0) is the weight on holding unemployment at u∗ . If we substitute in for the equations (11.85) and 313 (11.86), we obtain L = π 2 + b[(1 − σ)un + a(π e − π)]2 . (10.65) (a) Assume that the government set π = 0, and that this is fully credible—the public believes the government, so that π e = 0 as well. Show the loss of the government. (b) Assume that all agents are rational and have perfect foresight. Why can the government not achieve the loss in (1a)? What will be the actual rate of inflation in this economy? (c) Assume two countries have different values for b in their loss functions. Why would this create a credibility problem if the two countries tried to establish a fixed currency between them? 2. The Krugman model (45 %) Country A is a developing country with a long history of high inflation. The money demand is given on logarithmic form as mt − pt = −η(Et pt+1 − pt ), (10.66) where m is the log of the money supply, m = ln(M ), p is the log of the price level, and η is a parameter. Assume that PPP holds, so that the exchange rate on log-form, e, is given by et = pt − p∗t . (10.67) p∗ is the foreign price level. For simplicity we set p∗ = 0, and assume that foreign inflation is zero. If we assume perfect foresight, 314 and use continuous time notation, so that · et+1 − et = e, (10.68) we can write the money demand function as · mt − et = −η e. (10.69) Money supply, M , reflects the central bank asset sheet. The central bank has two main types of assets, foreign reserves and domestic government bonds. We can therefore write M as M = D + R, (10.70) where D is domestic bonds, and R is foreign reserves. The central bank will support a fixed exchange rate as long as R > 0. Three results: · – If the exchange rate is fixed at a level e = e, then e = 0, so we must have e = mt . (10.71) This implies that the money supply is fixed at a level mt = m. – If the money supply, M , grows at a fixed rate µ, the exchange rate is given as: et = mt + µη. (10.72) – Note that if a variable X grows at a given rate µ, the value of ln(Xt ) = xt can be stated as a function of the growth rate and the initial value of x: xt = x0 + µt. 315 (10.73) In the following we assume that the exchange rate is initially fixed. The exchange rate is fixed at e = e = m. We have that M = D0 + R0 . (10.74) (a) Assume that the central bank’s holdings of domestic government bonds, D, grows at a speed µ. If the exchange rate shall remain fixed, what must happen to the money supply? Which implication will this have for the level of foreign reserves, R? Why can this policy be described as “inconsistent”? (b) The “shadow exchange rate”, ee, is given as eet = dt + µη. (10.75) Explain the term “shadow exchange rate”. (c) According to the Krugman model a speculative attack will happen in the point T , when the fixed exchange rate equals the shadow exchange rate, or e = ee. Illustrate the paths of e and ee. Explain why a speculative attack must happen at T . (d) At p. 74 in “International Money”, in the discussion of the Krugman model, De Grauwe states: “The timing of the attack is independent of the stock of international reserves the authorities start with.” Find the expression for T . Comment on this statement. What is independent of the initial stock of reserves? (e) Illustrate the path of foreign reserves and the money supply. What happens to money supply at time T ? How much does 316 it change? Give an intuitive understanding of this result. (f) If the central bank increases its holdings of domestic bonds at a given rate, what might that tell you about fiscal policy in this country? Assume that the government is following the policy described above. However, the central bank is not increasing its holdings of domestic bonds. Instead the government is borrowing money abroad. Would this make a difference for the results in our model? Discuss consequences of the different strategies. 3. High volume—Is it a puzzle? (10 %) The daily volume in the FX spot market in April 1998 was 600 billion USD. As a comparison, the daily volume in the New York Stock Exchange in this period was 30 billion USD, and average daily world trade in goods and services was about 15 billion USD. Given your knowledge of how the FX-market works, discuss these fact. What features of the FX market might explain the high volume of the FX-market compared to other markets? 317 Chapter 11 Solutions Lecture 1 1. Gresham’s law (a) Question Gresham’s law states that bad money always will drive good money out of circulation. People will choose to use the bad money for transactions, and store the good money. Explain why. Solution The point here is that one asset (here currency) has different value depending on how it is used. Assume that the currency is in the form of gold coins. When this currency is used for transactions one unit has a value set by the price level. However, at the same time the coins has a commodity value equal to its weight in gold. The value of a coin as a commodity depends on the gold content of the coin. The value of a coin as a means of transaction only depends on the denomination of the coin. If you have two coins with the same denomination, but different gold contents, you will store the one with more gold. The one with 318 less gold you will use for transactions. If more bad coins are introduced, these will be used for transactions, and the good coins will be stored—bad money drive out good money. (b) Question Assume a system where two types of coins circulate in the economy. Some coins are of silver, and some coins are of gold. Discuss possible problems that can arise in such a system if there is discovered a huge deposit of silver. Will silver or gold coins dominate circulation? Will silver or gold dominate as a store of value? Solution If supply of silver rise, the value of silver must be expected to fall. If the relationship between the transaction value of a silver and a gold coin is fixed, silver is now the bad coin and gold is the good coin. Silver will drive gold out of circulation, as people store gold and use silver. Over time the relationship between the value of a silver and gold coin must be readjusted if a two metal standard is to be reintroduced. (c) Question Assume that one has a currency that is backed by a two-metal standard. Assume that for 35 units of currency one can claim 1 ounce of gold or 35 ounces of silver at the central bank. Assume gold supply increases three-fold, while supply of silver remains constant. How will this affect the central banks holdings of gold and silver? Will this currency be “stable”? Solution In the short-term the exchange ratio in the central bank remains fixed. However, an increase in the supply of gold would lead to fall in the relative price of gold to silver in the commodity markets. So people will bring their paper 319 money to the central bank to get silver in return, take this silver abroad and exchange it to gold, and return home and exchange gold into currency at the central bank. This form of arbitrage could return a handsome profit. This is in effect a “silver-run” on the central bank. One should expect the central bank to lose all its silver within a relatively short period of time. At this point the central bank must either change the exchange ratios, or convert to a unilateral gold standard. Bilateral currency standards was introduced because central banks did not have enough gold, and needed a wider basis for backing of a sufficient money supply. However, as long as there is a risk of large swings in the relative value of the two metals, such an arrangement must either be flexible—i.e. the exchange ratios must be frequently adjusted, or the system will be prone to currency runs. 2. Fiat money and free banking... (a) Question Assume that the Norwegian government allows everyone to print Norwegian kroner on their own colour printers. What would do you think would happen to the Norwegian money supply? What will happen to the Norwegian price level? Solution The cost of printing notes on a printer is close to zero. Everyone would expect that everyone else prints as much as he or she can, so everyone will print as much as he or she can as well. This can be illustrated by a simple game theoretic approach (try to use the prisoners dilemma). The solution is 320 evidently not welfare improving. (b) At the islands Yap in the Pacific Ocean people used large, heavy round stones with a hole in the middle as currency. One stone took two men approximately one week to make. These stones worked as both unit of account, means of payment and store of value. However, as they were difficult to carry, the islanders did not care to carry them around. Instead they issued legal titles to the stones. These legal titles were used for trading. Note that the stones only had value as currency. They had no value as a commodity. i. Question What is the difference between the stones on Yap and the ability to print your own money? Solution At Yap it took one week of labour to get the new note finished. There was real cost of producing currency. ii. Question Explain the fact that inflation on Yap was stable. Solution People would produce “currency stones” to the point where the marginal return of producing one was equal to the alternative value of labour. If the productivity growth in the rest of the economy is the same as the increase in the ability to produce stones, people would continue to produce the same ratio of stones to the economy as a whole. iii. Question What would happen to the price level on Yap if the islanders got a new technology that would reduce the time to make a new stone from one week to one day? 321 Should this have any effects for the real economy on Yap? Solution If productivity in producing stones increased dramatically, it would be reasonable to produce a lot more stones. This would induce inflation. The value of all stones would fall. People who had all their assets in “stones” would no longer be so rich, while people who had “stone debts” could no repay these debts with a fraction of the labour. If contracts are stated in nominal terms (contracts are stated as the number of stones owed, not as the number of stones owed as a fraction of the price level) money will not be neutral in this system. 3. Seignorage (a) Question Seignorage is given by Seignoraget = Mt − Mt−1 . Pt (11.1) We know that real money demand can be written as Mt = Et Pt Pt+1 Pt −η . (11.2) Assume perfect foresight. Further, assume that the central bank can commit to a fixed rate of money growth for all future, µ, so that Mt = 1 + µ. Mt−1 (11.3) Use this information to show that the rate of money growth, µopt , that will maximise seignorage revenue is equal to η1 . Solution The following list of equations go through the whole 322 derivation: St = Mt − Mt−1 Pt Mt − Mt−1 Mt Mt Pt −η Mt Pt+1 = Pt Pt −η Mt − Mt−1 Pt+1 St = Mt Pt −η Mt−1 Pt+1 St = 1 − Mt Pt St = Mt Pt =1+µ= Mt−1 Pt−1 1 St = 1 − (1 + µ)−η 1+µ µ St = (1 + µ)−η 1+µ St = µ (1 + µ)−1 (1 + µ)−η St = µ (1 + µ)−η−1 ∂St = (1 + µ)−η−1 + µ (−η − 1) (1 + µ)−η−2 = 0 ∂µ µ (η + 1) (1 + µ)−η−2 =0 1− (1 + µ)−η−1 1 − µ (η + 1) (1 + µ)−1 = 0 (1 + µ) − (µη + µ) = 0 1 − µη = 0 µ= 1 η (b) Question Average growth in Norwegian M1 over the period from December 1992 to January 2002 has been 9.48 per cent 323 on a yearly basis. Assume that Norges Bank behaves according to the rule of optimal seignorage. Find η. Solution η = 1 µ ⇒η= 1 0.0948 = 10.55 (c) Question Assuming constant money growth, the formula for seignorage can be written Seignoraget = µ(1 + µ)−η−1 . (11.4) Calculate seignorage for Norway. Solution Seignoraget = µ(1+µ)−η−1 = 0.0948(1+0.0948)−10.55−1 = 0.0333 (d) Question We want to find seignorage as a percentage of public expenditure. Note that in equation (11.4) seignorage is measured as a fraction of the price level. For our purposes it is reasonable to approximate the price level with the money stock in the last period. In January 2002 Norwegian M1 was 382.6 billion NOK. The public expenditure for 2001 was expected to be 487.9 billion NOK. Calculate seignorage as a percentage of government expenditure for Norway. Compare your number with the numbers in Box 8.1 in Obstfeld and Rogoff, ch. 8.2. Solution Seigniorage as per cent of public expenditure: St · M 1t 0.0333 · 382.6 = = 0.0261. P ublic expenditure 487.9 (11.5) Our estimate is that seignorage amounts to 2.61 per cent of public expenditure in Norway. As one can see from Box 8.1 in Obstfeld and Rogoff this is in line with estimates for other industrialised countries. 324 Lecture 2 1. Given the data given in the exercise, compute the values of the money supply and the monetary base. Solution: Money supply: 9750, money base: 900 2. Next, assume that the Argentinean real exchange rate appreciates vis-a-vis USD. Provide one or two sentences to say what this means. This question should be answered abstractly, without references to the above data. Your answer should be expressed in intuitive terms, using plain, jargon-free language. 3. Now suppose that, because of the ARP real appreciation, an Argentinean importer wants to import some U.S. goods. Specifically, she wants to import 18 dollars worth of machines. This means that she needs to obtain USD 18. (a) First, suppose the importer goes to her commercial bank and asks for USD 18. The commercial bank turns to a trader in an American bank, and asks him to sell it USD 18 in return for ARP 18. Assume the trade goes through, and the importer receives USD 18 from its bank in return for ARP 18. What is the effect on the Argentinean monetary base? Solution: This transactions does not involve the currency board. The money base is not affected. (b) Second, suppose that, because of the overvaluation, the trader at the American bank will not sell USD for ARP at 1:1. He might sell each USD for 1.2 ARP, but if he did then the fixed exchange rate would have de facto collapsed. The good news for the Argentinean importer is that the currency board is 325 obliged to sell her USD at 1:1. The commercial bank will trade ARP 18 for USD 18 by sending a request to the currency board. What is the currency board supposed to do with the pesos it receives for these USD? If the currency board does this, what is the effect on the Argentinean monetary base? Solution: The currency board is supposed to burn the ARPs it receive. To keep the balance sheet in balance, the amount of ARP issued must match the reserve holdings of USD. If reserves are reduced with 18, the amount of money issued must be reduced by 18. (c) According to the quantity theory of money, money (M ) times the number of transactions conducted with money (velocity, V ) should equal the price level, P , times the number of transactions in the economy, T , or M · V = P · T. (11.6) We can simplify by assuming that velocity is constant, and that T can be set equal to to total production in the economy, Y. Do you think the actions by the currency board described above will alleviate the overvaluation of the Argentinean peso? Why? Solution: According to the QTM a contraction of the money base should lead to lower prices. It the Argentinean price level falls, the real exchange rate of Argentina devalues. This will alleviate the overvaluation. 326 (d) What will happen if, for some reason, this process continues? That is, what will happen if Argentineans try to convert all their ARP-denominated bank deposits into USD? Solution: If the process continues, the currency board will run out of USD. At this point Argentina must either float the peso or impose capital controls. If the process continues further the banks will collapse. The reason is that the holdings of the currency board only back-up the currency, not the entire monetary supply. 4. Given the transaction by the Argentinean importer, what will happen to the Argentinean current account once this transaction occurs? Will there be change in the direction of trade flows? How will capital flows be affected? Solution: If the overvaluation in Argentina is alleviated, Argentine goods become more attractive in foreign markets, and foreign goods less attractive in Argentina. The Argentinean trade deficit will be reduced. Capital flows that are necessary to finance the trade deficit will abate. 5. Once the Argentinean importer has obtained the USD 18, you should find that the system of balance sheets are no longer ‘in equilibrium’. That is, the two ratios discussed above are no longer 12 and 60. Use the four linear equations described in the appendix to compute the new equilibrium. What is the new money supply? Is this new value for the money supply consistent with alleviating the overvaluation problem? 327 Solution: The four equations can be expressed as: C = 60H 12 + 60 R = H −C L = (60 − 1)R D = 12C. H is given as 900 − 18 = 882. We then find that C = 735 R = 147 L = 8673 D = 8820. The new money supply will be 9555, which is less than 9750. This is consistent with alleviating the overvaluation. The money supply has decreased, which will decrease prices and make the real value of ARP fall. The economics behind this might go as follows. Upon seeing reserves fall below a safe level, commercial banks start to call in loans. This causes interest rates to rise. The increase in interest 328 rates induces a fall in the level of economic activity and a drop in national income. The latter reduces the demand for goods, as well as money, thereby pushing the domestic price level down. The reduction in domestic demand, in addition to the depreciation of the real exchange rate, tends to push the current account balance toward surplus. 6. The money multiplier is defined as the ratio of the reduction in the money supply to the reduction in the monetary base. The money multiplier tells us how fast the supply of money grows if another unit of monetary base is created. What is the money multiplier here? If the central bank prints one more piece of currency, how much will the total money supply grow, and therefore how much will the price level increase (if V and Y is constant)? Solution: The money multiplier is 9750 − 9555 = 10.83 18 (11.7) The important point in the example above is to show that a currency board has a ‘self-correcting’ aspect to it. Excessive inflation (relative to the reserve country) and/or real exchange rate overvaluation should be corrected if the currency board does what it is supposed to do. In addition, the example points out that a county with a currency board has effectively given up any sort of active monetary policy. Monetary policy becomes a currency printing/burning robot. 329 Lecture 3 1. Question What do we mean with the n-1 problem in a multilateral exchange rate system? Solution The n-1 problem relates to the fact that when two currencies have a fixed exchange rate, the ratio of the money supplies in the two countries is fixed. Two currencies and one exchange rate implies one monetary policy. If the money supply of one country changes, the money supply of the other country must change as well. In a multilateral exchange rate agreements all countries must agree on changes in the money supply. If two countries disagree about the optimal money supply, the system can not survive unless one of the parties is willing to compromise. 2. Question Assume that the UIP holds. Use the n-1 problem to illustrate the strains put on the EMS-system by the German unification. Solution See De Grauwe, ch. 2.2. The German contraction of the money supply lead to a reduced demand for e.g. the French franc. The “market rate” of DEM appreciated, and the “market rate” of the FRF depreciated. To assure that the system was held within the established target zone either Germany had to increase its money supply or France had to reduce its money supply. In the early 1990’s the Bundesbank’s policy clearly did not fit several of the other countries in the EMS. The system got a credibility problem. The countries with a weak commitment to fix their rates within the EMS left the system in 1992. However, France never 330 Figure 11.1: Money supply shock in Germany... DEM/ECU DDEM So DEM S1 DEM M DEM The Bundesbank contracted the German money supply to contain inflationary pressure. 331 Figure 11.2: And the consequences for France FRF/ECU D1 FRF D0 FRF SFRF M FRF A money supply shock in Germany decreased demand for FRF. To hold the exchange rate within the target zone France needed to contract their money supply as well. 332 Figure 11.3: A change in the target zone DEM/ECU DDEM New zone So DEM S1 DEM M DEM A change in the target zone would have allowed the Bundesbank to contract the German money supply without putting strains on the fixed exchange rate. devalued its exchange rate. It was forced to widen the target zone of exchange rate fluctuations in 1993, however. 3. Question In a meeting in 1991 Germany suggested to revalue the DEM inside the EMS system (increase the value of DEM relative to the other currencies in the system). Could this have alleviated the strains on the system? Solution A German appreciation would have shifted the target zone up in the case of France, and down in the case of Germany. This would have allowed Germany to decrease its money supply without affecting the money supply of France. 4. Question France vetoed the German suggestion. Why would the French do this? 333 Solution Some possible arguments: – France believed that the fixed exchange rate was an important symbol for European integration. Changing the rate could endanger the credibility of the system. – France probably wanted to put pressure on Germany to compromise. After all the EMS was a multilateral agreement, and it was problematic that the Bundesbank acted without regard to common European goals. – It was not clear that the FRF was overvalued. In fact the FRF remained relatively stable against the DEM over the period from 1990 to 1998. A de facto devaluation of the FRF could have lead to increased inflation in France. Lecture 4 1. Assume the PPP to hold, i.e. et = pt − p∗t , (11.8) where et is the exchange rate in period t, and p∗ is the foreign price level. Assume that the foreign price level is fixed at p∗ = 0, and that foreign inflation, π ∗ , is zero. Discuss the relationship between domestic inflation, π, and the depreciation of the exchange rate, · e, under these assumptions. · Solution If p∗ = 0 ⇒ et = pt , so we must have that e = π. 2. We assume that the government focuses on the exchange rate instead of the price level. Give some arguments for why a government could choose to focus monetary policy on a stable exchange 334 rate instead of controlling the money supply. Solution By focusing on the exchange rate the government can achieve a number of things: – In a fixed exchange rate regime money growth will be determined by factors outside the central bank. This might increase credibility in monetary policy. – Unlike e.g. an inflation target, where the results of current monetary policy can first be observed after some time, an exchange rate is immediately observable in the market. – A stable exchange rate might have positive implications for trade. 3. Assume that the exchange rate is fixed, so that et = e. This · implies that e = 0. If the government adjusts the fixed rate this will have the cost of C. As long as the regime is fixed at et = e, C = 0. If the rate is adjusted, C > 0. The loss function can now be written as ·2 ·e · · L = e + b[(1 − σ)un + a(e − e)]2 + C e, (11.9) ·e where e is expected depreciation. Explain why C might be positive. Solution By adjusting the exchange rate the government might indicate that it is not really committed to a fixed rate. There might arise doubts about future monetary policy—i.e. the government loose credibility. One result might be higher interest rates in the future, as the markets no longer trust the fixed exchange rate. 335 4. Assume that the fixed exchange rate is credible and the government does not adjust the exchange rate. Calculate the loss of the government. ·e · Solution Here we have that e = 0 and e = 0. So L = b[(1 − σ)un ]2 . (11.10) 5. Assume that the fixed exchange rate is credible. Discuss under which circumstances the government might have incentive to change the exchange rate. What is the role of C? Solution The rate of depreciation that minimises the government loss will be given by δL · δe ·e · · = 2e − 2ab[(1 − σ)un + a(e − e)] + C = 0. (11.11) This gives us an optimal policy of ·e · opt ab(1 − σ)un ba2 e C = + − . 2 2 1 + ba 1 + ba 1 + ba2 ·e · e (11.12) I this case e = 0. It will only be optimal to set e > 0 if ab(1 − σ)un > C. (11.13) The cost of adjusting the rate increases the credibility of the regime. 6. Assume that the fixed exchange rate is not credible. Assume the market expects the government to devalue the exchange rate, i.e. ·e assume e > 0. How would this affect optimal government policy? Solution In this case it would be optimal to change the exchange 336 rate if ·e ab(1 − σ)un + ba2 e > C. (11.14) Notice that in this case the left hand side is notably larger, as ·e ab(1 − σ)un + ba2 e > ab(1 − σ)un . (11.15) In words: the probability of devaluation being the optimal policy has increased. 7. In the light of the above results, discuss the term “self-fulfilling” speculative attacks. Solution (Very short) The implication of the above results is that the cost of devaluing depends on market expectations. If the market expects a devaluation, this makes a devaluation a less costly policy option. Lecture 5 1. The Krugman model (a) If domestic credit grows at a speed µ and the exchange rate shall remain fixed, what must happen to the money supply? Which implication will this have for the level of foreign reserves, R? Assume that domestic credit grows by 20 per cent a year, so that µ = 0.2. Assume that initial domestic credit is D0 = 10 and initial foreign reserves are R0 = 90. At what time will R = 0 if this policy is not changes? Solution If the exchange rate shall remain fixed, the money supply must remain equal to M . This implies that an absolute 337 increase in domestic credit must be reflected by an absolute fall in foreign reserves. We have that M0 = 90 + 10 = 100. So when D = 100, R must by definition be zero. When is D = 100? ln(100) = ln(10) + 0.2 · t ⇒ t = 11.5. (11.16) With this policy foreign reserves will be zero in 11.5 years. (b) If we use the above model, and assume money supply growth at a fixed rate µ, we find the following expression for the exchange rate: et = mt + µη. (11.17) The “shadow exchange rate”, ee, is defined as the exchange rate that would have been the actual exchange rate if a speculative attack had already happened. Assume that the government continues the policy of fixed growth in domestic credit forever. Identify the shadow exchange rate given our definition of M . Solution After a speculative attack foreign reserves goes to zero. So the money supply will only consist of domestic credit. We obtain eet = dt + µη = d0 + µt + µη. (11.18) (c) According to the Krugman model a speculative attack will happen in the point T , when the fixed exchange rate equals the shadow exchange rate, or e = ee. Illustrate the paths of e and ee. Explain why a speculative attack must happen at T . Solution Assume that the fixed exchange rate equals the shadow rate at time T . Let the fixed exchange rate collapses 338 Figure 11.4: Fixed vs. shadow rate log exchange rate T Shadow floating rate Fixed rate log money supply time at a T + 2. In this case the shadow rate will exceed the fixed rate. The fixed rate is terminated at this point, the exchange rate must make a jump from e to ee. A discrete jump in the exchange rate will imply infinite profit opportunities for rational speculators. As everyone have perfect foresight, everyone will try to sell the domestic currency at time T + 1. Hence, the speculative attack will take place at T + 1. However, at T + 1 the jump will still be discrete. So everyone will sell at T . Why not sell at T − 1? Simply because one would lose money by doing so. If everyone sell at T − 1 the exchange rate actually will appreciate, as the shadow rate at this time is lower than the fixed rate. time log foreign reserves (d) Assume that η = 2. Find T . 339 Level of foreign reserves at time of attack Solution We have that by definition e = ln(M ) = ln(D0 + R0 ). At T we have that e = ln(D0 + R0 ) = d0 + µT + µη. (11.19) We insert the information above to obtain ln(10 + 90) = ln(10) + 0.2 · T + 0.2 · 2. (11.20) We can then find T as T = ln(D0 + R0 ) − d0 − µη ln(10 + 90) − ln(10) − 0.2 · 2 = = 9.5. µ 0.2 (11.21) The fixed exchange rate will collapse after 9.5 years of this policy, 2 years before the foreign reserves would have been empty without a speculative attack. 2. Tobin tax (a) Assume that the cost of speculation is 1. Calculate the profit of each trader if he sells and the other holds, and if he holds and the other sells, and if both hold and both sell for all three states of the economy. Organise your findings in three two by two matrixes. Identify Nash equilibria for all three cases. Solution The following three illustration give the results in the three cases. We have one Nash equilibrium (hold, hold) in the case if output is high, and two equilibria [(hold, hold) and (sell, sell)] in the case if output is low or intermediate. (b) Discuss the consequence of an increase in the cost of speculation from 1 to 1.5. Will any of the above Nash equilibria change? 340 Figure 11.5: High output Trader 1 Hold Sell Hold 0,0 0,-1 Sell -1,0 -1,-1 Trader 2 341 Figure 11.6: Intermediate output Trader 1 Hold Sell Hold 0,0 0,-1 Sell -1,0 1/4,1/4 Trader 2 342 Figure 11.7: Low output Trader 1 Hold Sell Hold 0,0 0,-1 Sell -1,0 3/2,3/2 Trader 2 343 Solution The Nash equilibrium will change in the intermediate case. We move from two equilibria to one equilibrium with (hold, hold). This increases the ability of the government to hold the exchange rate stable over the business cycle. (c) Discuss whether or not this is a good argument for introducing a Tobin tax. Solution Increasing the cost of speculation might reduce the willingness of speculators to take speculative positions. However, there are some problems: – To avoid speculation when investors expect a substantial change in the exchange rate would imply that one needs a very high tax. The higher the tax, the more stability the tax will provide. However, the higher the tax, the higher the potential problems of such a tax. It is not certain that the cost of high tax can justify the potential stability introduced by such a tax. – A tax in only one country could lead to capital flight from this country. – With the use of financial derivatives speculators can use other financial markets to do much of the same as they do in the FX market. It is very difficult to have such control over the financial markets that “tax avoidance” can be efficiently stopped. 344 Lecture 6 1. Assuming no transaction costs, suppose GBP=USD 2.4110 in New York, USD=FRF 3.997 in Paris, and FRF=GBP 0.1088 in London. How could you take advantage of these rates? Solution Assume the two dollar rates to be “correct”. Then the GBP/FRF rate should be 1 GBP/U SD 2.4110 GBP/F RF = = = 0.10377 6= 0.01088. F RF/U SD 3.997 (11.22) ⇒ The FRF is expensive in London. Triangular arbitrage does not hold. Strategy: use FRF 1,000,000 to buy GBP in London. ⇒ obtain GBP 108,800. sell GBP 108,800 in New York ⇒ obtain USD 262319. sell USD 262319 in Paris ⇒ obtain FRF 1048480. ⇒ Profit=FRF 48480. 2. The media frequently report that ”the dollar’s value strengthened against many currencies in response to the Federal Reserve’s plan to increase interest rates.” Explain why the dollar’s value is expected to appreciate, and why the rate may change even before the Fed affects interest rates. Solution Higher interest rates means a monetary contraction. According to the monetary equilibrium model a monetary contraction should lead to an appreciation of the exchange rate, as money supply, m, fall. According to the Dornbusch model we should expect a monetary contraction to lead to an immediate 345 appreciation, followed by a depreciation. If the Federal Reserve signals a change in interest rates, investors will update their expectations. As we have seen in the monetary equilibrium model, the exchange rate depends on expectations of the future values of fundamental variables. new information should immediately be incorporated in the exchange rate, even before the change has come into effect. 3. The following quotations are available to you. (You may either buy or sell at the stated rates.) Hong Kong Shanghai Bank: FRF/USD=4.8600 Dredsner Bank: DEM/USD=1.4200 Banque National de Paris: FRF/DEM=3.4400 Assume that you have an initial USD 1,000,000. Is triangular arbitrage possible? If so, explain the steps and compute your profit. Solution The cross rates from Dresdner and BNP implies a FRF/USD of F RF/U SD = F RF/U SD 4.8600 = = 4.8848 6= 4.8600. 1 U SD/DEM 1.4200 (11.23) You should find that by investing FRF 100 you can make a profit of FRF 0.51029. 4. You plan to spend one month at the luxurious Nusa Dua Hotel in Bali, Indonesia, a year from now. The present charge for a suitable suite plus meals is Rps 28,800 per night or USD 800 at the present exchange rate of INR/USD 36. (a) The Nusa Dua Hotel tells you that next year’s charges will 346 increase with Indonesian inflation, which you expect to be 16 per cent. U.S. inflation is currently 4 per cent per annum. You believe implicitly in the theory of purchasing power parity. How many U.S. dollars will you need one year hence to pay for your 30-day vacation? Solution 800U SD · (1 + 1.04) · 30 = 24, 960U SD (11.24) (b) The forward rate on a one year contract is INR/USD=40. How many dollars do you need one year hence if you enter into a forward contract today? Solution In one year you need 28, 800 · (1 + 0.16) · 30 = 1, 002, 240IN R (11.25) If the forward contract is at 40 INR= 1 USD, you need 1, 002, 240 = 25, 056U SD 40 (11.26) in one year. (c) On a one year instrument, the US rate of interest is 8 per cent. What is the rate of interest on a similar instrument in Indonesia? Solution If you use numbers from (b): F = 1+i 1 + i∗ ⇒i=1− 40 · 1 + 0.08 = 0.2. 36 (11.27) 5. The United States and France both produce Cabernet Sauvignon wine. A bottle of Cabernet Sauvignon sell in the United States 347 for USD 18. An equivalent bottle sells in France for FRF 100. (a) According to purchasing power parity, what should be the U.S. dollar/French franc spot rate of exchange? Solution = 100F RF 18U SD ⇒ 1U SD = 5.5556F RF. (11.28) (b) Suppose the price of Cabernet Sauvignon in the US is expected to rise to USD 20 over the next year, while the price of a comparable bottle of French wine is expected to rise to FRF 118. What should be the one-year forward U.S. dollar/French franc exchange rate? Solution F = 118F RF 20U SD ⇒ 1U SD = 5.90F RF. (11.29) (c) Given your answers to (a) and (b) above, and given that the current interest rate in the United States is 6 per cent for notes of one-year maturity, what would you expect current French interest rates to be? Solution 5.90 = 5.5556 1+i 1 + 0.06 ⇒ i = 0.1257. (11.30) 6. Suppose today’s spot exchange rate is USD/DEM=0.51. The sixmonth interest rates on dollars and DM are 13 per cent and 6 per cent respectively. The six-month forward rate is USD/DEM=0.5273. A foreign exchange advisory service has predicted that the DEM will appreciate to USD/DEM=0.54 within six months. 348 (a) How would you use forward contracts to profit in the above situation? Solution A forward contract implies that you get a certain amount of currency at some time in the future. You will pay the contract at delivery. If you buy 100 DEM at the current forward rate, you will have to have to pay out 100 · 0.5273 = 52.73 U SD in 6 months. However, if the advisory is correct, in 6 months 100 DEM will give 54.00 USD. How to make a profit? Assume that the spot rate in 6 months really will be 0.54. Contract to sell 52.73 USD in 6 months. You get 100 DEM. Exchange these back to USD at the spot rate. You will now hold 54.00 USD. Profit equals 54.00-52.73=1.27 USD. (b) How would you use borrowing and lending transactions to profit? Solution Assume the spot rate in 6 moths will actually be 0.54. Borrow 51 USD at 13 per cent today. In six months you will have to repay 54.32 USD. Exchange to DEM at current rate, obtain 100 DEM. Invest in Germany at 6 percent for 6 months, in 6 months you obtain 103. Exchange back at the rate USD/DEM=0.54. You will get 103 ∗ 0.54 = 55.62. Profit will be 55.62 − 54.32 = 1.30 U SD. 7. In the 1950s and 1960s many influential economists like Milton Friedman and Harry Johnson were in favour of floating exchange rates. Johnson argued that floating exchange rates normally would ”move only slowly and fairly predictably.” (a) Explain the reasoning behind such a statement. 349 Solution The market knows better than governments what is the true value of the currency. Speculation would be stabilising rather than destabilising. A speculator who increased the magnitude of exchange rate fluctuations could only do so by buying high and selling low, which is a recipe for going out of business rather quickly. (b) With the benefit of hindsight we know that exchange rate fluctuations have been anything but slow and predictable, at least in the short run. Explain. Solution Lecture 6 discusses a number of avenues to understanding this “puzzle”. In fact, there is no good answer. Lecture 7 The starting point of the monetary equilibrium model is the real money demand function, given as mt − pt = −ηit+1 + φyt . (11.31) From this we can derive an expression for the price level, given as s−t T ∞ η η 1 X (ms − φys + ηis+1 ) + lim pt+T . pt = T →∞ 1 + η s=t 1 + η 1+η (11.32) If we assume PPP and UIP to hold at all times, and we assume perfect foresight, we can obtain an expression for the the exchange rate: s−t T ∞ 1 X η η ∗ ∗ et = (ms −φys +ηis+1 −ps )+ lim et+T . T →∞ 1 + η s=t 1 + η 1+η (11.33) 350 1. Define the real exchange rate, Q. What assumption do we make about the real exchange rate when we assume PPP to hold? Solution P∗ Q= . P (11.34) where is the actual level of the exchange rate, P is the domestic price level and P ∗ is the foreign price level. On logs this is equivalent to q = e + p∗ − p. (11.35) In the PPP we assume that = P . P∗ (11.36) To exact, this is the absolute PPP. The implication of the absolute PPP must be that Q = 1, or that the log of Q, q, equal 0. 2. Write the assumptions of the uncovered interest rate parity in mathematical terms. Explain the intuitive argument behind the UIP. If the PPP holds at all times, and expected depreciation is zero, what are the implications for the relationship between domestic and foreign interest rates? Solution Et t+1 1 + it = , t 1 + i∗t (11.37) Et et+1 − et = it − i∗t . (11.38) or on log form as The argument behind the UIP is that expected returns in two similar assets should be the same. The expected uncovered return of investing in foreign assets should equal the return of investing 351 in a similar domestic asset. If expected depreciation is zero, we must have i = i∗ at all times. 3. Both equation (11.42) and (11.43) contain two elements. The last element is on the form lim T →∞ η 1+η T et+T . (11.39) et+T 6= 0? (11.40) (a) What is the implication if lim T →∞ η 1+η T Solution If the term is not zero, the value of (in this case e) will diverge from the value implied by “fundamentals”, y, i∗ , p∗ and m. (b) Explain the term “rational bubbles”. Solution If the timing of the crash of the bubble is uncertain, a bubble can exist even if everyone knows it is a bubble. If we expect prices to rise in this period, and the next period, and the period after that, we can make money by buying the asset today. But doing so, we just fuel the bubble—the more people who buy the asset, the more do prices rise. In fact everyone find it profitable to let the bubble exist—although everyone knows that a some time in the future the prices need to revert to a lower level. “Rational bubbles” are models where the there is much uncertainty about when the bubble will collapse. 352 (c) One often assumes that lim T →∞ η 1+η T et+T = 0. (11.41) Explain why this is reasonable. Discuss. Solution If we assume perfect foresight, as we have done above, it does seem unreasonable to think that we do not know when a bubble will end. In other words a bubble can not exist. However, under less strict assumptions about foresight, it is less certain whether the assumption of no bubbles will hold. In the end this is a question about how we believe expectations to be formed. 4. Assume that the price level is given by s−t ∞ η 1 X (ms − φys + ηis+1 ), pt = 1 + η s=t 1 + η (11.42) and that the exchange rate is given by s−t ∞ 1 X η (ms − φys + ηi∗s+1 − p∗s ). et = 1 + η s=t 1 + η (11.43) Hold i∗ , p∗ and y constant. Assume that m is fixed at m until time t. At time t therei s an unexpected, permanent contraction in the money supply. m falls to m0 . (a) What will be the effect to e and p? Illustrate. Solution See figure 11.8. (b) What is the effect to inflation? Illustrate. Solution There is of course no inflation before and after the event—m is supposed to be stable in both periods. There will be deflationary blip in period t. 353 Figure 11.8: The equilibrium model vs. the disequilibrium model e t time p t time i t time The whole lines give the solution to an unexpected negative monetary shock in the monetary equilibrium model. This is as discussed in lecture 1 and 2. The dashed lines give the movements of e, p and i as is expected in the 354 Dornbusch model. (c) What is the effect to the interest rate? Illustrate. Solution See figure 11.8. 5. In the Dornbusch model one assumes that prices are sticky. The PPP does no longer hold at every point of time, although it does hold in the long run. However, the UIP still holds. (a) Making the assumptions of the Dornbusch model, illustrate the effects to e, p and i of a contractionary shock to money supply. Solution See figure 11.8. (b) Explain the term overshooting. Why does overshooting arise in this model? Solution The UIP states that 1 + it Et t+1 = . t 1 + i∗t (11.44) We know the long term value of e. We know that i will rise above i∗ in the period of the contractionary shock, and move back to i∗ over time. We further know that e will fall in the period of the shock. If e falls to the long term value of e, there will be no appreciation over time, and UIP will not hold. So must fall bellow the long term value of e. This is overshooting. 6. What is a chartist? How does the behaviour of a chartist differ from the behaviour assumed in the monetary equilibrium model? Solution A chartist is an investor who bases his investment strategy on historic movements in the asset price. In the equilibrium model we assume that all historic information is incorporated in the current price, and that only new information can change this 355 price. In the equilibrium model past prices should tell nothing about future price movements. 7. Read the enclosed article by J. Frankel and K. Froot. Explain the possible role of chartist during the appreciation of the USD from 1980 to 1985. Lecture 8 1. Investors maximise function of the form 1 U = E(π) − Rvar(π). 2 (11.45) We assume R to be the same for all investors. Find the optimal f and b∗ . Solution Domestic investors will maximise a function on the form 1 U = (1−f )i+f (i∗ +µe )−µp − R f 2 σ ee + σ pp − 2f σ ep . (11.46) 2 We optimse with regard to f , and obtain δU 1 = −i + (i∗ + µe ) − R [2f σ ee − 2σ ep ] = 0. δf 2 (11.47) Solving (11.84) for f leaves us with f= σ ep 1 + (i∗ + µe − i). σ ee Rσ ee (11.48) If we substitute in for r we have f= σ ep r − . σ ee Rσ ee 356 (11.49) Foreign investors will maximise a function on the form 1 U = (1 − b∗ )i∗ + b∗ (i − µe ) − µp∗ − R [b∗ 2σ ee + σ p∗ p∗ + 2b∗ σ ep∗ ] . 2 (11.50) We optimse with regard to b∗ , and obtain δU 1 = −i∗ + (i − µe ) − R [2f σ ee + 2σ ep∗ ] = 0. ∗ δb 2 (11.51) Solving (11.51) for b∗ leaves us with b∗ = − σ ep∗ 1 − (i∗ + µe − i). σ ee Rσ ee (11.52) If we substitute in for r we have b∗ = − σ ep∗ r + . σ ee Rσ ee (11.53) 2. Explain the risks of holding a currency in this model. As you have found, f and b∗ can both be written as two terms: one that depends on r and one that does not depend on r. Give an interpretation of these two terms. Explain how a fall in r affects f and b∗ . What is the effect for currency flows? Solution The risk of holding currency is the risk of inflation. If inflation rise, the currency will lose value. The investor wants to invest in foreign currency to hedge against inflation risk, and to earn money on differences in return, reflected by the risk premium. The term that does not depend on r is the minimum variance portfolio. This gives the share of holdings of foreign (in the case of domestic investors) or domestic (in the case of foreign investors) currency that minimises the risk of inflation to the currency holdings. 357 The term that does depend on r is the speculative portfolio. A fall in r will lead to an increase in the domestic investors speculative portfolio holdings of foreign currency. We see that a fall in r will lead to a fall in the foreign investors holdings of domestic currency. The implication is a flow from the domestic currency to the foreign currency. 3. In addition to domestic investors and foreigners there is a domestic central bank. The holdings of the central bank is denoted as B g and F g for domestic currency and foreign currency respectively. Explain why we must have that B g + B + B ∗ = 0, (11.54) F g + F + F ∗ = 0. (11.55) and Solution A financial asset must by definition be the liability of someone else. If I hold a bond, someone has issued that bond. Money is the liability of the government that has issued it. 4. Start with the condition F g + F + F ∗ = 0. Insert your findings for F and F ∗ . Show that δF g >0 δ (11.56) if all investors have positive holdings of both currencies. Solution We have that σ ep r F =− − σ ee Rσ ee g B +F 358 ∗ σ ep∗ r B ∗ − 1+ − +F . σ ee Rσ ee (11.57) We want to identify the condition when δF g δ > 0. This will hold if ∗ σ ep r B σ ep∗ r B δF g = − + 1 + − . δ σ ee Rσ ee 2 σ ee Rσ ee 2 (11.58) This can be rewritten as δF g =f δ ∗ B B ∗ + (1 − b ) > 0. 2 2 (11.59) If B > 0 and f > 0 domestic investors hold both currencies, and the first term is greater than zero. If (1 − b∗ ) > 0 foreign investors holdings of foreign currency is greater than zero. If B ∗ > 0 their holdings of domestic currency is greater than zero. The last term must then be greater than zero, and the total must therefore be greater than zero. The condition will always be satisfied if both domestic and foreign investors hold a positive amount of both currencies. 5. Draw a diagram with on the y-axis, and F g on the x-axis. Insert the equilibrium condition of F g using the assumption above. Explain how F g will change with a change in f , assuming (a) a fixed exchange rate, and (b) a floating exchange rate. Solution For diagrams, see below. In a fixed exchange rate regime the central bank must adjust its foreign reserves as supply of foreign currency to the central bank changes. In a floating exchange rate regime the central bank will not intervene in the foreign exchange market. In this case the exchange rate must change to equilibrate the market. 6. Illustrate the effect of fall in r. Use three graphs: 359 (a) first assume a fixed exchange rate, (b) second assume a floating exchange rate, (c) then assume that the rate is fixed until the foreign reserves reach a certain level F g . At this point the rate is allowed to float. Lecture 9 1. The following was stated in the Lecture on May 28: “We have two maximisation problems. For the home country we have 1−m (QCF )m s.t. A = Y + B = CH + QCF , M ax U = CH (11.60) and for the foreign country ∗ M ax U = ∗ CH Q 1−m∗ ∗ (CF∗ )m s.t. A∗ = Y ∗ − B C∗ = H +CF∗ .00 Q Q (11.61) From these two maximisation problems we derived consumption functions. For the home country we found CH = (1 − m)(Y + B), CF = m Y +B , Q (11.62) and for the foreign country ∗ CH = Qm∗ (Y ∗ − B ), Q CF = (1 − m∗ )(Y ∗ − B ). Q (11.63) The four consumption functions are correct. However, the maximisation problem for the foreign consumers is not. Given the 360 Figure 11.9: Fixed exchange rate. Fall in r e Monetary policy, fixed rate Supply of foreign currency to the central bank Fg Figure 11.10: Floating exchange rate. Fall in r e Supply of foreign currency to the central bank Monetary policy, floating rate Fg 361 four consumption functions, make the necessary adjustment of the maximisation problem. Solution As a general rule we have that if the maximisation problem is formulated as U = X n Y 1−n s.t. A = X + pY, (11.64) the solution will be on the form X = nA, Y Y = (1 − n) . p (11.65) If you take a closer look, all four consumption functions stated above are on this form. However, if the maximisation problem for the foreign country was correct as stated we should expect that ∗ = (1 − m∗ )Q(Y ∗ − CH B ), Q CF = m∗ (Y ∗ − B ). Q (11.66) But I have stated that the consumption function given was correct, and the maximisation problem wrong. For the consumption function to be correct, the maximisation problem must be formulated ∗ M ax U = ∗ CH Q m∗ ∗ (CF∗ )1−m ∗ B CH s.t. A = Y − = + CF∗ . Q Q (11.67) ∗ ∗ 2. Given what you find above, is it reasonable to assume that 1 − m > m∗ ? (11.68) Solution m reflects the share of foreign goods in home consumption, and m∗ is the share of home goods in foreign consumption. 362 The statement above claims that the share of home goods in home country consumption exceeds the share of home goods in the foreign consumption. That sound reasonable. 3. Explain why m∗ Y ∗ = mY Q (11.69) will imply a trade balance of zero. Solution m∗ Y ∗ Q is the foreign consumption of home goods in home currency, or home exports denominated in home currency. mY is the home consumption of foreign goods in home currency, or home imports in home currency. If these to sums are equal, the trade balance is by definition zero. 4. Using the consumption functions above, and the market clearing clearing condition of ∗ CH + CH = Y, (11.70) and inserting the consumption functions, we derive the market clearing real exchange rate as Q= mY (1 − m − m∗ )B − . m∗ Y ∗ m∗ Y ∗ (11.71) Find the effect on Q of a change in Y ∗ . What does this imply for the welfare of the home country? Is a positive supply shock abroad good or bad for the home country? Solution We find that δQ mY − (1 − m − m∗ )B 1 Q = − = − ∗ < 0. ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ δY mY Y Y (11.72) A positive supply shock abroad will imply a real appreciation. A real appreciation means that the value of the home currency has 363 increased, consumers in the home country can consume more of the foreign good than before. Should not a real appreciation also mean less competitiveness? That is not a problem here: remember home output has not changed, and markets still clear, so all home output is consumed. The foreign country is richer, and will consume more of both home and foreign goods. A positive supply shock in one country will in this case be to the advantage of both countries. 5. We want to illustrate the effect of a temporary shock in Y , and how different capital flows affect Q differently. Use the equation for Q stated above. Assume Y ∗ = 20, m = 1/3 and m∗ = 1/3 in all periods. Ignore the existence of interest on debt. We look at 4 periods. In period 0 Y is 20, debt is zero, and the current account is zero. In period 1 output fall from 20 to 10. In period 2 output bounces back to 20, and remains constant in period 3 and 4. Note that the results are not in line with what was presented during the lecture... (a) Assume no capital flows. Illustrate the paths of Y , Q, A, B and total debt. Solution See table 11.1. (b) Assume that the country does not allow A to change in period 1. However debt accumulated in period 1 is to be repaid with equal amounts in period 2, 3 and 4. Illustrate the paths of Y , Q, A, B and total debt at end of period. Solution See table 11.2. 364 Figure 11.11: Exchange rate fixed if F g > F g . Fall in r e Supply of foreign currency to the central bank Monetary policy, fixed rate Monetary policy, floating rate Fg g F min Table Periods 0 Y 20 Q 1 A 20 B 0 debt 0 11.1: 1 10 0.5 10 0 0 First 2 3 4 20 20 20 1 1 1 20 20 20 0 0 0 0 0 0 Table 11.2: Second Periods 0 1 2 3 4 Y 20 10 20 20 20 Q 1 0 1.167 1.167 1.167 A 20 20 50/3 50/3 50/3 B 0 10 -10/3 -10/3 -10/3 debt 0 10 10/6 10/3 0 365 (c) Assume that the country adjusts absorption in period 1, but with the goal of having the same absorption in period 1, 2, 3 and 4. In the end of period 4 total debt should be zero. Illustrate the paths of Y , Q, A, B and total debt. Solution See table 11.3. Q appreciate less in period 1 compared to the result above. It also depreciates less in period 2. Lecture 10 Solve the following problems: 1. Given Seignoraget = (1 − 1 )(1 + µ)−η = µ(1 + µ)−η−1 , 1+µ (11.73) find δSeignoraget . δµ (11.74) Solution δSeignoraget = (1 + µ)−η−1 − µ(η + 1)(1 + µ)−η−2 = 0. (11.75) δµ 2. Given L = π 2 + b[(1 − σ)un + a(π e − π)]2 , (11.76) δL . δπ (11.77) find Solution δL = 2π − 2ab[(1 − σ)un + a(π e − π)] = 0. δπ 366 (11.78) 3. Given 1−m L = CH (QCF )m + λ (Y + B − CH − QCF ) , (11.79) find δL . δCF (11.80) Solution δL 1−m = mQm (CF )m−1 CH − Qλ = 0, δCF (11.81) 4. Given 1 U = (1−f )i+f (i∗ +µe )−µp − R f 2 σ ee + σ pp − 2f σ ep , (11.82) 2 find δU . δf (11.83) Solution 1 δU = −i + (i∗ + µe ) − R [2f σ ee − 2σ ep ] = 0. δf 2 (11.84) Other questions 1. The Barro-Gordon model (45 %) We can express the Phillips curve as u = un + a(π e − π). (11.85) Here u is the unemployment rate, un is the “non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment”, or NAIRU. π is the observed rate of inflation, and π e is the expected rate of inflation. If inflation 367 exceeds expected inflation, the unemployment rate can for a short period be less than the NAIRU. However, one can not expect inflation to exceed expected inflation over time. We assume that the government has two policy goals: to keep inflation stable, and to keep unemployment low. In fact, the government has as a goal to keep unemployment at a level u∗ < un . We specifically assume that u∗ = σun , (11.86) where 0 < σ < 1. The government minimises a loss function, L, that contain these two elements: L = π 2 + b[u − u∗ ]2 , (11.87) where b (assumed to be > 0) is the weight on holding unemployment at u∗ . If we substitute in for the equations (11.85) and (11.86), we obtain L = π 2 + b[(1 − σ)un + a(π e − π)]2 . (11.88) (a) Assume that the government set π = 0, and that this is fully credible—the public believes the government, so that π e = 0 as well. Show the loss of the government. Solution The the loss would be L = b[(1 − σ)un ]2 . (11.89) (b) Assume that all agents are rational and have perfect foresight. Why can the government not achieve the loss in (1a)? What 368 will be the actual rate of inflation in this economy? Solution The government can set π at will. If it minimises its loss function, inflation would be set at: δL = 2π − 2ab[(1 − σ)un + a(π e − π)] = 0. δπ (11.90) or (1+a2 b)π = ab[(1−σ)un +a(π e )] ⇒ π = ab(1 − σ)un a2 bπ e + . 1 + a2 b 1 + a2 b (11.91) If π e = 0 the government would set π 6= 0—it would choose to use the high credibility to “fool” the public. By setting inflation¿0 it achieves a lower unemployment rate. The public will understand the incentives of the government. They will know the government loss function. Expected inflation will therefore equal actual inflation, π = π e . The inflation rate will be: π = πe = ab(1 − σ)un a2 bπ e + 1 + a2 b 1 + a2 b ⇒ π = π e = ab(1 − σ)un . (11.92) (c) Assume two countries have different values for b in their loss functions. Why would this create a credibility problem if the two countries tried to establish a fixed currency between them? Solution If two countries shall fix their common exchange rate, this implies that the two countries must follow the same monetary policy over time. This implies that their inflation rates must be approximately equal over time as well. To see this, assume that PPP must hold over time. However, as we 369 can see above, optimal inflation will depend on the parameter b. If b is different, optimal inflation will not be the same. One should expect that the country with high b has higher inflation. This will strain the credibility of the regime. 2. The Krugman model (45 %) Country A is a developing country with a long history of high inflation. The money demand is given on logarithmic form as mt − pt = −η(Et pt+1 − pt ), (11.93) where m is the log of the money supply, m = ln(M ), p is the log of the price level, and η is a parameter. Assume that PPP holds, so that the exchange rate on log-form, e, is given by et = pt − p∗t . (11.94) p∗ is the foreign price level. For simplicity we set p∗ = 0, and assume that foreign inflation is zero. If we assume perfect foresight, and use continuous time notation, so that · et+1 − et = e, (11.95) we can write the money demand function as · mt − et = −η e. (11.96) Money supply, M , reflects the central bank asset sheet. The central bank has two main types of assets, foreign reserves and do- 370 mestic government bonds. We can therefore write M as M = D + R, (11.97) where D is domestic bonds, and R is foreign reserves. The central bank will support a fixed exchange rate as long as R > 0. Three results: · – If the exchange rate is fixed at a level e = e, then e = 0, so we must have e = mt . (11.98) This implies that the money supply is fixed at a level mt = m. – If the money supply, M , grows at a fixed rate µ, the exchange rate is given as: et = mt + µη. (11.99) – Note that if a variable X grows at a given rate µ, the value of ln(Xt ) = xt can be stated as a function of the growth rate and the initial value of x: xt = x0 + µt. (11.100) In the following we assume that the exchange rate is initially fixed. The exchange rate is fixed at e = e = m. We have that M = D0 + R0 . (11.101) (a) Assume that the central bank’s holdings of domestic government bonds, D, grows at a speed µ. If the exchange rate shall remain fixed, what must happen to the money supply? Which 371 implication will this have for the level of foreign reserves, R? Why can this policy be described as “inconsistent”? Solution If the exchange rate shall remain fixed, the money supply must remain equal to M . This implies that an absolute increase in domestic credit must be reflected by an absolute fall in foreign reserves. But when reserves go to zero, the central bank can no longer sustain a fixed exchange rate. (b) The “shadow exchange rate”, ee, is given as eet = dt + µη. (11.102) Explain the term “shadow exchange rate”. Solution The shadow exchange rate is the exchange rate that would have been the actual exchange if a speculative attack had already taken place. This implies that the shadow exchange rate is the exchange rate assuming that R = 0. It will only depend on the level of D. (c) According to the Krugman model a speculative attack will happen in the point T , when the fixed exchange rate equals the shadow exchange rate, or e = ee. Illustrate the paths of e and ee. Explain why a speculative attack must happen at T . Solution Assume that the fixed exchange rate equals the shadow rate at time T . Let the fixed exchange rate collapses at a T + 2. In this case the shadow rate will exceed the fixed rate. The fixed rate is terminated at this point, the exchange rate must make a jump from e to ee. A discrete jump in the exchange rate will imply infinite profit opportunities for rational speculators. As everyone have perfect foresight, everyone 372 will try to sell the domestic currency at time T + 1. Hence, the speculative attack will take place at T + 1. However, at T + 1 the jump will still be discrete. So everyone will sell at T . Why not sell at T − 1? Simply because one would lose money by doing so. If everyone sell at T − 1 the exchange rate actually will appreciate, as the shadow rate at this time is lower than the fixed rate. (d) At p. 74 in “International Money”, in the discussion of the Krugman model, De Grauwe states: “The timing of the attack is independent of the stock of international reserves the authorities start with.” Find the expression for T . Comment on this statement. What is independent of the initial stock of reserves? Solution We have that by definition e = ln(M ) = ln(D0 + R0 ). At T we have that e = m = ln(D0 + R0 ) = ee = d0 + µT + µη. (11.103) We can then find T as T = ln(D0 + R0 ) − d0 − µη . µ (11.104) Clearly, the timing of T does depend on R0 . The larger R0 , everything else given, the longer it takes before the speculative attack takes place. However, note that no value of R0 could stop a speculative attack from taking place—it will only affect the timing of the attack. A speculative attack is a certain outcome as long as there is a given growth in domestic credit. 373 (e) Illustrate the path of foreign reserves and the money supply. What happens to money supply at time T ? How much does it change? Give an intuitive understanding of this result. Solution In the fixed exchange rate regime, the exchange rate is given as e = m. (11.105) In the floating regime the exchange rate is given as eet = mt + ηµ. (11.106) However, at time T we have that e = ef T . So we must simultaneously have that m = mT + ηµ. (11.107) It follows that at time T money supply must fall by mT − m = −ηµ. (11.108) The point here is that the functions for the exchange rate depends on expectations: if money supply is constant, e = m, but if money supply is growing, e = m + ηµ. As we are changing from one regime to the other, the money supply must fall to assure that the arbitrage condition is fulfilled. For illustrations, see figure 11.12. (f) If the central bank increases its holdings of domestic bonds at a given rate, what might that tell you about fiscal policy in this country? Assume that the government is following the policy described 374 Figure 11.12: Anatomy of a speculative attack log exchange rate T Shadow floating rate Fixed rate log money supply time time log foreign reserves Level of foreign reserves at time of attack time 375 above. However, the central bank is not increasing its holdings of domestic bonds. Instead the government is borrowing money abroad. Would this make a difference for the results in our model? Discuss consequences of the different strategies. Solution We probably have a case with a government running fiscal deficits—reflected in their issuance of government bonds. The independence of the monetary authority form the fiscal authority is however weak, as the monetary authority evidently is forced to take up the fiscal debt. As there is fixed exchange rate, the debt can not be monetised directly. Instead the central bank builds down reserves. If the central bank’s holdings of foreign reserves do not change, then the fixed exchange rate regime remains viable for all future. However, it is questionable whether it is possible to borrow abroad of finance an eternal budget deficit. At some point the ability to borrow aborad must be expected to dry up. At this point of time the government must use the foreign reserves to repay old debt, and use the money supply to finance the deficit. So unless policy changes, the result—a speculative attack—would probably still follow. 3. High volume—Is it a puzzle? (10 %) The daily volume in the FX spot market in April 1998 was 600 billion USD. As a comparison, the daily volume in the New York Stock Exchange in this period was 30 billion USD, and average daily world trade in goods and services was about 15 billion USD. Given your knowledge of how the FX-market works, discuss these fact. What features of the FX market might explain the high 376 volume of the FX-market compared to other markets? Solution As there are no given solution to this question, every good discussion should be rewarded. Two points: (a) As exchange rate markets are used not only for trade of goods, but also for the trade of assets between people in different countries, and because the daily trade in assets are much bigger than the daily trade of goods, the turnover in the asset markets is probably the most relevant comparison if we want to understand the volume in the FX-market. However, trade in assets alone is probably not enough to explain the volume observed. (b) In class we have presented the “hot-potato-hypothesis”: the FX-market is a multiple dealer market with low transparency and low transaction costs. Dealers do not sit long on large currency positions (at least they tend to close out at night). When customers approach a dealer with a large trade, the dealer will try to reduce position by making transactions with other dealers. Other dealers will be eager to make such deals because this is the best way to obtain information about what is going on. Currency will be traded between dealers like a “hot-potato”. 377 Table 11.3: Third Periods 0 1 2 3 4 Y 20 10 20 20 20 Q 1 0.125 1.125 1.125 1.125 A 20 17.5 17.5 17.5 17.5 B 0 7.5 -2.5 -2.5 -2.5 debt 0 7.5 5 2.5 0