* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Capital Structure
Investment fund wikipedia , lookup
Internal rate of return wikipedia , lookup
Pensions crisis wikipedia , lookup
Debt settlement wikipedia , lookup
Debt collection wikipedia , lookup
Systemic risk wikipedia , lookup
Debtors Anonymous wikipedia , lookup
Modified Dietz method wikipedia , lookup
Financial economics wikipedia , lookup
Global saving glut wikipedia , lookup
Stock selection criterion wikipedia , lookup
Stock valuation wikipedia , lookup
First Report on the Public Credit wikipedia , lookup
Private equity wikipedia , lookup
Private equity secondary market wikipedia , lookup
Present value wikipedia , lookup
Private equity in the 2000s wikipedia , lookup
Government debt wikipedia , lookup
Financialization wikipedia , lookup
Household debt wikipedia , lookup
Early history of private equity wikipedia , lookup
Business valuation wikipedia , lookup
Capital Structure 15.1 The Capital-Structure Question and The Pie Theory 15.2 Maximizing Firm Value versus Maximizing Stockholder Interests 15.3 Financial Leverage and Firm Value: An Example 15.4 Modigliani and Miller: Proposition II (No Taxes) 15.5 Taxes 15.6 Summary and Conclusions The Capital-Structure Question and The Pie Theory The value of a firm is defined to be the sum of the value of the firm’s debt and the firm’s equity. V=B+S • If the goal of the management of the firm is to make the firm as valuable as possible, the the firm should pick the debt-equity ratio that makes the pie as big as possible. S B Value of the Firm The Capital-Structure Question There are really two important questions: 1. Why should the stockholders care about maximizing firm value? Perhaps they should be interested in strategies that maximize shareholder value. 2. What is the ratio of debt-to-equity that maximizes the shareholder’s value? As it turns out, changes in capital structure benefit the stockholders if and only if the value of the firm increases. Financial Leverage, EPS, and ROE Consider an all-equity firm that is considering going into debt. (Maybe some of the original shareholders want to cash out.) Current Assets $20,000 Debt $0 Equity $20,000 Debt/Equity ratio 0.00 Interest rate n/a Shares outstanding 400 Share price $50 Proposed $20,000 $8,000 $12,000 2/3 8% 240 $50 EPS and ROE Under Current Capital Structure EBIT Interest Net income EPS ROA ROE Recession $1,000 0 $1,000 $2.50 5% 5% Expected Expansion $2,000 $3,000 0 0 $2,000 $3,000 $5.00 $7.50 10% 15% 10% 15% Current Shares Outstanding = 400 shares EPS and ROE Under Proposed Capital Structure EBIT Interest Net income EPS ROA ROE Recession $1,000 640 $360 $1.50 5% 3% Expected Expansion $2,000 $3,000 640 640 $1,360 $2,360 $5.67 $9.83 10% 15% 11% 20% Proposed Shares Outstanding = 240 shares EPS and ROE Under Both Capital Structures All-Equity Recession EBIT $1,000 Interest 0 Net income $1,000 EPS $2.50 ROA 5% ROE 5% Current Shares Outstanding = 400 shares Expected $2,000 0 $2,000 $5.00 10% 10% Expansion $3,000 0 $3,000 $7.50 15% 15% Levered Recession EBIT $1,000 Interest 640 Net income $360 EPS $1.50 ROA 5% ROE 3% Proposed Shares Outstanding = 240 shares Expected $2,000 640 $1,360 $5.67 10% 11% Expansion $3,000 640 $2,360 $9.83 15% 20% Financial Leverage and EPS 12.00 Debt 10.00 EPS 8.00 6.00 4.00 No Debt Advantage to debt Break-even point 2.00 0.00 1,000 (2.00) Disadvantage to debt 2,000 3,000 EBIT EBI in dollars, no taxes Assumptions of the Modigliani-Miller Model Homogeneous Expectations Homogeneous Business Risk Classes Perpetual Cash Flows Perfect Capital Markets: Perfect competition Firms and investors can borrow/lend at the same rate Equal access to all relevant information No transaction costs No taxes Homemade Leverage: An Example Recession Expected Expansion EPS of Unlevered Firm $2.50 $5.00 $7.50 Earnings for 40 shares $100 $200 $300 Less interest on $800 (8%) $64 $64 $64 Net Profits $36 $136 $236 ROE (Net Profits / $1,200) 3% 11% 20% We are buying 40 shares of a $50 stock on margin. We get the same ROE as if we bought into a levered firm. Our personal debt equity ratio is: B $800 2 3 S $1,200 Homemade (Un)Leverage: An Example Recession Expected Expansion EPS of Levered Firm $1.50 $5.67 $9.83 Earnings for 24 shares $36 $136 $236 Plus interest on $800 (8%) $64 $64 $64 Net Profits $100 $200 $300 ROE (Net Profits / $2,000) 5% 10% 15% Buying 24 shares of an other-wise identical levered firm along with the some of the firm’s debt gets us to the ROE of the unlevered firm. This is the fundamental insight of M&M The MM Propositions I & II (No Taxes) Proposition I Firm value is not affected by leverage VL = VU Proposition II Leverage increases the risk and return to stockholders rs = r0 + (B / SL) (r0 - rB) rB is the interest rate (cost of debt) rs is the return on (levered) equity (cost of equity) r0 is the return on unlevered equity (cost of capital) B is the value of debt SL is the value of levered equity Cost of capital: r (%) The Cost of Equity, the Cost of Debt, and the Weighted Average Cost of Capital: MM Proposition II with No Corporate Taxes r0 rS r0 rW ACC B (r0 rB ) SL B S rB rS BS BS rB rB Debt-to-equity Ratio B S Implications of the MM No-Tax Propositions Capital structure is irrelevant in an MM world without corporate taxes. VL = V U The value of the firm (“size of the pie”) is determined by the firm’s capital budgeting decisions. Capital structure determines only how the pie is sliced. Increasing the extent to which a firm relies on debt increases both the risk and the expected return to equity – but not the price per share. The MM Propositions I & II (with Corporate Taxes) Proposition I (with Corporate Taxes) Firm value increases with leverage VL = VU + T C B Proposition II (with Corporate Taxes) Some of the increase in equity risk and return is offset by interest tax shield rS = r0 + (B/S)×(1-TC)×(r0 - rB) rB is the interest rate (cost of debt) rS is the return on equity (cost of equity) r0 is the return on unlevered equity (cost of capital) B is the value of debt S is the value of levered equity The Effect of Financial Leverage on the Cost of Debt and Equity Capital Cost of capital: r (%) rS r0 B (1 TC ) (r0 rB ) SL r0 rW ACC B SL rB (1 TC ) rS BSL B SL rB Debt-to-equity ratio (B/S) Total Cash Flow to Investors Under Each Capital Structure with Corp. Taxes All-Equity EBIT Interest EBT Taxes (Tc = 35% Total Cash Flow to S/H Recession $1,000 0 $1,000 $350 $650 Expected $2,000 0 $2,000 $700 $1,300 Expansion $3,000 0 $3,000 $1,050 $1,950 Expected $2,000 640 $1,360 $476 $468+$640 $1,524 $1,300+$224 $1,524 Expansion $3,000 640 $2,360 $826 $1,534+$640 $2,174 $1,950+$224 $2,174 Levered EBIT Interest ($800 @ 8% ) EBT Taxes (Tc = 35%) Total Cash Flow (to both S/H & B/H): EBIT(1-Tc)+TCrBB Recession $1,000 640 $360 $126 $234+640 $874 $650+$242 $874 Total Cash Flow to Investors Under Each Capital Structure with Corp. Taxes All-equity firm S G Levered firm S G B The levered firm pays less in taxes than does the allequity firm. Thus, the sum of the debt plus the equity of the levered firm is greater than the equity of the unlevered firm. An Example (no taxes): Imagine you have discovered an investment alternative which produces expected EBIT of $1,000 forever. Similar (unlevered) projects in the market have a required return r0 of 10%. You must put up $5,000 of your own money to invest in this project. You have two financing alternatives: Unlevered: you issue yourself $5,000 in equity, SU Levered: you sell yourself $1,000 debt, B, and $4,000 equity S. The debt pays the market rate rB of 5%. Example, continued Annual cash flows, depending on your choice of financing, are: Unlevered Levered EBIT $1,000 $1,000 Interest -50 (rB*B) EBT 1,000 950 Tax (0%) Net Income 1,000 950 CF(B+S) $1,000 $1,000 Example continued, Proposition I: VU=SU=EBIT/r0 = $1,000/.1=$10,000 VL= B + S = $10,000 S = $10,000 - $1,000 = $9,000 Example, continued Proposition II: rS = r0 + (B/S)(r0 - rB ) r0 = .10 + ($0/$10,000)(.10-.05) = 10% rS = .10 +($1,000/$9,000)(.10-.05)=10.56% WACC = (1,000/10,000)(5%) + (9,000/10,000)(10.56%) = 10% = r0 An Example of MM Propositions I & II with Corporate Taxes Consider the same investment and financing alternatives as for the no tax example, but now TC = 34%, Unlevered Levered EBIT $1,000 $1,000 Interest -50 EBT 1,000 950 Tax(34%) -340 -323 Net Income 660 627 CF(B+S) $660 $677 A Debt versus Equity Problem The market value of a firm that has $500,000 in debt is $1,700,000. The expected value of EBIT is a perpetuity. The interest rate on debt (pretax) is 10%. The company is subject to a 34% tax rate. If the company were 100% equity financed, the equity holders would have a 20% required return. What is the net income of the firm? What would be the market value of the firm if it were 100% equity financed? Example Continued VL=VU + TCB $1,700 = VU + (.34)*($500) => VU =$1,530 VU = EBIT (1- TC )/r0 $1,530 = EBIT *(1-.34)/.2 => EBIT = $463, 636 Summary: No Taxes In a world of no taxes, the value of the firm is unaffected by capital structure. This is M&M Proposition I: VL = VU Prop I holds because shareholders can achieve any pattern of payouts they desire with homemade leverage. In a world of no taxes, M&M Proposition II states that leverage increases the risk and return to stockholders B rS r0 (r0 rB ) SL Summary: Taxes In a world of taxes, but no bankruptcy costs, the value of the firm increases with leverage. This is M&M Proposition I: VL = VU + TC B Prop I holds because shareholders can achieve any pattern of payouts they desire with homemade leverage. In a world of taxes, M&M Proposition II states that leverage increases the risk and return to stockholders. B rS r0 (1 TC ) (r0 rB ) SL Bankruptcy Costs So far, we have seen M&M suggest that financial leverage does not matter, or imply that taxes cause the optimal financial structure to be 100% debt. In the real world, most executives do not like a capital structure of 100% debt because that is a state known as “bankruptcy”. In the next chapter we will introduce the notion of a limit on the use of debt: financial distress. The important use of this chapter is to get comfortable with “M&M algebra”.