Download Leverage Restrictions in a Business Cycle Model Lawrence J. Christiano Northwestern University

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Syndicated loan wikipedia , lookup

Investment management wikipedia , lookup

Household debt wikipedia , lookup

Financialization wikipedia , lookup

History of the Federal Reserve System wikipedia , lookup

Private equity wikipedia , lookup

Debt wikipedia , lookup

Global saving glut wikipedia , lookup

Shadow banking system wikipedia , lookup

Private equity in the 1980s wikipedia , lookup

Private equity secondary market wikipedia , lookup

Private equity in the 2000s wikipedia , lookup

Early history of private equity wikipedia , lookup

Bank wikipedia , lookup

History of investment banking in the United States wikipedia , lookup

Interbank lending market wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Leverage Restrictions in a Business
Cycle Model
Lawrence J. Christiano
Daisuke Ikeda
Northwestern University
Bank of Japan
March 13-14, 2015, Macro Financial Modeling, NYU Stern.
Background
• Wish to address the following sorts of questions:
— What restrictions should be placed on bank borrowing?
— How should those restrictions be varied over the business cycle?
• Want an environment with the following properties:
— model includes problem that restrictions on bank borrowing are
supposed to solve.
— riskiness of banks varies over time.
What We Do
• Modify a standard medium-sized DSGE model to include a
banking sector.
Assets
Liabilities
Loans and other securities Deposits
Banker net worth
• Job of bankers is to identify and finance good investment
projects.
— doing this requires exerting costly e§ort.
• Agency problem between bank and its creditors:
— banker e§ort is not observable.
• Consequence: borrowing restrictions on banks may generate
substantial welfare gains.
Outline
• Model
— first, without borrowing restriction
• observable e§ort benchmark
• unobservable case
— potential welfare gains of borrowing restriction
• Dynamics
Standard Model
Firms
L
Labor
market
K
C
I
Market for
Physical Capital
household
Standard Model with Banking
Firms
L
K
K,
~F ,
Labor
market
Entrepreneurs
household
t
Standard Model with Banking
Firms
L
Labor
market
C
I
Capital
Producers
Entrepreneurs
1
household
K
Entrepreneur
pays everything to the bank
and has nothing.
Standard Model with Banking
Firms
Labor
market
Capital
Producers
household
Entrepreneurs
banks
Mutual funds
Entrepreneurs
• bad entrepreneur: 1 unit, raw capital ! ebt units, e§ective
capital
• good entrepreneur: 1 unit, raw capital ! egt > ebt units,
e§ective capital
• return to capital enjoyed by entrepreneurs:
g
Rt+1 = egt Rkt+1 , Rbt+1 = ebt Rkt+1
Rkt+1
rkt+1 Pt+1 + (1 − d) Pk0 ,t+1
≡
Pk 0 t
Bankers
• each has net worth, Nt .
• a banker can only invest in one entrepreneur (asset side of
banker balance sheet is risky).
• by exerting e§ort, et , a banker finds a good entrepreneur with
probability p :
p (et ) = ā + b̄et
• in t, bankers seek to optimize:
Et l t + 1 { p ( et )
h
+ (1 − p (et ))
i
g
Rt+1 (Nt
g
+ dt ) − Rd,t+1 dt
Rbt+1 (Nt
+ dt ) − Rbd,t+1 dt
h
• Bankers have a cash constraint:
Rbt+1 (Nt + dt ) ≥ Rbd,t+1 dt
i
1
} − e2t
2
Bankers and their Creditors
• Bankers and Mutual Funds interact in competitive markets for
loan contracts:
#
g
dt , et , Rd,t+1 , Rbd,t+1
$
• Free entry and competition among mutual funds implies:
g
p (et ) Rd,t+1 + (1 − p (et )) Rbd,t+1 = Rt
• Two scenarios:
— banker e§ort, et , is observed by mutual fund
— banker e§ort, et , is unobserved.
Observed E§ort Benchmark
• Set
to bankers is the
# of contracts available
$
g
dt , et , Rd,t+1 , Rbd,t+1 ’s that satisfy
MF zero profits:
cash constraint:
g
p (et ) Rd,t+1 + (1 − p (et )) Rbd,t+1 = Rt ,
Rbt+1 (Nt + dt ) ≥ Rbd,t+1 dt
• Each banker chooses the most preferred contract from the
menu.
• Key feature of observed e§ort equilibrium:
#
$
g
et = Et lt+1 p0 (et ) Rt+1 − Rbt+1 (Nt + dt )
Unobserved E§ort
• In this case, banker always sets et to its privately optimal level,
whatever et is specified in the loan contract:
#
$
g
0
b
incentive:
et = Et lt+1 p (et ) [ Rt+1 − Rt+1 (Nt + dt )
#
$
g
− Rd,t+1 − Rbd,t+1 dt ].
• Set
to bankers is the
# of contracts available
$
g
dt , et , Rd,t+1 , Rbd,t+1 ’s that satisfy ‘incentive’ in addition to:
MF zero profits:
cash constraint:
g
p (et ) Rd,t+1 + (1 − p (et )) Rbd,t+1 = Rt ,
Rbt+1 (Nt + dt ) ≥ Rbd,t+1 dt
• One factor that can make et ine¢ciently low:
g
— Rd,t+1 > Rbd,t+1 .
Source of Ine¢ciency in Unobserved E§ort
Model
• The presence of a market interest rate in the incentive
constraint creates a ‘pecuniary externality’.
• Basic idea:
— Private cost to bank of higher funds, d :
• interest paid on deposits, R.
— Social cost of higher d:
• R plus damage to bank incentives when R rises with bigger d.
• Consequence: equilibrium d may be too high, in which case
limit on d is desirable.
• Most straightforward to see in a simple two-period setting.
— Grateful to Saki Bigio and Emmanuel Fahri for bringing
following argument to our attention.
Desirability of Borrowing Restrictions in
Two Period Version of Model
• Bankers and workers live in large, identical households.
— as in Gertler-Karadi, Gertler-Kiyotaki.
• Representative household’s problem:
max u(c0 ) + c1 ,
{c0 ,c1 ,d}
s.t. c0 + d = y, c1 = Rd + p.
where p denotes the profits brought home by bankers:
h
i
h
i
g
p = p(e) Rg (N + d) − Rd d + (1 − p(e)) Rb (N + d) − Rbd d .
Optimality condition for deposits:
R = u0 (y − d )
Desirability of Borrowing Restrictions in
Two Period Version of Model
• Banker problem (with potentially binding borrowing restriction):
max
g
{Rd ,Rbd ,d,e}
h
g
p (e) R (N
g
+ d) − Rd d
i
h
i 1
+ (1 − p (e)) Rb (N + d) − Rbd d − e2
2
h
i
+n Rb (N + d) − Rbd d
n
h
#
$ i
o
g
+h p0 (e) (Rg − Rb )(N + d) − Rd − Rbd d − e
+µ(d̄ − d)
subject to zero profit condition on loan contract.
Desirability of Borrowing Restrictions in
Two Period Version of Model
• Use zero profit condition and binding cash constraint to
g
simplify banker problem (drop Rd , Rbd ) :
1
max p (e) Rg (N + d) + (1 − p (e)) Rb (N + d) − Rd − e2
2
{d,e}
(
"
#
)
b (N + d)
Rd
−
R
+h p0 (e) (Rg − Rb )(N + d) −
−e
p(e)
+µ(d̄ − d)
• Optimality condition for d:
p(e)Rg + (1 − p(e))Rb = R +
µ
1 + hp0 (e)/p(e)
borrowing restriction raises cost of funds above R.
.
Ramsey Problem in Two Period Version of
Model
• After substituting out zero profit condition, cash constraint and
deposit supply
utility of period 0 consumption
max{
e,d
+h
"
z }| {
u(y − d)
1
+ c1 − e2
2
#
!
0 (y − d)d − Rb (N + d)
u
p0 (e) (Rg − Rb )(N + d) −
−e }
p(e)
s.t.
c1 = u0 (y − d)d + p(e)Rg (N + d) + (1 − p(e))Rb (N + d) − u0 (y − d)d
Ramsey Problem in Two Period Version of
Model
• Optimality condition for d:
p(e)Rg + (1 − p(e))Rb
extra marginal cost associated with extra d
= R+
z
}|
{
0
00
hp (e)/p(e)(−u (y − d))d
1 + hp0 (e)/p(e)
.
• To get the private d decision to coincide with Ramsey-optimal
decision, must choose d̄ so that multiplier, µ, on private
problem satisfies:
µ = hp0 (e)/p(e)(−u00 (y − d))d > 0
Back to Dynamic Model
• Model dynamics requires law of motion for banker net worth.
• Introduces an additional borrowing consideration.
Law of Motion of Net Worth
• Bankers live in a large representative household, with workers.
— Bankers pool their net worth at the end of each period (we
avoid worrying about banker heterogeneity)
• Law of motion of banker net worth
Nt+1 = gt+1 {p (et )
zh
profits of banks with good assets
g
Rt+1 (Nt
+ (1 − p (et ))
hz
}|
i{
g
+ dt ) − Rd,t+1 dt
profits of banks with bad assets
Rbt+1 (Nt
}|
i{
b
+ dt ) − Rd,t+1 dt }
lump sum transfer, households to their bankers
+
z}|{
Tt+1
Model Assumption that Banks Don’t
Systematically Rely on Equity Issues to
Finance Assets
• Evidence from two sources provide support for this assumption
as a description of the data.
— Adrian and Shin’s examination of the assets and liabilities of
two large French financial firms.
— US flow of funds data on assets and liabilities of financial
corporations.
• Adrian and Shin, ‘Procyclical Leverage and Value-at-Risk’
— Changes in financial firm equity not systematically related to
their assets.
— Changes in financial firm debt moves one-for-one with changes
in assets.
.BUFSJBMUBLFOGSPNUIFXPSLPG"ESJBO4IJO
%JTQMBZTBTDBUUFSQMPUDIBOHFJOFRVJUZBOEEFCUPOUIFIPSJ[POUBMBYJTBHBJOTUDIBOHFJOBTTFUTPOUIFIPSJ[POUBMBYJT/PUFUIBUUIFTMPQFPGDIBOHFTJOEFCUBHBJOTU
DIBOHFTJOBTTFUTJTFTTFOUJBMMZVOJUZXIJMFUIFTMPQFPGDIBOHFTJOFRVJUZBHBJOTUDIBOHFTJOBTTFUTIBTBTMPQFPG[FSP
5IFSFTVMUTBSFDPOTJTUFOUXJUIUIFOPUJPOUIBUUIJTGJOBODJBMDPNQBOZIFBERVBSUFSFEJO1BSJTGJOBODFTDIBOHFTJOBTTFUTXJUIDIBOHFTJOEFCUBOEOPUDIBOHFTJOFRVJUZ
BNP Paribas: annual change in assets, equity and debt
(1999 - 2010)
500
y = 1.0051x - 6.2
R2 = 0.9987
Change in equity and debt
(billion euros)
400
300
Debt
Change
200
100
Equity
Change
0
-100
-200
-200
-100
0
100
200
300
400
500
Asset change (billion euros)
Figure 3. BNP Paribas: annual change in assets, equity and debt (1999-2010) (Source: Bankscope)
Discussion of Acharya and Seru
7
Societe Generale: annual changes in assets, equity and debt
(1999 - 2010)
Annual change in equity and debt
(billion euros)
300
250
y = 0.996x - 3.15
R2 = 0.9985
200
150
Debt
change
100
50
Equity
change
0
-50
-100
-150
-200
-100
0
100
200
300
Annual asset change (billion euros)
Figure 4. Société Générale: annual change in assets, equity and debt (1999-2010) (Source: Bankscope)
• The model assumes that when bankers want
funds, issuing equity is not an option.
Borrowing by Private Depository Institutions (Table F.109, Flow of Funds)
billions of dollars
800
700
600
open market paper, bonds, other loans, deposits
500
400
300
200
100
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
Equity as a source of funds, Private Depository Institutions (F.109, F of F)
billions of dollars
12
11
This shows how major debt instruments were used at
private depository institutions in the wake of the crisis.
10
9
8
7
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
• The model assumes that when bankers want
funds, issuing equity is not an option.
Borrowing by Private Depository Institutions (Table F.109, Flow of Funds)
billions of dollars
800
700
600
open market paper, bonds, other loans, deposits
500
400
300
200
100
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
Equity as a source of funds, Private Depository Institutions (F.109, F of F)
billions of dollars
12
11
10
9
8
7
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
‘Crisis’
• Suppose something makes banker net worth, Nt , drop.
• For given dt , bank cash constraint gets tighter:
Rbt+1 (Nt + dt ) ≥ Rbd,t+1 dt .
• So, Rbd,t+1 has to be low
— when Nt is low, banks with bad assets cannot cover their own
losses and creditors must share in losses.
g
— then, creditors require Rd,t+1 high
g
• So, interest rate spread, Rd,t+1 − Rt , high, banker e§ort low.
• Banks get riskier (cross sectional mean return down, standard
deviation up).
Endogenous Risk
• Rate of return on equity, good banks and bad banks:
g
p (et ) good banks :
1 − p (et ) bad banks :
g
Rt+1 (Nt + dt ) − Rd,t+1 dt
Nt
b
Rt+1 (Nt + dt ) − Rbd,t+1 dt
,
Nt
=0
• Mean, Ebt+1 , and cross sectional standard deviation, sbt+1 , of
return on equity across banks:
sbt+1
= [p (et ) (1 − p (et ))]
Ebt+1 = p (et )
g
Rt+1 (Nt
1/2
g
g
Rt+1 (Nt + dt ) − Rd,t+1 dt
g
+ dt ) − Rd,t+1 dt
Nt
• In a crisis, risk rises and mean return falls.
Nt
Macro Model
• Sticky wages and prices
• Investment adjustment costs
• Habit persistence in consumption
• Monetary policy rule
Calibration targets
Table 2: Steady state calibration targets for baseline model
Variable meaning
variable name
Cross-sectional standard deviation of quarterly non-financial firm equity returns s b
magnitude
0.20
Fnancial firm interest rate spreads (APR)
400 R dg
Financial firm leverage
L
R
0.60
20.00
Profits of intermediate good producers (controled by fixed cost, )
0
Government consumption relative to GDP (controlled by g)
0.20
Growth rate of per capita GDP (APR)
400
Rate of decline in real price of capital (APR)
400
z
1
1
1.65
1.69
Data behind calibration targets
Figure 1: Cross-section standard deviation financial firm quarterly return on equity, HP-filtered US real GDP
0.1
0.4
Cross section volatility (left scale)
0.3
0.05
0.2
0
0.1
-0.05
HP filtered GDP (right scale)
0
Q3 1962
-0.1
Q1 1968
Q2 1973
Q4 1978
Q1 1984
Q2 1989
quarterly data
Q4 1994
Q1 2000
Q3 2005
Q4 2010
Parameter Values
Table 1: Baseline Model Parameter Values
Meaning
Name
Value
Panel A: financial parameters
return parameter, bad entrepreneur
b
-0.09
return parameter, good entrepreneur
g
0.00
constant, effort function
0.83
slope, effort function
b
0.30
lump-sum transfer from households to bankers
T
0.38
fraction of banker net worth that stays with bankers
0.85
Panel B: Parameters that do not affect steady state
steady state inflation (APR)
400
1
2.40
1.50
Taylor rule weight on inflation
Taylor rule weight on output growth
curvature on investment adjustment costs
0.50
y
smoothing parameter in Taylor rule
0.80
p
5.00
S
Calvo sticky price parameter
p
0.75
Calvo sticky wage parameter
w
0.75
z
1.65
Panel C: Nonfinancial parameters
steady state gdp growth (APR)
steady state rate of decline in investment good price (APR)
1.69
capital depreciation rate
0.03
production fixed cost
0.89
capital share
0.40
steady state markup, intermediate good producers
1.20
f
habit parameter
bu
household discount rate
100
steady state markup, workers
Frisch labor supply elasticity
1/
L
g
1
0.52
1.05
w
weight on labor disutility
steady state scaled government spending
0.74
4
L
1.00
1.00
0.89
Impact of Loss of Bank Net Worth
Deposit rate,
bad (failed) banks (APR) Interest rate spread (APR)
levels
levels
3
2.5
−2
1
−4
0.8
levels
Bank net worth (N)
3.5
−6
−8
−10
10
15
−14
Std dev, in cross section,
financial firm equity returns
0
15
GDP
0.15
0.1
10
−0.6
−0.8
15
5
level
−0.6
−0.8
−1
10
5
10
−0.6
−0.8
−1
15
5
2.5
24
2.4
22
2.3
2.2
15
2
10
15
Bank leverage
2.1
−1.2
15
−0.4
Inflation (APR)
−0.4
10
−0.2
levels
5
5
Consumption
−0.4
Investment
% dev, ss
10
% dev, ss
0.2
0.05
5
−0.2
% dev, ss
levels
0.25
0.4
0.2
−12
5
0.6
20
18
16
5
10
no leverage restrictions
leverage restrictions
15
14
5
10
15
Borrowing Restrictions
• Banks taxed for issuing deposits dt
— 1.2% AR (versus 3% AR on the risk free nominal rate).
— revenues redistributed back to banks in lump-sum form.
• What is the consequence of this restriction?
— With less dt , banks with bad assets more able to cover losses
• interest rate spread falls, so banker e§ort rises.
— Second e§ect of borrowing restriction,
• borrowing restriction in e§ect implements collusion among
bankers
• allows them to behave as monopsonists
• make profits on demand deposits....lots of profits:
h
big
z}|{
# g
$
#
$i
dt
g
p ( et ) R
−R
+ (1 − p (et )) Rbt+1 − Rbd,t+1
t+1
d,t+1
Nt
• makes Nt grow, o§seting incentive e§ects of decline in dt .
Impact of Loss of Bank Net Worth
Deposit rate,
bad (failed) banks (APR) Interest rate spread (APR)
levels
levels
3
2.5
−2
1
−4
0.8
levels
Bank net worth (N)
3.5
−6
−8
−10
10
15
−14
Std dev, in cross section,
financial firm equity returns
0
15
GDP
0.15
0.1
10
−0.6
−0.8
15
5
level
−0.6
−0.8
−1
10
5
10
−0.6
−0.8
−1
15
5
2.5
24
2.4
22
2.3
2.2
15
2
10
15
Bank leverage
2.1
−1.2
15
−0.4
Inflation (APR)
−0.4
10
−0.2
levels
5
5
Consumption
−0.4
Investment
% dev, ss
10
% dev, ss
0.2
0.05
5
−0.2
% dev, ss
levels
0.25
0.4
0.2
−12
5
0.6
20
18
16
5
10
no leverage restrictions
leverage restrictions
15
14
5
10
15
Conclusion
• Described a model in which there is a problem that is mitigated
by the introduction of borrowing restrictions.
• Currently exploring what are the optimal dynamic properties of
leverage.
— the cyclical behavior of the tax on leverage depends on which
shock drives the cycle.
— if driven by permanent technology shocks, then act to
discourage debt in a boom.