* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Leverage Restrictions in a Business Cycle Model Lawrence J. Christiano Northwestern University
Syndicated loan wikipedia , lookup
Investment management wikipedia , lookup
Household debt wikipedia , lookup
Financialization wikipedia , lookup
History of the Federal Reserve System wikipedia , lookup
Private equity wikipedia , lookup
Global saving glut wikipedia , lookup
Shadow banking system wikipedia , lookup
Private equity in the 1980s wikipedia , lookup
Private equity secondary market wikipedia , lookup
Private equity in the 2000s wikipedia , lookup
Early history of private equity wikipedia , lookup
History of investment banking in the United States wikipedia , lookup
Leverage Restrictions in a Business Cycle Model Lawrence J. Christiano Daisuke Ikeda Northwestern University Bank of Japan March 13-14, 2015, Macro Financial Modeling, NYU Stern. Background • Wish to address the following sorts of questions: — What restrictions should be placed on bank borrowing? — How should those restrictions be varied over the business cycle? • Want an environment with the following properties: — model includes problem that restrictions on bank borrowing are supposed to solve. — riskiness of banks varies over time. What We Do • Modify a standard medium-sized DSGE model to include a banking sector. Assets Liabilities Loans and other securities Deposits Banker net worth • Job of bankers is to identify and finance good investment projects. — doing this requires exerting costly e§ort. • Agency problem between bank and its creditors: — banker e§ort is not observable. • Consequence: borrowing restrictions on banks may generate substantial welfare gains. Outline • Model — first, without borrowing restriction • observable e§ort benchmark • unobservable case — potential welfare gains of borrowing restriction • Dynamics Standard Model Firms L Labor market K C I Market for Physical Capital household Standard Model with Banking Firms L K K, ~F , Labor market Entrepreneurs household t Standard Model with Banking Firms L Labor market C I Capital Producers Entrepreneurs 1 household K Entrepreneur pays everything to the bank and has nothing. Standard Model with Banking Firms Labor market Capital Producers household Entrepreneurs banks Mutual funds Entrepreneurs • bad entrepreneur: 1 unit, raw capital ! ebt units, e§ective capital • good entrepreneur: 1 unit, raw capital ! egt > ebt units, e§ective capital • return to capital enjoyed by entrepreneurs: g Rt+1 = egt Rkt+1 , Rbt+1 = ebt Rkt+1 Rkt+1 rkt+1 Pt+1 + (1 − d) Pk0 ,t+1 ≡ Pk 0 t Bankers • each has net worth, Nt . • a banker can only invest in one entrepreneur (asset side of banker balance sheet is risky). • by exerting e§ort, et , a banker finds a good entrepreneur with probability p : p (et ) = ā + b̄et • in t, bankers seek to optimize: Et l t + 1 { p ( et ) h + (1 − p (et )) i g Rt+1 (Nt g + dt ) − Rd,t+1 dt Rbt+1 (Nt + dt ) − Rbd,t+1 dt h • Bankers have a cash constraint: Rbt+1 (Nt + dt ) ≥ Rbd,t+1 dt i 1 } − e2t 2 Bankers and their Creditors • Bankers and Mutual Funds interact in competitive markets for loan contracts: # g dt , et , Rd,t+1 , Rbd,t+1 $ • Free entry and competition among mutual funds implies: g p (et ) Rd,t+1 + (1 − p (et )) Rbd,t+1 = Rt • Two scenarios: — banker e§ort, et , is observed by mutual fund — banker e§ort, et , is unobserved. Observed E§ort Benchmark • Set to bankers is the # of contracts available $ g dt , et , Rd,t+1 , Rbd,t+1 ’s that satisfy MF zero profits: cash constraint: g p (et ) Rd,t+1 + (1 − p (et )) Rbd,t+1 = Rt , Rbt+1 (Nt + dt ) ≥ Rbd,t+1 dt • Each banker chooses the most preferred contract from the menu. • Key feature of observed e§ort equilibrium: # $ g et = Et lt+1 p0 (et ) Rt+1 − Rbt+1 (Nt + dt ) Unobserved E§ort • In this case, banker always sets et to its privately optimal level, whatever et is specified in the loan contract: # $ g 0 b incentive: et = Et lt+1 p (et ) [ Rt+1 − Rt+1 (Nt + dt ) # $ g − Rd,t+1 − Rbd,t+1 dt ]. • Set to bankers is the # of contracts available $ g dt , et , Rd,t+1 , Rbd,t+1 ’s that satisfy ‘incentive’ in addition to: MF zero profits: cash constraint: g p (et ) Rd,t+1 + (1 − p (et )) Rbd,t+1 = Rt , Rbt+1 (Nt + dt ) ≥ Rbd,t+1 dt • One factor that can make et ine¢ciently low: g — Rd,t+1 > Rbd,t+1 . Source of Ine¢ciency in Unobserved E§ort Model • The presence of a market interest rate in the incentive constraint creates a ‘pecuniary externality’. • Basic idea: — Private cost to bank of higher funds, d : • interest paid on deposits, R. — Social cost of higher d: • R plus damage to bank incentives when R rises with bigger d. • Consequence: equilibrium d may be too high, in which case limit on d is desirable. • Most straightforward to see in a simple two-period setting. — Grateful to Saki Bigio and Emmanuel Fahri for bringing following argument to our attention. Desirability of Borrowing Restrictions in Two Period Version of Model • Bankers and workers live in large, identical households. — as in Gertler-Karadi, Gertler-Kiyotaki. • Representative household’s problem: max u(c0 ) + c1 , {c0 ,c1 ,d} s.t. c0 + d = y, c1 = Rd + p. where p denotes the profits brought home by bankers: h i h i g p = p(e) Rg (N + d) − Rd d + (1 − p(e)) Rb (N + d) − Rbd d . Optimality condition for deposits: R = u0 (y − d ) Desirability of Borrowing Restrictions in Two Period Version of Model • Banker problem (with potentially binding borrowing restriction): max g {Rd ,Rbd ,d,e} h g p (e) R (N g + d) − Rd d i h i 1 + (1 − p (e)) Rb (N + d) − Rbd d − e2 2 h i +n Rb (N + d) − Rbd d n h # $ i o g +h p0 (e) (Rg − Rb )(N + d) − Rd − Rbd d − e +µ(d̄ − d) subject to zero profit condition on loan contract. Desirability of Borrowing Restrictions in Two Period Version of Model • Use zero profit condition and binding cash constraint to g simplify banker problem (drop Rd , Rbd ) : 1 max p (e) Rg (N + d) + (1 − p (e)) Rb (N + d) − Rd − e2 2 {d,e} ( " # ) b (N + d) Rd − R +h p0 (e) (Rg − Rb )(N + d) − −e p(e) +µ(d̄ − d) • Optimality condition for d: p(e)Rg + (1 − p(e))Rb = R + µ 1 + hp0 (e)/p(e) borrowing restriction raises cost of funds above R. . Ramsey Problem in Two Period Version of Model • After substituting out zero profit condition, cash constraint and deposit supply utility of period 0 consumption max{ e,d +h " z }| { u(y − d) 1 + c1 − e2 2 # ! 0 (y − d)d − Rb (N + d) u p0 (e) (Rg − Rb )(N + d) − −e } p(e) s.t. c1 = u0 (y − d)d + p(e)Rg (N + d) + (1 − p(e))Rb (N + d) − u0 (y − d)d Ramsey Problem in Two Period Version of Model • Optimality condition for d: p(e)Rg + (1 − p(e))Rb extra marginal cost associated with extra d = R+ z }| { 0 00 hp (e)/p(e)(−u (y − d))d 1 + hp0 (e)/p(e) . • To get the private d decision to coincide with Ramsey-optimal decision, must choose d̄ so that multiplier, µ, on private problem satisfies: µ = hp0 (e)/p(e)(−u00 (y − d))d > 0 Back to Dynamic Model • Model dynamics requires law of motion for banker net worth. • Introduces an additional borrowing consideration. Law of Motion of Net Worth • Bankers live in a large representative household, with workers. — Bankers pool their net worth at the end of each period (we avoid worrying about banker heterogeneity) • Law of motion of banker net worth Nt+1 = gt+1 {p (et ) zh profits of banks with good assets g Rt+1 (Nt + (1 − p (et )) hz }| i{ g + dt ) − Rd,t+1 dt profits of banks with bad assets Rbt+1 (Nt }| i{ b + dt ) − Rd,t+1 dt } lump sum transfer, households to their bankers + z}|{ Tt+1 Model Assumption that Banks Don’t Systematically Rely on Equity Issues to Finance Assets • Evidence from two sources provide support for this assumption as a description of the data. — Adrian and Shin’s examination of the assets and liabilities of two large French financial firms. — US flow of funds data on assets and liabilities of financial corporations. • Adrian and Shin, ‘Procyclical Leverage and Value-at-Risk’ — Changes in financial firm equity not systematically related to their assets. — Changes in financial firm debt moves one-for-one with changes in assets. .BUFSJBMUBLFOGSPNUIFXPSLPG"ESJBO4IJO %JTQMBZTBTDBUUFSQMPUDIBOHFJOFRVJUZBOEEFCUPOUIFIPSJ[POUBMBYJTBHBJOTUDIBOHFJOBTTFUTPOUIFIPSJ[POUBMBYJT/PUFUIBUUIFTMPQFPGDIBOHFTJOEFCUBHBJOTU DIBOHFTJOBTTFUTJTFTTFOUJBMMZVOJUZXIJMFUIFTMPQFPGDIBOHFTJOFRVJUZBHBJOTUDIBOHFTJOBTTFUTIBTBTMPQFPG[FSP 5IFSFTVMUTBSFDPOTJTUFOUXJUIUIFOPUJPOUIBUUIJTGJOBODJBMDPNQBOZIFBERVBSUFSFEJO1BSJTGJOBODFTDIBOHFTJOBTTFUTXJUIDIBOHFTJOEFCUBOEOPUDIBOHFTJOFRVJUZ BNP Paribas: annual change in assets, equity and debt (1999 - 2010) 500 y = 1.0051x - 6.2 R2 = 0.9987 Change in equity and debt (billion euros) 400 300 Debt Change 200 100 Equity Change 0 -100 -200 -200 -100 0 100 200 300 400 500 Asset change (billion euros) Figure 3. BNP Paribas: annual change in assets, equity and debt (1999-2010) (Source: Bankscope) Discussion of Acharya and Seru 7 Societe Generale: annual changes in assets, equity and debt (1999 - 2010) Annual change in equity and debt (billion euros) 300 250 y = 0.996x - 3.15 R2 = 0.9985 200 150 Debt change 100 50 Equity change 0 -50 -100 -150 -200 -100 0 100 200 300 Annual asset change (billion euros) Figure 4. Société Générale: annual change in assets, equity and debt (1999-2010) (Source: Bankscope) • The model assumes that when bankers want funds, issuing equity is not an option. Borrowing by Private Depository Institutions (Table F.109, Flow of Funds) billions of dollars 800 700 600 open market paper, bonds, other loans, deposits 500 400 300 200 100 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Equity as a source of funds, Private Depository Institutions (F.109, F of F) billions of dollars 12 11 This shows how major debt instruments were used at private depository institutions in the wake of the crisis. 10 9 8 7 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 • The model assumes that when bankers want funds, issuing equity is not an option. Borrowing by Private Depository Institutions (Table F.109, Flow of Funds) billions of dollars 800 700 600 open market paper, bonds, other loans, deposits 500 400 300 200 100 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Equity as a source of funds, Private Depository Institutions (F.109, F of F) billions of dollars 12 11 10 9 8 7 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 ‘Crisis’ • Suppose something makes banker net worth, Nt , drop. • For given dt , bank cash constraint gets tighter: Rbt+1 (Nt + dt ) ≥ Rbd,t+1 dt . • So, Rbd,t+1 has to be low — when Nt is low, banks with bad assets cannot cover their own losses and creditors must share in losses. g — then, creditors require Rd,t+1 high g • So, interest rate spread, Rd,t+1 − Rt , high, banker e§ort low. • Banks get riskier (cross sectional mean return down, standard deviation up). Endogenous Risk • Rate of return on equity, good banks and bad banks: g p (et ) good banks : 1 − p (et ) bad banks : g Rt+1 (Nt + dt ) − Rd,t+1 dt Nt b Rt+1 (Nt + dt ) − Rbd,t+1 dt , Nt =0 • Mean, Ebt+1 , and cross sectional standard deviation, sbt+1 , of return on equity across banks: sbt+1 = [p (et ) (1 − p (et ))] Ebt+1 = p (et ) g Rt+1 (Nt 1/2 g g Rt+1 (Nt + dt ) − Rd,t+1 dt g + dt ) − Rd,t+1 dt Nt • In a crisis, risk rises and mean return falls. Nt Macro Model • Sticky wages and prices • Investment adjustment costs • Habit persistence in consumption • Monetary policy rule Calibration targets Table 2: Steady state calibration targets for baseline model Variable meaning variable name Cross-sectional standard deviation of quarterly non-financial firm equity returns s b magnitude 0.20 Fnancial firm interest rate spreads (APR) 400 R dg Financial firm leverage L R 0.60 20.00 Profits of intermediate good producers (controled by fixed cost, ) 0 Government consumption relative to GDP (controlled by g) 0.20 Growth rate of per capita GDP (APR) 400 Rate of decline in real price of capital (APR) 400 z 1 1 1.65 1.69 Data behind calibration targets Figure 1: Cross-section standard deviation financial firm quarterly return on equity, HP-filtered US real GDP 0.1 0.4 Cross section volatility (left scale) 0.3 0.05 0.2 0 0.1 -0.05 HP filtered GDP (right scale) 0 Q3 1962 -0.1 Q1 1968 Q2 1973 Q4 1978 Q1 1984 Q2 1989 quarterly data Q4 1994 Q1 2000 Q3 2005 Q4 2010 Parameter Values Table 1: Baseline Model Parameter Values Meaning Name Value Panel A: financial parameters return parameter, bad entrepreneur b -0.09 return parameter, good entrepreneur g 0.00 constant, effort function 0.83 slope, effort function b 0.30 lump-sum transfer from households to bankers T 0.38 fraction of banker net worth that stays with bankers 0.85 Panel B: Parameters that do not affect steady state steady state inflation (APR) 400 1 2.40 1.50 Taylor rule weight on inflation Taylor rule weight on output growth curvature on investment adjustment costs 0.50 y smoothing parameter in Taylor rule 0.80 p 5.00 S Calvo sticky price parameter p 0.75 Calvo sticky wage parameter w 0.75 z 1.65 Panel C: Nonfinancial parameters steady state gdp growth (APR) steady state rate of decline in investment good price (APR) 1.69 capital depreciation rate 0.03 production fixed cost 0.89 capital share 0.40 steady state markup, intermediate good producers 1.20 f habit parameter bu household discount rate 100 steady state markup, workers Frisch labor supply elasticity 1/ L g 1 0.52 1.05 w weight on labor disutility steady state scaled government spending 0.74 4 L 1.00 1.00 0.89 Impact of Loss of Bank Net Worth Deposit rate, bad (failed) banks (APR) Interest rate spread (APR) levels levels 3 2.5 −2 1 −4 0.8 levels Bank net worth (N) 3.5 −6 −8 −10 10 15 −14 Std dev, in cross section, financial firm equity returns 0 15 GDP 0.15 0.1 10 −0.6 −0.8 15 5 level −0.6 −0.8 −1 10 5 10 −0.6 −0.8 −1 15 5 2.5 24 2.4 22 2.3 2.2 15 2 10 15 Bank leverage 2.1 −1.2 15 −0.4 Inflation (APR) −0.4 10 −0.2 levels 5 5 Consumption −0.4 Investment % dev, ss 10 % dev, ss 0.2 0.05 5 −0.2 % dev, ss levels 0.25 0.4 0.2 −12 5 0.6 20 18 16 5 10 no leverage restrictions leverage restrictions 15 14 5 10 15 Borrowing Restrictions • Banks taxed for issuing deposits dt — 1.2% AR (versus 3% AR on the risk free nominal rate). — revenues redistributed back to banks in lump-sum form. • What is the consequence of this restriction? — With less dt , banks with bad assets more able to cover losses • interest rate spread falls, so banker e§ort rises. — Second e§ect of borrowing restriction, • borrowing restriction in e§ect implements collusion among bankers • allows them to behave as monopsonists • make profits on demand deposits....lots of profits: h big z}|{ # g $ # $i dt g p ( et ) R −R + (1 − p (et )) Rbt+1 − Rbd,t+1 t+1 d,t+1 Nt • makes Nt grow, o§seting incentive e§ects of decline in dt . Impact of Loss of Bank Net Worth Deposit rate, bad (failed) banks (APR) Interest rate spread (APR) levels levels 3 2.5 −2 1 −4 0.8 levels Bank net worth (N) 3.5 −6 −8 −10 10 15 −14 Std dev, in cross section, financial firm equity returns 0 15 GDP 0.15 0.1 10 −0.6 −0.8 15 5 level −0.6 −0.8 −1 10 5 10 −0.6 −0.8 −1 15 5 2.5 24 2.4 22 2.3 2.2 15 2 10 15 Bank leverage 2.1 −1.2 15 −0.4 Inflation (APR) −0.4 10 −0.2 levels 5 5 Consumption −0.4 Investment % dev, ss 10 % dev, ss 0.2 0.05 5 −0.2 % dev, ss levels 0.25 0.4 0.2 −12 5 0.6 20 18 16 5 10 no leverage restrictions leverage restrictions 15 14 5 10 15 Conclusion • Described a model in which there is a problem that is mitigated by the introduction of borrowing restrictions. • Currently exploring what are the optimal dynamic properties of leverage. — the cyclical behavior of the tax on leverage depends on which shock drives the cycle. — if driven by permanent technology shocks, then act to discourage debt in a boom.