* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Agarwal Daniel Naik
United States housing bubble wikipedia , lookup
Modified Dietz method wikipedia , lookup
Greeks (finance) wikipedia , lookup
Rate of return wikipedia , lookup
Private equity wikipedia , lookup
Shadow banking system wikipedia , lookup
Interbank lending market wikipedia , lookup
Syndicated loan wikipedia , lookup
Private equity secondary market wikipedia , lookup
Fundraising wikipedia , lookup
Money market fund wikipedia , lookup
Investment fund wikipedia , lookup
Flows, Performance, and Managerial Incentives in the Hedge Fund Industry Vikas Agarwal Georgia State University Naveen D. Daniel Georgia State University and Narayan Y. Naik London Business School JEL Classification: G10, G19 This version: September 1, 2003 ____________________________________________ Vikas Agarwal and Naveen D. Daniel are from Georgia State University, Robinson College of Business, 35, Broad Street, Suite 1221, Atlanta GA 30303, USA: e-mail: [email protected] (Vikas) and [email protected] (Naveen) Tel: +1-404-651-2699 (Vikas) +1-404-651-2691 (Naveen) Fax: +1-404-651-2630. Vikas Agarwal is a Research Associate with EDHEC. Narayan Y. Naik is from London Business School, Sussex Place, Regent's Park, London NW1 4SA, United Kingdom: e-mail: [email protected] Tel: +44-207-262-5050, extension 3579 Fax: +44-207-7243317. We would like to thank Nicole Boyson, Conrad Ciccotello, William Fung, Mila Getmansky, Paul Gompers, William Goetzmann, Jason Greene, Roy Henriksson, David Hsieh, Robert Kosowski, Lalitha Naveen, Sebastien Pouget, Stefan Reunzi, Krishna Ramaswamy, Ivo Welch, and participants at the Autumn seminar of INQUIRE Europe in Stockholm, All-Georgia conference, EFA 2003 meetings in Glasgow, FMA European 2003 meetings in Dublin, Georgia State University, London Business School and Wharton Hedge Fund conference for many helpful comments and constructive suggestions on an earlier version of this paper. This paper was adjudged the best paper on hedge funds at the European Finance Association (EFA) 2003 meetings in Glasgow. We are grateful for funding from INQUIRE Europe. We are grateful to Josh Rosenberg of Hedge Fund Research Inc., Chicago, TASS Investment Research Ltd., London and Zurich Capital Markets, Switzerland for providing us with the data on individual hedge funds and hedge fund indexes. We are thankful to Otgontsetseg Erhemjamts, Purnendu Nath, and Subhra Tripathy for excellent research assistance. We are responsible for all errors. Flows, Performance, and Managerial Incentives in the Hedge Fund Industry Abstract Using a comprehensive database of individual hedge funds and funds of hedge funds, we investigate the determinants of money-flow and performance in the hedge fund industry. We have several important findings. First, good performers in a given year experience significantly larger money-flows in the subsequent year and this performance-flow relation is convex. Second, funds with persistently good (bad) performance attract larger (smaller) inflows compared to those that show no persistence. Third, we find that money-flows are positively associated with managerial incentives measured by the delta of the option-like incentive-fee contract offered to hedge fund managers. Fourth, when we examine the relation between flows and future performance, we find that larger hedge funds with greater inflows are associated with worse performance in the future, a result consistent with decreasing returns to scale in the hedge fund industry. Fifth, we find that funds with better managerial incentives (those with greater delta) are associated with better performance in the future. Finally, we find that unlike individual hedge funds, funds of hedge funds enjoy economies of scale. Overall, these results significantly improve our understanding of the complex interaction between money-flows, performance, and managerial incentives in the hedge fund industry. 2 Flows, Performance, and Managerial Incentives in the Hedge Fund Industry In recent years, the hedge fund industry has emerged as an alternative investment vehicle to the traditional mutual fund industry. It differs from the mutual fund industry in two important ways. First, hedge funds are much less regulated compared to mutual funds, with limited transparency and disclosure. Second, hedge funds charge performance-based incentive fees, which help align the interests of manager and investors. These differences have important implications for investment behavior of capital providers and the incentives of the hedge fund managers to deliver superior performance. Therefore, in this paper, we investigate the complex interaction between flows, performance, and managerial incentives in the hedge fund industry. Due to legal restrictions placed on advertising by hedge funds and limited disclosure, investors face significant search costs in selecting hedge funds. While we have a reasonable idea of the factors investors consider before placing their money in mutual funds (Ippolito, 1992; Chevalier and Ellison, 1997; Goetzmann and Peles, 1997; Sirri and Tufano, 1998), pension funds (Del Guercio and Tkac, 2002) and private equity funds (Kaplan and Schoar, 2003), we have limited understanding of the determinants of money-flows in the hedge fund industry. Given the institutional differences between hedge funds and traditional asset management vehicles, different factors may be influencing the investors’ fund selection process. This leads us to our first research question. What are the determinants of money-flows in the hedge fund industry? In particular, how do the money-flows relate to a fund’s past performance (returns and persistence in returns), managerial incentives (call option-like incentive fee structure), and other fund characteristics (size, volatility, and age)? Active money management has long been considered as a puzzle to financial economists (Gruber, 1996). For example, it is not clear why investors devote resources to evaluate past 3 performance and chose funds on that basis, when future performance seems to be unrelated to past performance. To resolve this puzzle, Berk and Green (2002) present a model of active portfolio management where such behavior arises as a rational response on the part of the investors. They argue that investors’ propensity to chase past performance drives the lack of performance persistence found in the empirical literature. An important assumption underlying their model is that the managers face decreasing returns to scale and therefore, money-flows into better performing funds lower their abnormal returns in future. This leads us to our second research question. What is the relation between money-flows and fund’s future performance (returns and the likelihood of persistence in its future returns)? Furthermore, in case of hedge funds, managerial incentives in the form of option-like incentive-fee contract play an important role in motivating the managers to perform better. Therefore, we also examine the relation between managerial incentives (proxied by the delta of the option-like incentive-fee contract) and future performance. Finally, we examine funds of hedge funds (henceforth FOFs), a rapidly growing segment of the hedge fund industry. These intermediaries invest in other hedge funds. In order to search, select, monitor, and track the performance of individual hedge funds, they charge a fixed management fee and a performance-based incentive fee. Thus, an investor in FOFs encounters an additional layer of agency. However, FOFs offer certain benefits including diversification, due diligence, professional management, and potential access to star managers of hedge funds that may be closed to new investors. This leads us to our third and final research question. What are the determinants of money-flows and performance in FOFs and whether they are different from those in case of individual hedge funds? We conduct our investigation by merging three leading hedge fund databases: Hedge Fund Research (HFR), TASS, and Zurich Capital Markets/Managed Accounts Reports 4 (ZCM/MAR). Our database contains return histories for 1776 live and 1655 dead individual hedge funds and 352 live and 187 dead FOFs. Using the merged database, we make four important contributions to the hedge fund literature. First, we conduct a comprehensive study of the determinants of money-flows into the hedge fund industry. Goetzmann, Ingersoll, and Ross (2003) (henceforth GIR) is the only paper to study this issue by conducting a univariate analysis of money-flows and past returns. We believe that in addition to past returns, investors consider various other factors such as fund size, age, volatility, and more importantly, managerial incentives in the form of degree of moneyness of the manager’s option-like incentive-fee contract. For example, an investor may be reluctant to invest his money in a small, young, and highly volatile fund, which is significantly below its high-water mark.1 In addition to these factors, investors may also be paying attention to consistency in performance of a fund. Arguably, investors prefer to place their money in funds with persistently above-median returns. Therefore, we also examine the relation between flows and persistence in past performance, a previously unstudied phenomenon. Second, we make an important contribution to the extant literature by explicitly measuring the managerial incentives through the delta of the manager’s option-like incentive-fee contract. Performance-based compensation is an important tool to motivate the manager to perform well.2 However, the incentive fee as a percentage of profits, per se, does not take into account how far the fund is relative to its high-water mark. For example, Ackermann, McEnally, and Ravenscraft (1999, pp. 860) acknowledge the limitations of using only incentive fees as a metric for managerial incentives as follows: “The problem is that the relationship between high1 Fund size and age may proxy for managerial skill and hence, investors’ confidence in a particular fund. Prior literature on hedge funds (Ackermann, McEnally, and Ravenscraft, 1999; Brown, Goetzmann, and Ibbotson, 1999; Liang, 1999; Edwards and Caglayan, 2001) has examined the relation between incentive fees and performance 2 5 water marks, incentive fees, and volatility is complicated. The relationship should depend on where the fund is relative to its high-water mark. This is further complicated by the fact that new investors may have different high-water marks than original investors.” We specifically address this issue and determine the managerial incentives by measuring the delta of the manager’s incentive-fee option. For this purpose, we compute a fund’s yearly money-flows since the start of a fund’s return history. We then estimate fund’s delta after applying the hurdle rate and highwater mark provisions to yearly money-flows from both new and original investors. We measure delta as the dollar increase in the incentive-fee-based compensation of the manager for an increase of one percent in the fund’s return. Clearly, delta depends on the degree of moneyness of the options granted to the manager by annual inflows. The larger is the value of delta, the greater is the incentive to deliver superior returns. This is the first attempt in the hedge fund literature to empirically quantify the level of incentives, in dollar terms, offered by the performance-based-compensation contracts. Third, we examine the relation between current flows and future performance and address the issue of decreasing returns to scale in the hedge fund industry. This is an important issue that underpins Berk and Green’s (2002) model. In addition, as argued above, highpowered incentives should motivate the manager to perform better. Towards that end, we also examine the relation between manager’s option-delta and future performance, an issue hitherto unexplored in the hedge fund literature. Finally, we make an important contribution to the literature by analyzing the determinants of money-flows and performance for FOFs. Due to the double-fee arrangement, Brown, Goetzmann, and Liang (2002) argue that FOFs face different incentives compared to and, in general, has found a positive relation between the two. See Elton, Gruber and Blake (2003) for the performance of mutual funds that charge incentive fees. 6 individual hedge funds. Therefore, we also examine how money-flows and performance relate to managerial incentives. We have six main findings. First, we find money-flows chase returns and the performance-flow relation is convex. This finding is consistent with that of Chevalier and Ellison (1997), Goetzmann and Peles (1997), and Sirri and Tufano (1998) in the mutual fund industry. Our finding, however, differs from that of GIR (2003), who find that the best performers experience outflows. They argue that this may be due to good performers being reluctant to accepting new money. It is important to note that presence of such managers in our sample biases against finding evidence of money chasing good performance. We believe that the differences in regulatory and market environments during the two sample periods may be responsible for the differences in GIR’s and our results. For example, the National Securities Markets Improvement Act of 1996 removed the restriction on the maximum of 99 qualified investors. Further, during our sample period, data on individual hedge funds and indexes started becoming widely available, which made it easier for investors to compare the performance a hedge fund with its peer group. To assess the impact of these changes, we re-run GIR’s univariate specification using only offshore funds from our composite database during 1989-1995. We find that instead of outflows, the top performers experience flows that are indistinguishable from zero. This suggests that the nature of the hedge fund industry has indeed changed over time, and in recent years it has started resembling the mutual fund industry. Our second finding pertains to the relation between flows and persistence in performance. Following Brown, Goetzmann, and Ibbotson’s (1999) approach, we label a fund as a winner (loser) if its return in a given year is above (below) median return of peer-group funds. We classify a fund as persistent winner (loser) if it is a winner (loser) for two successive years. We 7 find that money-flows are significantly higher (lower) for funds that are persistent winners (losers). Our third finding concerns the relation between money-flows and managerial incentives. We find a positive relation between flows and delta, which confirms that investors prefer to place their money in funds where the manager has greater incentives to perform better. Since delta incorporates information about the entire history of returns and money-flows, this finding suggests that investors take into account historical returns as well as money-flows. Our fourth finding pertains to the relation between current money-flows and future performance. We find that flows into larger funds are associated with lower returns in the future. Further, they are also associated with lower probability of those funds showing good persistence in the future. This finding is consistent with the presence of decreasing returns to scale in the hedge fund industry. It is also consistent with the findings of Chen et al (2002) for the mutual fund industry. Fifth, we find future performance to be positively related to managerial incentives. This suggests that investors prefer funds where the manager has higher incentives to perform well in the future, where good performance is reflected in higher returns and higher probability of exhibiting good persistence. Our final result relates to FOFs. When we analyze this intermediated sector of the hedge fund industry, we find that FOFs with good performance (higher returns or good persistence) attract greater money-flows. While this finding is similar to that for individual hedge funds, there are two important differences. First, we find no significant relation between managerial incentives, flows, and future performance. This suggests that investors’ preferences and funds’ performance in response to managerial incentives are different for FOFs. Second, we find that larger flows into bigger FOFs are positively related to future returns and to the probability of 8 showing good persistence. This suggests that FOFs may be enjoying economies of scale. It is also consistent with the notion that FOFs with substantial assets under management may have greater bargaining power and enjoy better access to well-performing managers that may otherwise be closed for new money. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section I describes the data. Sections II and III examine the relation between new money-flows, managerial incentives, and past performance. Section IV and V investigate the relation between money-flows, managerial incentives, and future performance. Section VI offers concluding remarks with suggestions for future research. I. Data A. Data Description In this paper, we construct a comprehensive hedge fund database that is a union of three large databases namely HFR, TASS, and ZCM/MAR.3 This enables us to resolve occasional discrepancies among different databases as well as create a sample that is more representative of the entire hedge fund industry. We consider both individual hedge funds as well as FOFs for the purpose of our study. Our sample period extends from January 1994 to December 2000. We focus on this period for three reasons. First, the number of funds prior to our sample period is relatively few. Second, the databases do not extensively cover “dead” funds before 1994.4 Finally, publicly disseminated data on hedge fund indexes became available only since 1994, 3 In the past, researchers have used one or more of the three major hedge fund databases. For example, Fung and Hsieh (1997) use TASS database, Ackermann, McEnally, and Ravenscraft (1999) use HFR and ZCM/MAR databases, Agarwal and Naik (2000, 2003) and Liang (2000) uses HFR and TASS databases, while Brown, Goetzmann, and Park (2001) use data from Offshore Funds Directory and TASS. 4 It is important to note that the word “dead” is misleading and “missing-in-action” may be a more appropriate term as they include funds that are liquidated, merged/restructured, and funds that stopped reporting returns to the database vendors but may have continued operations. However, in order to be consistent with previous research, we 9 which enabled investors to assess the relative performance of a fund more easily. Therefore, we conduct our analysis using 1994-2000 data. Table I (Panels A and B) provides the breakdown of funds from different data vendors. After merging the three databases, we find that there are 1776 (352) live hedge funds (FOFs) and 1655 (187) dead hedge funds (FOFs).5 Figure 1 reports the overlap between the three databases via Venn diagrams. The Venn diagrams in Figure 1 show that there is an overlap of 30% (41%) in the number of hedge funds (FOFs) across the three databases, with HFR having the largest coverage (54%). These Venn diagrams demonstrate that there are a large number of hedge funds that are unique to different databases and thus, merging them helps in capturing a more representative sample of the hedge fund industry. Even though hedge funds market themselves as “absolute performers”, investors arguably evaluate the performance of a hedge fund relative to its peers. Unfortunately, there is no universally acceptable way of classifying hedge funds into different styles. Academic research (Fung and Hsieh, 1997; Brown and Goetzmann, 2003) shows that there are five to eight distinct style factors in hedge fund returns. Following these insights, we classify the reported hedge fund strategies into four broad categories: Directional, Relative Value, Security Selection, and MultiProcess Traders. Appendix A describes the mapping between the data vendors’ classification and our classification. Table I Panel C reports the distribution of hedge funds across the four broad strategies. Table II reports the means and medians of monthly net-of-fee returns, volatility of returns, age, management and incentive fees for individual hedge funds and FOFs. We find that, in continue to call them “dead” funds. 5 We exclude managed futures, natural resources, mutual funds, and ‘other’ hedge funds since these categories are not usually considered as “typical” hedge funds. We also exclude long-only, Regulation D and funds with missing strategy information. 10 general, FOFs have significantly lower returns and volatility, higher age and management fee but lower incentive fee compared to individual hedge funds. Lower returns of FOFs can be attributed, in part, to lesser biases compared to hedge funds (Fung and Hsieh, 2000) while the lower volatility of FOFs can be explained by the diversified nature of their portfolios. B. Computation of Money-Flows We first compute dollar flows for fund i during month m as follows Dollar Flowi , m = AUM i , m − AUM i , m −1 (1 + Ri , m ) (1) where, AUM i ,m and AUM i ,m −1 are the size for fund i at the end of month m and month m-1 and Ri ,m is the return for fund i during month m.6 We aggregate the monthly flows during the year t to estimate annual flows (Annual Dollar Flowi,t). As in Chevalier and Ellison (1997) and Sirri and Tufano (1998), we scale annual dollar flows by beginning-of-year assets under management to capture the change in size due to net money-flows. Flowi,t = Annual Dollar Flowi ,t (2) AUM i ,t −1 In Table III, we report the trend in assets under management (AUM) and money-flows in the hedge fund industry. As can be seen from Table III, the total assets under management for hedge funds have grown five-fold from $40 billion to $201 billion from December 1993 to December 2000. Over the same period, the total assets under management for FOFs have also grown from $9 billion to $25 billion. We observe that, in general, more than 25% of funds experience 6 This formula assumes that the fund flows occur at the end of the month. For the sake of robustness, we also compute money-flows assuming that they occur at the beginning of the month and find very similar results. When AUM data is not available at a monthly frequency, we compute flows for coarser intervals. 11 outflows. Further, the mean flows are systematically higher than the median flows suggesting that some funds experienced significant growth in the assets under their management. C. Computation of Managerial Incentives One of the distinguishing differences between mutual funds and hedge funds is the manager’s compensation contract. Unlike most mutual funds, hedge funds charge incentive fees as a fixed percentage of the profits earned. Typically, incentive-fee contracts include hurdle rate and high-water mark provisions. Hurdle rate (usually a rate of return on cash or LIBOR) is the minimum return that the manager needs to achieve before claiming any incentive fees. Highwater mark requires the manager to make up for the previous losses before he can earn incentive fees. Hence, incentive-fee contracts are essentially a call-option on the assets under management with the exercise price depending on the hurdle rate and high-water mark provisions. An incentive fee contract amounts to the investor having written a fraction of a call option on the assets under management. For example, if incentive fee equals 20 percent, then it is equivalent to the investor having written 0.2 of a call option on the money invested. When money gets invested in a fund at different points in time, each investment is associated with its own high-water mark. In addition, when a hurdle rate is specified, the manager must exceed it before he can claim an incentive fee. Therefore, in general, incentive-fee contracts endow the manager with a portfolio of call options. The value of the each of the call options depends on the time when the money came in, its high-water mark and whether the return exceeds the hurdle rate or not. 12 The option-like compensation provides the fund manager with incentives to deliver superior returns.7 We proxy these incentives by the delta of the portfolio of options, which equals the dollar change in the incentive fee for a one percent change in the fund’s return. The greater the delta, larger is the incentive to deliver superior returns. We describe the procedure of computing delta in Appendix B. By definition, delta depends on the degree of moneyness of the portfolio of options generated by money-flows over time, which in turn, depends on whether a fund has had a negative return in a year or in previous years. Clearly, if the fund has had negative returns during a year, the fund will be below its high-water mark. However, a fund with a positive return in a given year could still be below its high-water mark if its cumulative negative returns in prior years exceed the positive return in the current year. We report the summary statistics of funds with negative returns and those below high-water mark in Panel B of Table III. In case of individual hedge funds, we find that the percentage of funds with negative returns has increased from 8.4% to 33.1% from December 1993 to December 2000. The mean (median) losses also increased from 11.2% (7.9%) to 19.9% (15.0%) over this period. Consistent with our discussion above, a larger proportion of funds are below their high-water mark (50.2% and 51.3% in December 1993 and December 2000 respectively). The shortfall below high-water mark for these funds will however be smaller than the magnitude of loss in that year because it includes funds that have positive returns during that year and are below high-water mark due to poor return history. As expected, the mean (median) shortfall below high-water mark varies from 2.9% (0.3%) in December 1993 to 8.3% (1.2%) in December 2000. The results for FOFs are qualitatively similar to those for individual funds. 7 It is important to note that option-like payoffs also influence risk-taking incentives of hedge fund managers. Agarwal, Daniel, and Naik (2003) examine these and find that fund volatility is positively related to both implicit 13 Finally, we report the summary statistics of delta in Panel C of Table III.8 Over the sample period, we find that mean (median) delta across all hedge funds has increased from $130,000 ($30,000) in December 1993 to $240,000 ($50,000) in December 2000. In contrast, across all FOFs, the mean (median) delta has decreased from $170,000 ($20,000) to $80,000 ($10,000) over the same period.9 II. Determinants of Money-Flows In this section, we investigate the determinants of money-flows into and out of individual hedge funds and FOFs. It may be that investors follow a top-down approach where they first choose the broad strategies in which to invest, and then decide in which funds to invest. Therefore, as a first step, we explore the performance-flow relation at a strategy level. For this purpose, we sum up annual dollar flows across all funds within a strategy and obtain aggregate strategy-level flows. We plot in Figure 2 the annual dollar flows against prior-year’s weighted average returns of the funds following different strategies. We use both equally-weighted and value-weighted (weighted by AUM) returns at the strategy level. Figure 2 suggests that, in general, money-flows chase recent performance for all four strategies as well as for all the funds considered together. We investigate this finding further at an individual fund level using our composite database. When investors infer a manager’s ability through past returns, one would expect to find that funds that have performed especially well in the recent past would attract larger money-flows. and explicit risk-taking incentives. 8 We measure delta in millions of dollars. However, it is simple to convert our dollar delta into the standard Black and Scholes (1973) call option delta by dividing our dollar delta by (0.01*incentive fee*investors’ assets). 9 Like hedge fund managers, top executives of corporations receive option-like payoffs, which create similar managerial incentives. It is interesting to compare the level of managerial incentives in these two industries. Coles, Daniel, and Naveen (2003) report the mean (median) delta of executive stock options for the top 1500 firms in S&P 14 For poorly performing funds, one may not find significant outflows due to impediments unique to the hedge fund industry such as lockup period, notice period, and redemption period. There are two additional factors that may also affect the performance-flow relation. First, investors may place less weight on the recent performance as some of the hedge fund managers could show a good previous track record. Second, some of the well-performing hedge funds may be closed to new investment. For these funds, we would find no money inflows despite their good performance. This will lower the likelihood of finding that money-flows chase good performance. Our empirical analysis captures the net effect of all these factors. To examine the performance-flow relation, we need to categorize performance as good or bad. While it would be useful to estimate risk-adjusted performance, this is a perilous task given the non-normality in hedge funds returns and option-like dynamic trading strategies adopted by hedge funds (Fung and Hsieh, 1997, 2001; Goetzmann et al, 2002; Agarwal and Naik, 2003). Therefore, we use returns relative to one’s peer group as a measure of performance. In order to compare our findings for hedge funds, with those of Sirri and Tufano (1998) for mutual funds, we follow an identical empirical procedure. We classify each fund-year observation into one of five quintiles based on performance. We find that the average inflow into funds in the top (first) quintile is 63% compared to an average outflow of 3% for funds in the bottom (fifth) quintile. We find a similar performance-flow relation for FOFs as well. In particular, the top quintile performers attract inflow of 25% compared to outflow of 15% for the bottom quintile performers.10 during 1992-2000 to be $584,000 ($196,000). See Murphy (1999) and Core, Guay, and Larcker (2003) for a survey of literature on executive compensation. 10 For hedge funds, the t-test shows that the difference in the flows between all the adjacent quintiles (e.g., top and second, second and third, and so on) is significantly different (p-value=0.000). For FOFs, the t-test shows that only the difference in the flows between top and second, and fourth and bottom quintile is significantly different. 15 A. Performance-flow relation for individual Hedge Funds Arguably, investors consider factors in addition to performance, such as size, volatility, age, managerial incentives, and past flows before making their investment decisions. Therefore, we examine the relation between flows and performance using a multivariate regression that controls for other potential determinants of money-flows. We specify the following regression: 5 ( ) Flowi ,t = β 0 + ∑ β1j Qranki j,t −1 +β 2 ( Deltai ,t −1 ) + β 3 Sizei ,t −1 + β 4 (σ i ,t −1 ) + β 5 I ( AgeTopi ,t −1 ) j =1 3 + β 6 I ( AgeBottomi ,t −1 ) + β 7 ( MFeei ,t ) + β 8 ( Flowi ,t −1 ) + β 9 ( Ri ,t ) + ∑ β10s I ( Strategyi , s ) + ε i ,t s =1 (3) where, Flowi ,t and Flowi ,t −1 are the money-flows in fund i in years t and t-1, Qranki ,jt −1 is the fractional rank of fund i in quintile j for year t-1, Deltai ,t −1 is the natural logarithm of delta of the managers’ incentive-fee-contract for fund i as of end of year t-1,11 Sizei ,t −1 is the size of the fund measured as the natural logarithm of the AUM for fund i at time t-1, σ i ,t −1 is the standard deviation of the monthly returns of fund i during year t-1, I ( AgeTopi ,t −1 ) is an indicator variable that takes the value 1 if the fund age is in the top one-third of funds at the end of year t-1, I ( AgeBottomi ,t −1 ) is an indicator variable that takes the value 1 if the fund age is in the bottom one-third of funds at the end of year t-1, MFeei ,t is the management fees charged by fund i in year t, Ri ,t is the return of fund i in year t, I ( Strategyi , s ) are strategy dummies that take the value 1 if fund i belongs to strategy s, and ε i ,t is the error term. 11 We measure delta in millions of dollars and take its natural logarithm to mitigate the outlier effect. 16 We construct the fractional rank quintiles, Qranki ,jt −1 as per Sirri and Tufano (1998). First, each fund is given a fractional rank, Frank, from 0 through 1 based on returns in year t-1. This fractional rank represents its percentile performance relative to other funds in the same period. We estimate the coefficients on fractional ranks using piecewise linear regression framework over five quintiles. Towards that end, we define Qrank 1 , the bottom quintile rank, to equal Min (0.2, Frank), Qrank 2 = Min (0.2, Frank- Qrank 1 ) and so forth up to the highest performance quintile, Qrank 5 , i.e., the top quintile. The slope coefficients on these piecewise decompositions of fractional ranks represent the slope of the performance-flow relation over their range of sensitivity. Sirri and Tufano (1998) argue that the use of Fama and MacBeth (1973) procedure “produces more conservative estimates of the significance levels” of their coefficient estimates compared to those from pooled regression. Hence, we follow Fama and MacBeth (1973) procedure. For robustness, we repeat our analysis using pooled regressions and obtain similar results. We report the results of regression based on Fama-MacBeth (1973) procedure in Table IV.12 The results for individual hedge funds in Model 1 show that only the coefficients on the top and the third quintile are significantly positive at the 1% level. This suggests that the wellperforming funds attract significantly higher flows compared to the poorly performing ones. The coefficient on the top quintile (coeff=1.757) implies that if a fund moves 10 percentile in the highest performance group, it will attract incremental inflows of 18%. The magnitude of the top quintile coefficient is similar to that documented by Sirri and Tufano (1998) for mutual funds. Also, the R-square of our model (about 13%) is of the same order of magnitude as Sirri and 12 To minimize the influence of outliers, we winsorize top 1% of the annual returns, standard deviation, assets under management, and net flows. 17 Tufano (1998). Our R-square is considerably higher than R-square (about 4%) obtained from univariate analysis in GIR (2003), confirming the importance of controlling for fund-specific factors in addition to fund returns. To examine if there is convexity in flow-performance relation, we conduct a Chow test on a pairwise basis on adjacent performance quintiles. In case of individual hedge funds, we find that only the third and fourth quintile coefficients are significantly different from each other (pvalue=0.08). This suggests that in case of individual hedge funds, the kink in the performanceflow relation occurs at the 40th percentile as compared to the 80th percentile kink documented by Sirri and Tufano (1998) in case of mutual funds.13 Chevalier and Ellison (1997) document that the money-flows of older funds are less sensitive to recent returns. Thus, we examine if the convexity of performance-flow relation varies across age for individual hedge funds. For this purpose, we interact the terms for the five performance quintiles and those for the two age dummies and re-estimate the regression in equation (3) after including these interaction terms (not reported for the sake of brevity). Chow test results indicate kinks at the 40th, 60th, and 80th percentile for younger funds, and none for the middle-age and older funds. This suggests that similar to mutual fund industry, flows into the younger funds appear to be more sensitive to recent performance. We investigate the possibility that investors might consider coarser performance groups by combining the middle three quintiles into one group as in Sirri and Tufano (1998).14 The results in Model 2 of Table IV show that the coefficient of the top quintile (coeff=1.474) and the middle three quintiles pooled together (coeff=0.743) are significantly positive at the 5% and 1% level 13 14 Interestingly, Kaplan and Schoar (2003) find a concave performance-flow relationship in private equity funds. Here, the middle quintile rank is given by Min (0.6, Frank – Qrank1). 18 respectively, while the bottom quintile coefficient is indistinguishable from zero. These results are once again consistent with those from the five-quintile specification in Model 1. A.1 Relation between Flows and Managerial Incentives As discussed earlier, performance-related fee provides strong incentives to the manager to perform better. Managers whose funds are near or at their high-water marks face better incentives compared to those substantially below their high-water marks. We capture these incentives through delta. It is important to note that delta incorporates information about the entire history of returns and money-flows. Greater the delta, greater are the managerial incentives. Recognizing this effect, investors may prefer to invest in funds with greater delta. Therefore, we expect to find a positive relation between flows and delta. The results for individual hedge funds (in Models 1 and 2) show that the slope coefficient for delta is positive and significant (coeff.=0.011). The impact of delta is economically significant. An increase in the delta from 25th percentile ($10,000) to 75th percentile ($131,000) is associated with an increase in annual flows by 2.8% compared to the median flow of 11.7%. These findings suggest that investors recognize the importance of managerial incentives and accordingly invest in funds where managers have better incentives, namely, funds with higher delta.15 A.2 Relation between Flows and other factors Next, we examine the relation between money-flows and other fund characteristics such as size and age. From Table IV, we observe that the slope coefficient on fund size is significantly 15 For robustness, we examine if there is non-linear relation between flows and delta by including square of delta in equation (3) and find the slope coefficient to be positive but not significant. 19 negative in both specifications, implying that smaller funds get higher flows. We also find that the coefficient of younger funds dummy is significantly positive, implying that younger funds experience higher flows than the middle-aged funds. Prior literature on mutual funds (Gruber, 1996) has used lagged flows in addition to the fund characteristics discussed above. Lagged flow is an important determinant of flows into hedge funds for a number of reasons. First, lagged flows can proxy for non-performance variables such as reputation and marketing efforts that can influence investors’ decisions. Second, investors may want to stick to their prior decision and continue to invest in the same fund, behavior deemed as status-quo bias. Finally, uninformed investors may herd with others and select funds that have recently experienced larger flows. Therefore, we include lagged flow in equation (3) and find that it is positively related to flows. Previous researchers (Chevalier and Ellison, 1997) have also studied the response of money-flows in mutual funds to contemporaneous returns. Hence, we also include returns Rt at time t in equation (3) and find that flows are positively related to contemporaneous returns. One may argue that lagged flows and contemporaneous returns may not be in the information set of investors. Hence, for robustness, we repeat our analysis by excluding these variables from equation (3) and find that our results remain unchanged. Recent research in mutual funds suggest that there are significant spillover effects, i.e., “star” or well-performing funds within a fund family can lead to an increase in the flows to other funds in that family (Khorana and Servaes, 2000; Massa, 2000; Ivkovich, 2001, Nanda, Wang, and Zheng, 2002). We examine if there are similar spillover effects in the hedge fund industry. Unlike mutual funds, multiple-fund families are rare in hedge funds. The average number of funds per family across our sample period is 1.3 (minimum of 1 fund and a maximum of 11 funds per family) with 80% of the funds not belonging to a family. In order to examine spillover 20 effects, we include performance of other funds in a family as an additional explanatory variable in equation (3). In unreported results, we find the slope coefficient on this variable to be positive but not significant. A.3 Comparison of results with Goetzmann, Ingersoll and Ross (2003) Although our findings are consistent with those of Chevalier and Ellison (1997) and Sirri and Tufano (1998) for mutual funds, they differ from those of GIR (2003). We believe that the differences in the regulatory or market environments during the periods covered in the two studies are responsible for the differences in the findings. For example, during our sample period, the restriction on the maximum number of qualified investors was relaxed. Further, data on individual hedge funds as well as a range of hedge fund indexes started becoming widely available. These changes made it easier for investors to obtain information about hedge funds and to compare their performance with peer group. To examine if the differences in the results are indeed attributable to the changing nature of the industry, we repeat our analysis, as in GIR, using only offshore funds from our sample during 1989-1995. Instead of GIR’s finding of outflows for top performers, we find that the top performers experience flows that are indistinguishable from zero (see Appendix C).16 This suggests that the nature of the hedge fund industry has changed over time, and in recent years it has started resembling the mutual fund industry. B. Robustness checks 16 Please note that the two samples will still not be identical as GIR use Offshore Funds directory while we use offshore funds included in the our composite database created by merging HFR, TASS, and ZCM/MAR databases. 21 For our performance-flow regression in equation (3), we need data on annual flows. However, if a fund disappears from our database during a year, it will not have annual flows in the year of its disappearance. Unlike mutual funds, where liquidation due to poor performance is the only reason for fund’s disappearance, hedge funds may disappear for other reasons as well. These reasons include delisting by the data vendor, non-reporting by fund, change in fund names, and mergers (Fung and Hsieh, 2000). Goetzmann and Peles (1997) assign a flow of -100 percent in the last year for those funds that disappear due to poor performance. Following their insights, we examine the robustness of our results by assigning a flow of -100 percent in the last year for funds that disappear due to liquidation. We continue to find no relation between flows and returns for poorly performing funds. This confirms that our results are not sensitive to exclusion of last year’s flows for liquidated funds. This is consistent with the findings of Sirri and Tufano (1998) for mutual funds. Next, we investigate whether the investors consider longer-term performance for making investment decisions. For this purpose, we analyze the fund flows based on the fund’s two-year performance at time t-1. In particular, we form five fractional rank variables based on recent biannual performance. For the sake of brevity, we do not report the results here. We find that none of the performance quintiles come out significant. However, delta continues to be positively related to flows.17 At first sight, lack of significant relation between bi-annual performance quintiles and flows may suggest that investors care more about recent performance. However, it is important to note that delta incorporates the fund’s performance history and investors’ response (in terms of money-flows) to this history. Hence, our finding of positive and significant 17 In addition, size, lagged flows, and contemporaneous returns exhibit significant relation with flows as in Models 1 and 2 in Table IV. 22 relation between flows and delta suggests that investors do take into account the long-term performance of the funds. C. Performance-flow relation for Funds of Hedge Funds Since FOFs are an intermediated sector of hedge fund industry with an additional layer of fees and agency issues, in this subsection, we separately investigate the performance-flow relation for FOFs. For this purpose, we re-estimate regression in equation (3) for FOFs and report our results in Table IV. Results for Model 1 show that the slope coefficient for top quintile is positive and significant at the 5% level (coeff.=2.028). This implies that if a FOF moves 10 percentile in the highest performance group, it will attract incremental inflows of 20%. This increase is of similar order of magnitude to that observed in case of individual hedge funds (18%). Further, we investigate the possibility of investors considering coarser performance groups by combining the middle three quintiles into one group. The results in Model 2 of Table IV show that only the coefficient of the top quintile (coeff=1.850) is significantly positive at the 5% level. These results suggest that the well-performing FOFs attract significantly higher flows than the poorly performing ones in this intermediated sector of the hedge fund industry as well. We conduct Chow test on the pairwise differences in the slope coefficients for adjacent performance rank quintiles. Our results indicate that there are no kink points based on Model 1. However, when we pool the middle three quintiles (Model 2), we obtain a kink at the 80th percentile. Thus, our results using coarser performance groups suggest that there seems to be some evidence of convex performance-flow relation for FOFs. 23 Similar to individual hedge funds, we find the slope coefficient for delta and lagged flows to be positive, but not significant. Furthermore, like in case of hedge funds, we find flows are negatively related to size and positively related to contemporaneous returns. Overall, the findings in this section confirm that money-flows chase recent performance both for individual hedge funds and FOFs. Arguably, in addition to recent performance, investors consider consistently good performance before investing their money into hedge funds and FOFs, an issue we examine in the next section. III. Relation between flows and persistence in prior performance A stronger signal of manager’s ability is persistence in performance and not simply one year of superior performance. Investors therefore should direct more flows to managers who show persistence. Therefore, in this section, we examine the relation between money-flows and persistence in prior performance. To capture persistence, we follow Brown, Goetzmann, and Ibbotson (1999) and Agarwal and Naik (2000) and define a fund to be a winner (loser) in year t, if its returns are greater (less) than the return of the median fund in its peer group in that year. The indicator variable I(Persistent Winneri,t-1) equals 1 if fund i is a winner in years t-1 and t-2, and equals 0 otherwise. Similarly, the indicator variable I(Persistent Loseri,t-1) equals 1 if fund i is a loser in years, t-1 and t-2, and equals 0 otherwise. We investigate the persistence-flow relation by estimating the following regression: Flowi ,t = γ 0 + γ 1 I ( PersistentWinneri ,t −1 ) + γ 2 I ( Persistent Loseri ,t −1 ) + γ 3 ( Deltai ,t −1 ) +γ 4 Sizei ,t −1 + γ 5 (σ i ,t −1 ) + γ 6 I ( AgeTopi ,t −1 ) + γ 7 I ( AgeBottomi ,t −1 ) + γ 8 ( MFeei ,t ) 3 +γ 9 ( Flowi ,t −1 ) + γ 10 ( Ri ,t ) + ∑ γ 11s I ( Strategyi , s ) + ei ,t s =1 (4) 24 We report the results from regression in equation (4) in Table V. Since, we have both Persistent Winner and Persistent Loser indicator variables in the regression, the excluded category of funds is the one that shows reversals, i.e., those who win in one year and lose in the other. We find that the coefficient of Persistent Winner is significantly positive (coeff=0.205) for individual hedge funds implying that the flow is 20.5% higher for funds which exhibit persistently good returns compared to those that exhibit reversals. Similarly, the coefficient of Persistent Loser is significantly negative (coeff=-0.137) for individual hedge funds. This implies that consistently poorly performing funds experience 13.7% lower flows compared to the funds exhibiting reversals. As before, slope coefficient on delta is significantly positive (coeff.=0.012) suggesting that funds with better managerial incentives attract higher flows. An increase in delta from 25th to 75th percentile is associated with 3.1% increase in annual flows. Finally, the slope coefficients of control variables are similar to those in Table IV. In particular, we find that larger funds and higher-volatility funds experience lower flows. We repeat this analysis with FOFs and also report our results in Table V. Like hedge funds, we find that FOFs that are persistent winners experience significantly higher flows compared to those that exhibit reversals. However, unlike hedge funds, we do not find that persistent losers experience lower flows. We also do not find a significant relation with delta. Overall, these findings suggest that investors direct more flows towards persistent winners and less towards persistent losers. Having seen that the flows are positively related to past performance and persistence in past performance, we next examine the relation between flows and future performance as well as persistence in future performance. IV. Relation between flows, incentives, and future performance 25 New money-flows into a fund may hinder its future performance due to decreasing returns to scale. 18 In this section, we shed light on this issue by examining the relation between money-flows into a fund in a given year and its future performance. A. Flows, incentives, and future returns – OLS specification We examine the flow-future performance relation by regressing a fund’s annual returns on prior year’s flows, managerial incentives, size, and other control variables. In particular, we estimate the following regression: Ri ,t = λ0 + λ1 ( Flowi ,t −1 ) + λ2 Sizei ,t −1 + λ3 Sizei ,t −1 ∗ Flowi ,t −1 + λ4 ( Deltai ,t −1 ) + λ5 (σ i ,t −1 ) + λ6 I ( AgeTopi ,t −1 ) + λ7 I ( AgeBottomi ,t −1 ) (5) 3 + λ8 ( MFeei ,t ) + ∑ λ9s I ( Strategyi , s ) + ξi ,t s =1 If there are decreasing returns to scale in the hedge fund industry, one would expect this effect to be especially prominent for larger funds experiencing higher inflows. In order to capture this, we include interaction of size and flows Sizei ,t −1 ∗ Flowi ,t −1 in our regression. As before, we also include controls for age, volatility, and management fee. Since higher delta implies higher incentives to perform better, we expect to see a positive relation between delta and future performance. Table VI reports our findings from the regression in equation (5). The OLS results (Model 1) in Table VI (Panel A) show that the coefficient on size is significantly negative suggesting that larger funds are associated with lower returns in the following year. Further, we find coefficient of interaction term between size and flow to be significantly negative. As this is an interaction between two variables, we examine the effect of the two individually as well as jointly. An increase in the size from 25th to 75th percentile is 18 Chen et al (2002) find that fund size erodes performance in the mutual fund industry. They attribute it to reasons 26 associated with a return decrease of 2.3% in the following year, compared to the median annual return of 12.4%. A similar increase in flow is associated with a return decrease of 0.5%. This suggests that compared to flow, size has a bigger impact on the future fund returns. Finally, an increase in both size and flow from their respective 25th to 75th percentiles is associated with a return decrease of 3.0%. Overall, these results suggest that larger flows into bigger funds are associated with lower returns in the future. This suggests that there may be decreasing returns to scale in the hedge fund industry. When we examine the relation between managerial incentives and future performance, we find that the slope coefficient on delta is positive and significant (coeff.=0.005), implying that higher delta is associated with higher returns in the following year. The impact of delta is economically significant. An increase in the delta from 25th percentile ($10,000) to 75th percentile ($131,000) is associated with a return increase of 1.4% compared to the median annual return of 12.4%. These findings confirm that higher delta provides greater incentives to the managers for better performance. Finally, we find that younger (older) fund dummy to be significantly positive (negative) suggesting that younger (older) funds are associated with better (worse) returns. Since hedge funds invest in relatively illiquid securities, it can induce serial correlation in monthly returns (Getmansky, Lo, and Makarov, 2003). We believe this should not affect our analysis, which uses annual returns. However, for robustness, we include lagged annual returns as a control variable in equation (5). We find that the slope coefficient on lagged returns variable is not significant and our results (not reported) remain unchanged. B. Flows, incentives, and future returns – Logisitic specification such as liquidity and organizational diseconomies. 27 To allow for the possibility that the relation between flows and future performance may be non-linear, we adopt a logistic regression approach. The dependent variable here is WINNER, which takes the value 1 if a fund has above-median annual returns in its peer group.19 Thus, we are interested in understanding how flows are associated with probability of the fund being a winner in the following year. In particular, we estimate logistic regression as follows: WINNERi ,t = φ0 + φ1 ( Flowi ,t −1 ) + φ 2 Sizei ,t −1 + φ3 Sizei ,t −1 ∗ Flowi ,t −1 + φ4 ( Deltai ,t −1 ) +φ4 (σ i ,t −1 ) + φ5 I ( AgeTopi ,t −1 ) + φ6 I ( AgeBottomi ,t −1 ) + φ7 ( MFeei ,t ) + (6) 3 + ∑ φ9s I ( Strategyi , s ) + ζ i ,t s =1 We report the results from this regression for individual hedge funds in Model 2 of Table VI (Panel A). The results for Model 2 show that the slope coefficients on both size as well as the interaction term between size and flow are significantly negative, while that on flow to be positive. Hereafter, for all the logistic regression results, we examine the economic significance of a variable in the following way. We change the variable of interest from 25th to 75th percentile value and then measure its impact on the dependent variable (probability). We then compare it to the implied probability for a median fund.20 Increase in size is associated with a decrease in the probability of being a winner by 4.3%, compared to an implied probability of 55%. In contrast, increase in flow is associated with a decrease in the probability of being a winner by 0.8%. As in the case of OLS results, these findings suggest that size has a bigger impact on fund’s future performance compared to flows. Finally, an increase in both the size and flow is associated with a decrease in the probability of being a winner by 7.1%. These results confirm that larger flows into bigger hedge funds are associated with poor performance in the future. 19 For robustness, we also define a fund as a winner if its returns fall in the top quartile of its peer group and find our results to be qualitatively similar. 20 We compute the implied probability for the median fund as the exponential of the sum-product of slope coefficients and median values of independent variables divided by one plus the exponential of this sum-product. 28 As in case of OLS results, we continue to find a strong relation between delta and future performance implying that funds with better incentives are more likely to be winners. An increase from 25th to 75th percentile in delta is associated with an increase in the probability of being a winner by 2.7%. This positive relation lends justification to investors’ action of directing more money-flows to funds with greater delta. C. Flows, incentives, and future returns – Results for Funds of Hedge Funds We estimate the OLS regression in equation (5) and report the results for FOFs in Table VI (Panel B). Unlike in case of individual hedge funds, our results for Model 1 show that size is positively related to future returns in case of FOFs. However, like in individual hedge funds, the coefficient on interaction term (size*flow) is significantly negative, and coefficient on flow is positive though not significant. An increase in the size is associated with a return increase of 3.0%, compared to the median annual return of 11.8%. A similar increase in flow is associated with a return decrease of 0.7%. This suggests that although flows are negatively associated with future returns in case of FOFs, size has a positive relation with future returns. This suggests that larger size in case of FOFs is an advantage reflected in greater bargaining power and better access to hedge funds with good performance. The overall impact of size and flow on returns is positive and economically significant. An increase in both size and flow is associated with a return increase of 1.7%. Finally, in contrast to individual hedge funds, we do not find any relation between delta and future performance in case of FOFs. We report the results of logistic regression for FOFs in Model 2 of Table VI (Panel B). Again, like in the case of individual hedge funds, we find the slope coefficient for flow to be positive and that for the interaction term (size*flow) to be negative. However, in contrast to the results for individual hedge funds, we now find size coefficient to be positive and significant. An 29 increase in size is associated with an increase in the probability of being a winner by 10.9%, compared to an implied probability of 61.2%. In contrast, an increase in flow is associated with a decrease in the probability of being a winner by 0.7%. These findings confirm our OLS results of flows being negatively related and size being positively related to future performance. Further, as in case of OLS specification, size has a bigger economic impact compared to flows. Finally, an increase in both the size and flow is associated with an increase in the probability of being a winner by 9.4%. Overall, our results confirm that larger flows into bigger FOFs are associated with better future performance and these results are mainly driven by size. Consistent with OLS results, we do not find any relation between delta and future performance in case of FOFs for the logistic regression. Overall, these findings suggest that larger flows into bigger funds are associated with poor performance implying decreasing returns to scale for individual hedge funds. Further, size seems to have a bigger impact on future performance compared to flows. In contrast, there seem to be economies of scale in case of FOFs where bigger size seems to be associated with better performance. Also, managerial incentives captured by delta are positively related to future returns. In the next section, we examine the relation between money-flows and persistence in future returns. V. A. Relation between flows, incentives, and persistence in future returns Flows, incentives, and persistence in future returns – Results for individual hedge funds The previous section documents that larger hedge funds with greater inflows are associated with lower returns in the following year. This section examines whether the flows show a relation with persistence in future performance using a logistic regression framework given below: 30 PersistentWinneri ,t ( Loseri ,t ) = θ 0 + θ1 ( Flowi ,t −1 ) + θ 2 Sizei ,t −1 + θ 3 Sizei ,t −1 ∗ Flowi ,t −1 + θ 4 ( Deltai ,t −1 ) +θ 5 (σ i ,t −1 ) + θ 6 I ( AgeTopi ,t −1 ) + θ 7 I ( AgeBottomi ,t −1 ) + θ 8 ( MFeei ,t ) (7) 3 + ∑θ 9s I ( Strategyi , s ) + π i ,t s =1 where, Persistent Winner and Loser are as defined in Section III. Panel A of Table VII reports the logistic regressions results for individual hedge funds. In Model 1, the dependent variable is Persistent Winner. Based on our results from Model 1, we find that the slope coefficient for size is significantly negative (coeff.=-0.14). The slope coefficients on flow and the interaction term (size*flow) are positive and negative respectively, but insignificant. An increase in size is associated with a decrease in the probability of a fund being a Persistent Winner by 6.1% compared to an implied probability of 28.7%. In contrast, an increase in flow is associated with a decrease in the probability by 0.7%. An increase in both the size and flow is associated with a decrease in the probability by 7.0%. Overall, our results suggest that the larger funds with higher flows are less likely to exhibit consistently good performance indicative of decreasing returns to scale for individual hedge funds. The coefficient on delta is positive and significant (coeff.=0.09) in Model 1, implying that higher delta is associated with a higher probability of being a Persistent Winner. This confirms our earlier results of delta being positively related with future performance. An increase in delta is associated with an increase in the probability by 4.9%. For Persistent Loser as a dependent variable, our results in Model 2 show significantly positive coefficient on interaction term of size and flow (coeff.=0.048). The slope coefficients on flow and size are negative and positive respectively, but insignificant. An increase in size is associated with an increase in the probability of a fund being a Persistent Loser by 1.9% compared to an implied probability of 23.4%. In contrast, an increase in flow is associated with an increase in the probability by 0.2%. Once again, size dominates flow in its relation with future 31 performance. An increase in both the size and flow is associated with an increase in the probability by 2.5%. Overall, our results suggest that the larger funds with higher flows are more likely to exhibit consistently poor performance suggesting decreasing returns to scale in individual hedge funds. Further, we find the slope coefficient on delta is significantly negative (coeff.=-0.06). An increase in delta is associated with a decrease in the probability of being a Persistent Loser by 2.8%. This suggests that better managerial incentives are associated with lower likelihood of a fund being a persistent loser and confirms our earlier results of delta being positively related with future performance. B. Flows, incentives, and persistence in future returns – Results for funds of hedge funds We estimate the logistic regression in equation (7) for FOFs and report our results in Panel B of Table VII. Results in Model 1 show that the slope coefficients for both size and flow are significantly positive (coeffs.=0.396 and 0.568 respectively) while that for their interaction term is significantly negative (coeff.=-0.18). An increase in size is associated with an increase in the probability of a fund being a Persistent Winner by 16.3% compared to an implied probability of 23.8%. In contrast, an increase in flow is associated with a decrease in the probability by 0.3%. An increase in both the size and flow is associated with an increase in the probability by 14.6%. We also do not find a significant relation between delta and probability of being a Persistent Winner. We re-estimate the logistic regression in equation (7) for the case of Persistent Loser and report our results in Model 2 in Table VII (Panel B). We find the slope coefficient on size is significantly negative (coeff.=-0.204) while that on flow is also negative, but not significant. Further, the coefficient on interaction term (size*flow) is positive, though insignificant. An 32 increase in size is associated with a decrease in the probability of a fund being a Persistent Loser by 5.7% compared to an implied probability of 14.9%. In contrast, an increase in flow is associated with an increase in the probability by 0.3%. An increase in both the size and flow is associated with a decrease in the probability by 5.3%. These findings confirm our earlier results of economies of scale being a significant contributor to performance in the case of FOFs. We do not find a significant relation between delta and probability of Persistent Loser. Overall, these findings confirm our earlier OLS results, namely, larger flows into bigger funds are associated with poor performance persistence for individual hedge funds. Again, size seems to have a bigger impact on future persistence compared to flows. In contrast, there seem to be economies of scale in FOFs. Larger FOFs seem to exhibit superior performance, which is different from the result for individual hedge funds. VI. Concluding Remarks In this paper, we conduct an in-depth investigation of the determinants of money-flows in the hedge fund industry and the relation between flows and future performance. We employ a composite database of individual hedge funds and FOFs constructed by merging the HFR, TASS, and ZCM/MAR databases. We contribute to the extant literature by constructing a proxy for managerial incentives through delta of the manager’s option-like incentive-fee contract. We have several new findings. First, money-flows chase good performance and the performance-flow relation seems to be convex in the hedge fund industry. This finding is different from that of Goetmann, Ingersoll, and Ross (2003) in hedge funds but it is consistent with the findings of Chevalier and Ellison (1997), Goetzmann and Peles (1997), and Sirri and Tufano (1998) in mutual funds. Second, money-flows are significantly higher (lower) for funds that show good (bad) persistence. Third, funds with greater managerial incentives enjoy higher 33 flows. Since delta incorporates information about the entire history of returns and money-flows, this finding suggests that investors take into account historical returns as well as money-flows. Fourth, larger flows into bigger funds are associated with poor future performance in terms of lower returns and lower likelihood of being a persistent winner. This finding is consistent with the presence of decreasing returns to scale in the hedge fund industry and lends support to the underlying assumption in Berk and Green’s (2002) model. Fifth, funds with higher delta exhibit better performance, both in terms of returns and persistence in returns. Finally, we show how FOFs differ from individual hedge funds in terms of the relation between money-flows and past as well as future performance. Our findings suggest in contrast to hedge funds, there may be economies of scale in FOFs. Overall, these findings significantly improve our understanding of the behavior of investors and managers in the hedge fund industry. *** *** *** 34 References Ackermann, C., R. McEnally, and D. Ravenscraft, 1999, “The Performance of Hedge Funds: Risk, Return and Incentives,” Journal of Finance, 54 (3), 833-874. Agarwal, Vikas, Naveen D. Daniel, and Narayan Y. Naik, 2003, “Risk-taking Incentives and Hedge Fund Volatility,” Working Paper, Georgia State University and London Business School. Agarwal, Vikas, and Narayan Y. Naik, 2000, “Multi-Period Performance Persistence Analysis of Hedge Funds,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 35 (3), 327-342. Agarwal, Vikas, and Narayan Y. Naik, 2003, “Risks and Portfolio Decisions involving Hedge Funds,” forthcoming Review of Financial Studies. Berk, Jonathan B., and Richard C. Green, 2002, “Mutual Fund Flows and Performance in Rational Markets,” NBER Working Paper No. 9275. Black, Fischer, and Myron Scholes, 1973, “The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities,” Journal of Political Economy, 81(3), 637-654. Brown, S.J., and W.N. Goetzmann, 2003, “Hedge Funds with Style,” Journal of Portfolio Management, 29 (2), 101-112. Brown, S.J., W.N. Goetzmann, and R.G. Ibbotson, 1999, “Offshore Hedge Funds: Survival and Performance 1989-1995,” Journal of Business 72, 91-117. Brown, S.J., W.N. Goetzmann, and Bing Liang, 2002, “Fees on Fees in Funds of Funds,” Working Paper, Case Western Reserve University, New York University, and Yale School of Management. Chen, Joseph, Harrison Hong, Ming Huang, and Jeffrey D. Kubik, 2002, “Does Fund Size Erode Performance? Liquidity, Organizational Diseconomies and Active Money Management,” Working Paper, Princeton University. Chevalier, Judith, and Glenn Ellison, 1997, “Risk Taking by Mutual Funds as a Response to Incentives,” Journal of Political Economy, 105, 1167-1200. Coles, Jeffrey L., Naveen D. Daniel, and Lalitha Naveen, 2003, “Executive Compensation and Managerial Risk-Taking,” Working Paper, Arizona State University and Georgia State University. Core, J.E., W.R. Guay, and David F. Larcker, 2003, “Executive Equity Compensation and Incentives: A Survey,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review, 9(1), 27-50. Del Guercio, D., and Paula A. Tkac, 2002, “The determinants of the flow of funds of managed portfolios: mutual funds versus pension funds,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 37 (4), 523-557. Elton, Edwin J., Martin J. Gruber and Christopher R. Blake, 2003, “Incentive Fees and Mutual Funds,” Journal of Finance, 58 (2), 779-804. Edwards, F. R., and M.O. Caglayan, 2001. “Hedge fund performance and manager skill,” Journal of Futures Markets 21 (11), 1003-1028. Fama, Eugene F., and James D. MacBeth, 1973, “Risk, Return and Equilibrium: Empirical Tests,” Journal of Political Economy, 81 (3), 607-636. Fung, W., and D.A. Hsieh, 1997, “Empirical characteristics of dynamic trading strategies: The case of hedge funds,” Review of Financial Studies, 10, 275-302. Fung, W., and D.A. Hsieh, 2000, “Performance Characteristics of Hedge Funds and CTA Funds: Natural Versus Spurious Biases,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 35 (3), 291307. Fung, W., and D.A. Hsieh, 2001, “The Risk in Hedge Fund Strategies: Theory and Evidence from Trend Followers,” Review of Financial Studies, 14 (2), 313-341. Getmansky, Mila, Andrew W. Lo, and Igor Makarov, 2003, “An Econometric Model of Serial Correlation and Illiquidity in Hedge Fund Returns,” forthcoming Journal of Financial Economics. 35 Goetzmann, W.N., J. Ingersoll, and S.A. Ross, 2003, “High-Water Marks and Hedge Fund Management Contracts,” Journal of Finance, 58 (4), 1685-1718. Goetzmann, W.N., J. Ingersoll, Matthew Spiegel, and Ivo Welch, 2002, “Sharpening Sharpe Ratios,” Working Paper, Yale School of Management. Goetzmann, W.N., N. Peles, 1997, “Cognitive Dissonance and Mutual Fund Investors,” Journal of Financial Research, 20 (2), 145–58. Gruber, Martin, 1996, “Another Puzzle: The growth in actively managed mutual funds,” Journal of Finance 51, 783-810. Ippolito, R.A., 1992, “Consumer reaction to measures of poor quality: evidence from the mutual fund industry,” Journal of Law and Economics, 35 (1), 45-70. Ivkovich, Zoran, 2001, “Is Blood Thicker than Water: Spillovers in Mutual Fund Families,” Working Paper, Yale School of Management. Jorion, Phillipe, 2000, “Risk Management Lessons from Long-Term Capital Management,” European Financial Management, 6, 277-300. Kaplan, Steve, and Antoinette Schoar, 2003, “Private Equity Performance: Returns, Persistence and Capital Flows,” NBER Working Paper 9807. Khorana, Ajay and Henri Servaes, 2001, “An examination of competition and investor behavior in the mutual fund industry,” Working Paper, Georgia Institute of Technology and London Business School. Liang, Bing, 1999, “On the Performance of Hedge Funds,” Financial Analysts Journal, 55, 72-85. Liang, Bing, 2000, “Hedge funds: The Living and the Dead,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 35 (3), 309-326. Liang, Bing, 2003, “The Accuracy of Hedge Fund Returns,” Journal of Portfolio Management, Spring, 111-122. Massa, Massimo, 2000, “Why so many mutual funds? Mutual fund families, market segmentation, and financial performance,” Working Paper, INSEAD. Murphy, K., 1999, “Executive compensation,” in Orley Ashenfelter and David Card (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 3b, Elsevier Science North Holland (1999), Chapter 38: 2485-2563. Nanda, Vikram, Z. Jay Wang, and Lu Zheng, 2002, “Family Values and the Star Phenomenon,” Working Paper, University of Michigan. Sirri, Erik, and Peter Tufano, 1998, “Costly Search and Mutual Fund Flows,” Journal of Finance, 53, 1589-1622. 36 Table I: Breakdown of Funds by Data Sources This table shows the number of hedge funds (Panel A) and funds of hedge funds (Panel B) from the three databases namely HFR, ZCM/MAR, and TASS. Panel C provides the distribution of funds across different strategies. Live funds are those that are operational as of Dec 2000. Dead funds are those that died during our sample period, 19942000. Panel A: Hedge Funds Source HFR TASS ZCM/MAR HFR and TASS HFR and ZCM/MAR ZCM/MAR and TASS HFR, ZCM/MAR and TASS Total Live 395 348 244 205 154 121 309 1776 Dead 712 221 486 13 41 147 35 1655 ALL 1107 569 730 218 195 268 344 3431 Panel B: Funds of Hedge Funds Source HFR TASS ZCM/MAR HFR and TASS HFR and ZCM/MAR ZCM/MAR and TASS HFR, ZCM/MAR and TASS Total Live 61 101 0 34 59 23 74 352 Dead 156 0 0 0 0 15 16 187 ALL 217 101 0 34 59 38 90 539 Panel C: Distribution of Hedge Funds across Strategies Live 21% 22% 45% 12% Strategy Directional Traders Relative Value Security Selection Multi-Process 37 Dead 38% 21% 31% 10% ALL 30% 21% 38% 11% Table II: Cross-Sectional Fund Characteristics This table shows the cross-sectional characteristics of hedge funds and funds of hedge funds during our sample period, 1994-2000. Management fee and incentive fee do not change over time. We report the p-values for the difference between means (Wilcoxon rank-sum test) and for the difference between medians (Median Two-Sample test). Hedge Funds Funds of Hedge Funds p-value Mean 17.23 11.35 0.00 Median 13.26 11.80 0.00 Mean 4.72 3.17 0.00 Median 3.62 2.53 0.00 Mean 4.71 5.07 0.00 Median 3.91 4.34 0.00 Mean 1.22 1.29 0.00 Median 1.00 1.50 0.00 Mean 18.24 8.70 0.00 Median 20.00 10.00 0.00 Fund Characteristics Returns (%) Volatility (Standard Deviation) (%) Age (years) Management Fee (%) Incentive Fee (%) 38 Table III: Trends in Assets under Management, Flows and Managerial Incentives Panel A of this table shows the summary statistics of assets under management (AUM) and net flows while Panel B provides the summary statistics of the funds that have negative returns and are below high-water mark (HWM). Panel C provides the summary statistics of managerial incentives (delta) across hedge funds and funds of hedge funds during the beginning, middle and end of the sample period, i.e. at the end of 1993, 1997, and 2000. Q1 and Q3 indicate the 25th and 75th percentiles. AUM Net Flows (%) Panel A Hedge Funds 12/93 12/97 12/00 12/93 12/97 12/00 Total ($bn) 40.7 136.5 201.0 9.1 13.9 24.8 Mean ($M) 115.0 120.2 135.3 181.0 86.1 90.3 Q1 ($M) 9.3 10.0 12.1 10.5 6.5 9.1 Median ($M) 23.3 30.0 38.4 36.6 21.0 28.0 Q3 ($M) 88.0 89.0 111.0 118.7 67.7 79.0 Mean Q1 Median Q3 101.1 -3.2 27.8 108.7 85.2 -11.1 14.3 75.9 53.9 -15.5 4.1 50.3 84.3 -4.9 8.6 152.3 45.0 -16.3 6.6 58.3 30.3 -14.0 6.7 35.6 Summary Statistics Negative Returns (%) Funds of Hedge Funds 12/97 12/00 12/93 12/97 12/00 8.43 12.04 33.12 5.56 3.74 27.86 Mean -11.24 -15.22 -19.85 -13.32 -7.62 -14.35 Median -7.87 -8.77 -15.04 -13.10 -9.33 -9.29 50.20 43.07 51.29 31.58 31.30 37.44 Mean -2.85 -3.99 -8.28 -2.10 -2.21 -3.25 Median -0.28 -0.00 -1.21 -0.00 -0.00 -0.00 Funds below HWM (%) Shortfall for funds below HWM (%) Panel B Hedge Funds 12/93 Funds with negative returns (%) Delta ($M) Funds of Hedge Funds Summary Statistics Panel C Hedge Funds Funds of Hedge Funds Summary Statistics 12/93 12/97 12/00 12/93 12/97 12/00 Mean 0.13 0.17 0.24 0.17 0.09 0.08 Median 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.02 0.01 0.01 39 Table IV: Fund Flows and Past Performance This table reports average OLS estimates (Fama-MacBeth) using flow as the dependent variable. Flow is the growth rate in the AUM, defined as (AUMt-AUMt-1*(1+Rt))/AUMt-1, where AUMt are the AUM at time t and Rt is the fund return in period t. The independent variables include lagged fractional rank quintiles (quintiles of Rankt-1), logarithm of lagged delta (Deltat-1), lagged size computed as the logarithm of assets under management (Sizet-1), lagged return volatility (Volatilityt-1), lagged age dummies for younger (bottom 33% of age) and older (top 33% of age) funds, management fees, lagged flow (Flowt-1), contemporaneous returns (Returnt), and strategy dummies. Figures marked with ***, **, and * are significant at the 1%, 5%, and 10% respectively. Dependent variable: Flowt Independent Variables Intercept Rankt-1 - Bottom Quintile Rankt-1 - 4th Quintile Rankt-1 - 3rd Quintile Rankt-1 - 2nd-4th Quintile Rankt-1 - 2nd Quintile Rankt-1 - Top Quintile Delta t-1 Sizet-1 Volatilityt-1 Younger Fund dummy Older Fund dummy Management Fee Flowt-1 Returnt Strategy dummies Adjusted R2 Hedge Funds Model 1 Model 2 0.269* 0.291* 0.981 0.609 0.139 1.467*** 0.743*** 0.186 1.757** 1.474** * 0.011 0.011* *** -0.130 -0.129*** -2.277 -2.303 0.129* 0.130* 0.002 0.002 -1.153 -1.348 0.053*** 0.054*** *** 0.674 0.680*** Yes Yes 13.2% 13.3% 40 Funds of Hedge Funds Model 1 Model 2 -0.085 -0.145 1.286 2.294 1.027 -0.548 -0.156 -0.678 2.028** 1.850** 0.008 0.008 -0.078*** -0.085** -3.870 -2.918 -0.047 -0.046 -0.005 0.094 10.778 6.679 0.191 0.188 1.044** 1.072** 25.2% 23.1% Table V: Fund Flows and Persistence in Past Performance This table reports average OLS coefficient estimates (Fama-MacBeth) using flow as the dependent variable. Flow is the growth rate in the assets under management (AUM), defined as (AUMt-AUMt-1*(1+Rt))/AUMt-1, where AUMt are the AUM at time t and Rt is the fund return in period t. The independent variables include persistence at time t-1 and logarithm of lagged delta (Deltat-1). Persistent Winner (Loser) is an indicator variable that takes the value 1 if a fund has annual returns above (below) median in its peer group during years, t-2 and t-1. Other control variables include lagged size computed as the logarithm of assets under management (Sizet-1), lagged return volatility (Volatilityt-1), lagged age dummies for younger (bottom 33% of age) and older (top 33% of age) funds, management fees, lagged flow (Flowt-1), contemporaneous returns (Returnt), and strategy dummies. Figures marked with ***, **, and * are significant at the 1%, 5%, and 10% respectively. Dependent variable: Flowt Independent Variables Hedge Funds Funds of Hedge Funds 0.588** 0.452 Intercept 0.205** 0.125* Persistent Winner dummyt-1 -0.137* -0.037 Persistent Loser dummyt-1 0.012* 0.014 Delta t-1 -0.108*** -0.089 Sizet-1 -1.822** -4.512 Volatilityt-1 0.060 -0.235 Younger Fund dummy -0.008 0.102 Older Fund dummy -1.747 1.653 Management Fee ** 0.151 0.132 Flowt-1 0.584** 0.843 Returnt Yes Strategy dummies 12.9% 9.1% Adjusted R2 41 Table VI: Fund Flows and Future Returns This table reports average OLS coefficient estimates (Fama-MacBeth) using the returns at time t as the dependent variable. This table also reports the logistic regression of WINNER using pooled time-series data. WINNER takes the value 1 if a fund has above-median annual returns in its peer group during year t. The independent variables include the lagged size computed as the logarithm of assets under management (Sizet-1), lagged flow (Flowt-1), interaction of lagged size and lagged flow (Sizet-1* Flowt-1), logarithm of lagged delta (Deltat-1), lagged return volatility (Volatilityt-1), lagged age dummies for younger (bottom 33% of age) and older (top 33% of age) funds, management fees, and strategy dummies. Figures marked with ***, **, and * are significant at the 1%, 5%, and 10% respectively. Panel A: Hedge Funds Independent Variables Intercept Sizet-1 Flowt-1 Sizet-1 * Flowt-1 Delta t-1 Volatilityt-1 Younger Fund Dummy Older Fund Dummy Management Fee Strategy Dummies Adjusted / Pseudo R2 OLS Model 1 Returnst 0.181*** -0.010** 0.011 -0.005* 0.005*** 0.172 0.022* -0.027** -0.736 Yes 10.0% Logistic Model 2 WINNERt 0.60*** -0.08*** 0.12** -0.05*** 0.06*** 0.27 0.12 -0.35*** 1.99 Yes 1.7% Panel B: Funds of Hedge Funds Independent Variables Intercept Sizet-1 Flowt-1 Sizet-1 * Flowt-1 Delta t-1 Volatilityt-1 Younger Fund Dummy Older Fund Dummy Management Fee Adjusted / Pseudo R2 OLS Model 1 Returnst 0.090 0.013* 0.052 -0.020** -0.002 -0.868 0.009 -0.029 0.218 7.1% 42 Logistic Model 2 WINNERt 0.187 0.209*** 0.448* -0.155** 0.018 -12.715** -0.137 -0.210 -1.004 5.0% Table VII: Fund Flows and Persistence in Future Returns This table reports the results of logistic regression using the different performance persistence dummies at time t as the dependent variable. Persistent Winner (Loser) is an indicator variable that takes value 1 if the fund is a winner (loser) in two consecutive years and 0 otherwise, where a fund is a winner if it has above-median annual returns in its peer group in that year. The independent variables include the lagged size computed as the logarithm of assets under management (Sizet-1), lagged flows (Flowt-1), interaction of lagged size and lagged flow (Sizet-1* Flowt-1), logarithm of lagged delta (Deltat-1), lagged return volatility (Volatilityt-1), lagged age dummies for younger (bottom 33% of age) and older (top 33% of age) funds, management fees, and strategy dummies. Figures marked with ***, **, and * are significant at the 1%, 5%, and 10% respectively. Panel A: Hedge Funds Persistent Winner Persistent Loser Model 1 Model 2 -0.14 -1.204*** Intercept *** -0.14 0.045 Sizet-1 0.04 -0.148 Flowt-1 -0.03 0.048** Sizet-1 * Flowt-1 0.09*** -0.060*** Delta t-1 -0.86 -7.451*** Volatilityt-1 ** 0.24 -0.216* Younger Fund Dummy *** -0.41 0.287** Older Fund Dummy 3.96 -5.373 Management Fee Yes Yes Strategy Dummies 2 2.1% 3.2% Pseudo R Independent Variables Panel B: Funds of Hedge Funds Independent Variables Intercept Sizet-1 Flowt-1 Sizet-1 * Flowt-1 Delta t-1 Volatilityt-1 Younger Fund Dummy Older Fund Dummy Management Fee Pseudo R2 Persistent Winner Persistent Loser Model 1 Model 2 *** -2.308 -1.161* *** 0.396 -0.204* ** 0.568 -0.164 *** -0.184 0.063 -0.023 0.009 -6.349 -9.573 0.710* 0.437 0.199 0.915** -5.624 22.835 7.3% 3.6% 43 Figure 1: Distribution of Funds by Data Sources This table shows the percentage of hedge funds (Panel A) and funds of hedge funds (Panel B) from the three databases namely HFR, ZCM/MAR, and TASS at the end of our sample period, i.e., at the end of 2000. Panel A: Distribution of Number of Hedge Funds ZCM/MAR 32% 6% 6% 10% 17% 21% 8% HFR TASS Panel B: Distribution of Number of Funds of Hedge Funds HFR 40% 6% 11% 17% 19% 7% 0% TASS ZCM/MAR 44 Figure 2: Flows in the Four Strategies as a function of past performance (1994-2000) This figure plots the annual flows in millions of dollars with the lagged annual returns for all the funds belonging to the four strategies and “All Funds” from 1994 to 2000. Directional Traders: Annual Dollar Flows vs Lagged Annual Returns 5000 Relative Value: Annual Dollar Flows vs Lagged Annual Returns 50% 7000 40% 6000 3000 Value-Weighted Returns 30% Equal-Weighted Returns 5000 2000 20% 1000 10% Dollar Flows 1994 1998 1996 1999 2000 0% 1997 -1000 -10% -2000 -20% Annual Dollar Flows ($M) Annual Dollar Flows ($M) 1995 0 Value-Weighted Returns Equal-Weighted Returns Lagged Annual Returns Dollar Flows 4000 4000 3000 2000 1000 1999 0 1994 -3000 -30% 1996 1997 1998 -1000 Year Year Security Selection: Annual Dollar Flows vs Lagged Annual Returns Multi-Process: Annual Dollar Flows vs Lagged Annual Returns 60% 8000 3500 7000 3000 50% 5000 40% 4000 Equal-Weighted Returns 3000 30% Value-Weighted Returns 2000 20% 1000 1998 0 1994 1995 1996 1997 1999 2000 Dollar Flows 2500 Annual Dollar Flows ($M) Dollar Flows Lagged Annual Returns 6000 Annual Dollar Flows ($M) 1995 2000 Value-Weighted Returns 1500 Equal-Weighted Returns 1000 500 0 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 -500 10% -1000 -1000 0% -2000 -1500 Year Year All Funds: Annual Dollar Flows vs Lagged Annual Returns 16000 40% 14000 35% Dollar Flows 10000 30% Value-Weighted Returns 25% 8000 20% Equal-Weighted Returns 6000 15% 4000 10% 2000 5% 0 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 0% -2000 -4000 -5% Year 45 Lagged Annual Returns Annual Dollar Flows ($M) 12000 Appendix A: Classification of Hedge Fund Strategies This table provides the mapping of the strategies provided by different data vendors with the four broad strategies that we use in our study. It also provides a brief definition of each of the four broad strategies. Source HFR, ZCM/MAR and TASS Vendor’s Strategy Convertible Arbitrage Broad Strategy Relative Value HFR, ZCM/MAR Distressed Securities Multi-Process HFR, ZCM/MAR and TASS Emerging Markets Directional Traders HFR, ZCM/MAR and TASS Equity Hedge Security Selection HFR, ZCM/MAR Equity Non-Hedge Security Selection HFR, ZCM/MAR and TASS Event Driven Multi-Process HFR, ZCM/MAR and TASS Fixed Income Relative Value HFR Foreign Exchange Directional Traders ZCM/MAR Global Established Security Selection ZCM/MAR Global International Security Selection HFR, ZCM/MAR and TASS Macro Directional Traders HFR, ZCM/MAR and TASS Market Neutral Relative Value HFR, ZCM/MAR Market Timing Directional Traders HFR, ZCM/MAR Merger Arbitrage Relative Value Traders HFR, ZCM/MAR and TASS Relative Value Arbitrage Relative Value Traders HFR, ZCM/MAR Sector Directional Traders HFR, ZCM/MAR and TASS Short Selling Directional Traders HFR, ZCM/MAR Statistical Arbitrage Relative Value Directional Traders usually bet on the direction of market prices of currencies, commodities, equities, and bonds in the futures and cash markets. Relative Value strategies take positions on spread relations between prices of financial assets or commodities and aim to minimize market exposure. Security Selection managers take long and short positions in undervalued and overvalued securities respectively and reduce the systematic market risks in the process. Usually, they take positions in equity markets. Multi-Process strategy involves multiple strategies employed by the funds usually involving investments in opportunities created by significant transactional events, such as spin-offs, mergers and acquisitions, bankruptcy reorganizations, recapitalizations and share buybacks. For example, the portfolio of some Event-Driven managers may shift in majority weighting between Merger Arbitrage and Distressed Securities, while others may take a broader scope. 46 Appendix B: Computation of Delta We compute of the dollar flows from the investors for each fund and each year. For each year’s dollar flow, we compute the option delta separately at the end of each year. We sum these deltas to determine the total fund delta for the assets under management of each fund at the end of each year. The exercise price of the option on each annual flow depends on its high-water mark level and hurdle rate. For dollar outflows, we follow a FIFO (first-in, first-out) policy. Using Black and Scholes (1973) formula, we estimate the dollar change in the manager’s performance-related incentive fee for a one percent change in asset value. In particular, we compute delta as delta = N(Z)*(S*0.01)*I where Z S X T R σ N( ) I = [ln(S/X) + T(R+σ2/2)]/[σ*T0.5] = Spot price = Exercise price = Time to maturity of the option in years (one year) = Risk-free rate of interest = Volatility of monthly returns over the year = Cumulative density function of a standard Normal distribution = Incentive fee expressed as a fraction 47 Appendix C: Following GIR (2003) approach for only offshore funds in our sample This table reports the regressions of flow on the performance in the previous year following Goetzmann, Ingersoll, and Ross (GIR) (2003). As in GIR (2003), the results are for the sub-sample of offshore funds for the period, 19901995. Figures marked with ***, **, and * are significant at the 1%, 5%, and 10% respectively. Independent Variables Intercept 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 F-M Model 1 Model 2 -0.802*** -0.951*** -0.697** -0.606** -0.789* -0.173 -0.670*** -0.328* Rankt-1 – Bottom Quintile -1.025 0.902 -0.472 1.144 1.999 1.398 0.658 1.023 Rankt-1 - 4th Quintile 1.704 2.402 2.641 -0.786 -0.133 -1.868 0.660 -0.007 Rankt-1 - 3rd Quintile -0.085 -1.849 -0.340 3.070 -0.795 -0.339 -0.056 -0.005 Rankt-1 - 2nd Quintile -0.289 0.767 1.475 -1.704 3.229 0.885 0.727 0.946 Rankt-1 -Top Quintile 0.181 1.490 -2.252 1.461 0.759 5.516 1.192 1.943 Lagged Return 0.106 Year Dummies Adjusted R2 -0.029 -3.0% 1.6% 2.4% -0.6% 48 2.3% -0.1% 0.4% Yes Yes 2.4% 1.6%