* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download 1 Solutions to End-of-Chapter Problems in
Greeks (finance) wikipedia , lookup
Financial economics wikipedia , lookup
Internal rate of return wikipedia , lookup
Business valuation wikipedia , lookup
Adjustable-rate mortgage wikipedia , lookup
Lattice model (finance) wikipedia , lookup
Stock valuation wikipedia , lookup
Global saving glut wikipedia , lookup
Financialization wikipedia , lookup
Purchasing power parity wikipedia , lookup
Interest rate ceiling wikipedia , lookup
History of pawnbroking wikipedia , lookup
Pensions crisis wikipedia , lookup
Credit rationing wikipedia , lookup
Continuous-repayment mortgage wikipedia , lookup
Monetary policy wikipedia , lookup
Interest rate swap wikipedia , lookup
Balance of payments wikipedia , lookup
Credit card interest wikipedia , lookup
Solutions to End-of-Chapter Problems in Blanchard & Melino Textbook Chapters 7+ Note of Jan. 09, 2003: There is no ‘Solution Manual’ for the textbook. The solutions appearing below have been worked out by Prof. Jump and/or a TA and have not been fully verified; some may contain errors. Additionally, the solutions have not been completed for all of the chapters in the textbook; this is a work in progress and additional solutions will be added to this page as they are completed on a chapter-by-chapter. Solutions, Chapter 7 7-1 The “proof” follows directly from the fact that the expected rate of price inflation between time periods t and t+1 is defined as ðet = (Pet+1 - Pt ) / Pt . 7-2 The exact expression is rt = [(1 + it ) / (1 + ðet )] - 1 . The approximation is rt . it - ðet . Note that in both cases rt, it , and ðet are measured in decimal form. (a) Exact is 4.95% ; approximate is 5.0%. (b) Exact is 4.76%; approximate is 5.0%. (c) Exact is 3.45%; approximate is 5.0%. 7-3 There is nothing to prevent the real rate of interest from being negative (though this seems very unlikely to happen in the real world). A negative real rate would occur if the expected rate of price inflation were greater than the nominal rate of interest. For example, suppose ðet = 10% and it = 8%. Then rt = -2.0% (approximately). In this case lenders are effectively paying borrowers for the privilege lending to them. Why would anyone lend in that case? Because earning a -2.0% real return is preferable to holding money and earning a -10% real return. 7-4 (a) This is just simple compounding. If ðem is the monthly expected rate of inflation, then the annual rate is the value of ðea that solves the equation: (1 + ðea ) = (1 + ðem )12 , where both rates are expressed in decimal form. For ðem = 0.30 , ðea = 22.30 (or 2,230.0 %) . (b) Exact is 4.72% ; approximate is 110.0%. 1 7-5 (a) $300,000 (b) $285,940 (c) $173,550 7-6 (a) Will want to use real payments and real interest rates here. It will be difficult to estimate the value of nominal income, say, 10- years from now without knowing what will be the rate of price inflation over the next 10 years. But future values of income can be expected to move in proportion to future rates of price inflation so that the future value of real income may be estimated without having to know the rate of price inflation. (b) The nominal value (price) of a house is equal to the present discounted value of the future nominal rents it would generate. If the nominal rate of interest rises, the value of a house declines. The choice between renting and buying a house depends upon one’s expectations of the future value of nominal interest rates. If nominal rates are expected to rise, it probably pays to rent and avoid the capital losses anticipated for home ownership. 7-7 (a) Using IS and LM schedules plotted on a graph with the axes labelled Y and r : A decrease in ðe will cause the LM schedule to shift upwards to the left and result in lower Y and higher r. [For a given value of r, a lower value of ðe will result in a decrease in the nominal rate of interest – leading to an increase in the quantity of money demanded. Since the supply of money has not changed, Y must fall and r must rise to restore the demand for money to its original level.] (b) Adding a contractionary monetary policy to a decrease in ðe will cause Y to fall by more than Part (a) and r to rise by more than Part (a). 7-8 Left to the student as an exercise. 7-9 (a) Pa = $10,000 [1 + 1/(1.05) + 1/(1.05)2] (b) Pi = Pa + $10,000 ; Piii = $10,000 [1 + 1/(1.10) + 1/(1.05)2] Pii = 2Pa ; Piv = $10,000 [1 + 1/(1.10) + 1/(1.10)2] Solutions, Chapter 8 8-1 Exercise left to student. 8-2 Certainly aggregate consumption would rise immediately as a result of the actions of young households (e.g., students) who currently have low incomes but expect to have high incomes in the future. Right now such households can’t borrow against future earnings and are constrained to have consumption # current income. If borrowing is suddenly permitted, the close link between C and YD for these households will weaken 2 and the marginal propensity to consume out of current disposable income will decrease. 8-3 The present discounted value of lifetime earnings exceeds $1million for recent university graduates in Canada. 8-4 Here the present discounted value of profits is the sum of an infinite geometric series. To answer the question you will have to know something about geometric series in general. ∞ Consider the sum S = ∑ B x . It turns out that S = F [ 1 − x ] , where F is the first term 1 t t =a in the summation and x is the common ratio. In the example the first term is F = Bxa , so 1 ]. S = Bxa [ 1−x Now in the case of Problem 8-4, B = $10,000 , a = 0 , and x = (1 - 0.1) / (1+r); hence the present discounted value of profits is 1 +r 1 PV = $10,000 [ ] = $10,000 [ ]. r + 0 .1 1 − [ 0 .9 / (1 + r )] (a) r = 0.05; PV of profits = $70,000 > $50,000 cost ; buy the machine. (b) r = 0.10; PV of profits = $55,000 > $50,000 cost ; buy the machine. (c) r = 0.15; PV of profits = $46,000 < $50,000 cost ; do not buy the machine. 8-5 (a) Human wealth = (1-0.4 )$50,000 [1 +(1.05)/(1.0) +(1.05)2/(1.0)2] = $94,575 (b) Total wealth = human wealth + nonhuman wealth = $194,575. (c) Since r = 0, this is easy. Annual consumption = total wealth ÷ 10 = $19,457.50 . (d) Assuming she still wants the same annual consumption for each of the next 10 years, current consumption will rise by $1,200. [Remember the tax rate is 40% so the bonus will yields $12,000 in after-tax income.] 8-6 The (real) present discounted value of $20,000 to be received 30 years from now is $20,000 / (1.04)30 = $6,166,37. The investor should sell the wine now for $7,000. 8-7 The nominal interest rate is i = 8.0 %, so the present discounted value is $40,000 [1 +1/(1.08) +1/(1.08)2] . 3 Solutions, Chapter 9 9-1 Let Fn denote the face value (or, cash payment at maturity) of a discount bond that will mature in n years, and let Pn denote the current price of this bond. Then the yield to maturity is the value of in that solves the following equation: Pn = Fn / (1+in)n . (a) in = 11.08 % (b) in = 5.41 % (c) in = 3.57 % 9-2 (a) i2t . ½ (i1t + ie1t+1 ) = 7.5 %. (b) (1+ i2t )2 = ( 1+ i1t )(1 + ie1t+1 ); i2t = 7.47 % . 9-3 (a) 4.0 % 9-4 The policy will cause the LM schedule to shift downwards to the right. The current rate of interest will fall. The yield to maturity on an n-period bond is Rn t approx. equal to (1/n)[it + ien t+1 + ..........+ ien t+n-1] . If the money supply increase had been anticipated, only it will fall. Rn t will decline for all values of n but the effect will be smaller the larger is n. Thus the yield curve will shift down more for shorter maturities than for longer maturities and assume a more upward-sloping appearance. 9-5 (a) $1,047.62 9-6 Current price = initial dividend [1 / ( r - g )] , where r is the real rate of interest and g is the annual rate of real dividend growth. (a) $5,000 9-7 (b) 4.5 % (c) 5.0 % (b) $1,000. (b) $1,428.57 . (a) The interest rate will rise so stock prices will fall. Profits will also fall, reducing dividends and further causing share prices to decline. (b) Ambiguous. The interest rate falls but profits are also likely to fall. (c) The interest rate falls so stock prices rise. 4 (d) Profits will decline, reducing dividends and stock prices Solutions, Chapter 10 10-1 (a) IS shifts left (down). (b) IS shifts left, down. (c) An increase in the current rate of interest is a movement along the IS and/or LM schedules, but one of these schedules must have shifted for some unspecified reason to cause the current interest rate to change. (d) Same answer as Part (c). (e) LM shifts right (up). 10-2 The critical difference between the statement in this question and the discussion in section 10-3 of the text is that here, the central bank will act to keep expected future interest rates from changing. Future taxes will be higher and expected future output will be lower and both of these expectations cause the current IS schedule to shift to the left. There is no ambiguity. 10-3 (a) Expected future taxes will be lower and expected future output higher – both effects causing the current IS schedule to shift to the right. However, future interest rates are expected to be higher and this causes the current IS schedule to shift to the left. The net effect on the IS curve is ambiguous. (b) Expected future taxes will be lower causing the current IS schedule to shift to the right. To keep future Y constant, the central bank will have to reduce the future money supply, which means the future interest rate will rise. This, in turn, will cause current I to decline -- countering the expansionary effect of lowering current taxes. The net effect on the IS curve in the current time period is ambiguous. What is not ambiguous is that by preventing current Y from changing, the central bank ensures that current consumption increases but is fully offset by a decline in current investment. (c) Expected future taxes will be lower and expected future output higher – both effects causing the current IS schedule to shift to the right. To keep the current interest rate from rising, the central bank must take a expansionary policy and shift the LM curve to the right. Current output unambiguously rises as both consumption and investment increase. 10-4 No. Rational expectations only requires that agents be consistent in their beliefs. For example, suppose I believe that stock markets follow the phases of the moon – peaking at full moon and bottoming out at new moon. If I make a prediction about the stock market a year from now, it would be rational of me to base my prediction on what will be the 5 phase of the moon a year from now. If I do, then my prediction is a “rational expectation”, irrespective of whether my beliefs do or do not have merit. [That said, we would expect rational agents to revise their beliefs if they systematically yielded incorrect predictions, but that is a topic for future consideration.] 10-5 Exercise left to the student. Solutions, Chapter 11 11-1 Exercise left to the student. 11-2 Tradeables are automobiles and computers. 11-3 (a) 1.0 (bushel per bottle) 11-4 The peak value (lowest exchange rate as defined in the text) of the Canadian dollar vis-avis currencies of G10 countries occurred in 1991. That would have been the best time to travel around the world in terms of lowest cost as measured in Canadian dollars. 11-5 (a) 0.16 (Canadian good / French good) (b) 1.2 (bushels per bottle) (c) 1.5 (bushels per bottle) (b) 0.10 (Canadian good / French good) (c) A real appreciation of the Canadian dollar of 37.5% . 11-6 (a) $1.11 (b) $1.06 (c) 0.96363 Yen (d) Since 1.01 > 0.96363, a Japanese resident should invest in Japan. (e) Et = 0.01 ($cdn /Yen); The implied value of Eet+1 = 0.011, so the Canadian dollar is expected to depreciate by 10 % relative to the Yen. (f) i - i* = 5 % but (Eet+1 - Et ) / Et = +10 %. Solutions, Chapter 12 12-1 The “domestic demand for goods” is the quantity of all goods purchased by domestic agents; that is, the sum of C+I+G. Note that the “domestic demand for goods” does not distinguish between goods that are domestically-produced and those that are imported. The “demand for domestic goods” is the quantity of all domestically-produced purchased 6 either by domestic agents or by agents in the rest of world; that is, the sum of C+I+G+X-åQ . 12-2 This is kind of roundabout. If a budget deficit occurs, government saving is negative and total (aggregate) saving, S, is likely to decline. Recall that S-I must equal NX; so if S declines with I unchanged, NX must also decline and NX is the balance of trade. Another way of saying the same thing is that if the government runs a deficit, it must borrow to finance it. If private agents neither save more nor invest less when this occurs, the borrowed funds must come from the rest of world. As this borrowing from the rest of world occurs, the balance on capital and financial account of the balance of payments must move towards surplus. Since NX + Bal. on Capital Account = 0 , if the latter goes to surplus, the former must go to deficit. 12-3 Large countries tend to be less reliant on foreign trade and, as a consequence, have large multipliers – meaning that large countries can effectively counter recessions with domestic monetary and fiscal policy without international co-ordination. In small counties imports tend to be a large fraction of the “domestic demand for goods” so multipliers have small values. This means that, say, an expansionary fiscal policy undertaken by a small country will have a large import leakage and small impact on domestic output. (The import leakage will benefit the small country’s trading partners.) To counter a mutual recession, small countries should co-ordinate their monetary and fiscal policies to gain the maximum effects. 12-4 Here the IS Schedule is Y = C+I+G+X-åQ = [400 + 0.5(Y-T)] + [700 - 4,000 i +0.2Y] + G + [100 + 0.1Y*+100å ] - å [0.1Y -50å] = (0.5 + 0.2 - 0.1 å)Y [400- 0.5 T ] + [700 - 4,000 i ] + G + [100 + 0.1Y*+100å ] + 50 å2 =[ 1 ] {[400 -0.5 T ]+ [700 - 4,000 i ] + G + [100 + 0.1Y*+100å ] + 50 ( 1 − 0 .7 + 0 .1ε ) å2} Here the multiplier is [ 1 ] and has value 2.0 when å = 2. ( 1 − 0 .7 + 0 .1ε ) (a) The value of the terms in { } is 1,400 when i = 0.1; so equilibrium Y = 2,800. (b) C = 400 + 0.5 (2,800 - 200) = 1,700 I = 700 - 4,000 (0.1) + 0.2 (2,800) = 860 NX = [ 100 + 0.1 (1,000) +100 (2)] - 2 [ 0.1 (2,800) - 50 (2)] = 400 - 360 = +40 7 Demand for domestic goods is Z = C+I+G+X-åQ = 2,800 . (c) (i) The multiplier is 2.0, so an increase in G from 200 to 400 will cause Y to increase by 400 to the level 3,200. (ii) C = 400 + 0.5 (3,200 - 200) = 1,900 I = 700 - 4,000 (0.1) + 0.2 (3,200) = 940 NX = [ 100 + 0.1 (1,000) +100 (2)] - 2 [ 0.1 (3,200) - 50 (2)] = 400 - 440 = - 40 Demand for domestic goods is Z = C+I+G+X-åQ = 3,200 . (iii) Net exports went from a surplus of + 40 to a deficit of - 40 as imports rose in response to the increase in domestic production. (d) Increase in Y* from 1,00 to 1,200 will cause X to increase by 20; the multiplier is 2.0 so Y will increase by 40 to the new level 2,840. Now C= 1,720; I=868; NX=+52 . (iii) The 200 increase in Y* resulted in only a direct increase in the demand for domestic goods of 20 via exports. This stimulated a multiplied increase of 40 in Y and induced an increase in åQ of 8. The trade balance improved by 12 because the original source of the domestic expansion was higher exports. 12-5 An appreciation will lower the prices paid by consumers for foreign goods but it will raise the prices paid by the rest of world for domestic goods and lead to a decline in exports. This will not only be disadvantageous to the firms that produce exported goods and their employees but it will also be contractionary on the economy as a whole – causing GDP to decline. Governments will normally want to avoid this. 12-6 (a) A depreciation of the exchange rate by itself will both improve the trade balance and increase output. No fiscal policy is necessary. (b) A fiscal contraction will by itself reduce output and improve the trade balance. No exchange rate change is necessary. 12-7 This can be accomplished by an exchange rate depreciation coupled with a contractionary fiscal policy – say, an increase in taxes. Exports will rise, consumption will decline, and investment will be unchanged. As for imports, å rises and Q declines, so it is not certain what happens to real imports åQ . It is possible that åQ might increase but, if so, the increase must be smaller than the increase in X (because of the Marshall-Learner condition, which we assume to be satisfied). 12-8 Assuming that I depends positively(+) on Y*, the effect will be to shift the ZZ schedule 8 upwards; i.e., increase the intercept. There will be no effect on the NX schedule. 12-9 The economy of a relatively small geographical area like Ontario is extremely open to foreign trade. That is, the ratio of both exports and imports to GDP originating in Ontario is very high. This means that the multiplier for fiscal actions taken by the government of Ontario is quite small and may even be < 1.0 . (See solution to Q.12-3.) Solutions, Chapter 13 13-1 Since the investor does not care about risk, she will be indifferent between a fixed and floating exchange rate. Her expected rate of return from investing in a foreign bond is (approximately) it* + (Eet+1 - Et) /Et . The investor does not care whether Et+1 is known with certainty or not; she only cares about the value of Eet+1 . 13-2 We can answer this using either the exact or the approximate versions of interest rate parity. With the exact version, Et = Eet+1 [(1+it*) /(1+tt)]. With the approximate version Et = Eet+1 / (1+tt - it*) . (a) Et = 0.2038 (exact); 0.2041 (approximate) (b) Et = 0.20 (both) (c) Et = 0.1963 (exact); 0.1961 (approximate). 13-3 There is no contradiction. Suppose that agents firmly believe that the future exchange rate will be some specific value Eet+1 . Then interest rate parity implies that the current exchange rate and the current rate of interest will be inversely related via (the approximation) Et = Eet+1 / (1+tt - it*) . If we start with t t = it* , then Et = Eet+1 . Now if the Canadian rate, it , rises, Et must decline in order to maintain interest rate parity in the face of a fixed expectation about the value of the future exchange rate making Et < Eet+1 . Now the exchange rate is expected to rise between time periods t and t+1, so the Canadian dollar is expected to depreciate relative to the German currency (which is now the Euro but was the Mark at the time our textbook was written). 13-4 The statement is “True” unless we can come up with a combination of policy actions that will reduce the US trade deficit without simultaneously reducing the US government’s budget deficit. I can think of only one such combination and it is rather contrived: Pursue an expansionary monetary policy, coupled with a “balanced budget” fiscal contraction (reduce both G and T by the same amounts), such that i increases but Y does not change. The rise in i will lead to a depreciation of the US dollar, causing the trade balance to improve while the budget deficit (G-T) remains unchanged. [Observe that this requires that the foreign interest rate i* does not rise on a one-to-one basis in response to 9 higher i – a questionable result, explored in detail in Q. 13-9.] 13-5 Fiscal policy is less effective in an open economy for two reasons. First, the fact that imports rise (fall) in response to increases (decreases) in Y creates “leakages” in the circular flow of income and spending that causes the value of the multiplier to be smaller. Second, fiscal policy actions are at least partially offset by movements in the exchange rate. For example, an expansionary fiscal policy aimed at increasing Y will cause an appreciation of the domestic currency, leading to lower NX and limiting the increase in Y. Monetary policy, on the other hand, is more effective in an open economy. This is because monetary policy actions cause reinforcing movements in the exchange rate. For example, an expansionary monetary policy aimed at increasing Y will cause a depreciation of the domestic currency, leading to higher NX and boosting the increase in Y. 13-6 and 13-7 pertain to fixed exchange rates and will be answered at a later date. 13-8 (a) From interest rate parity Eet+1 = Et (1+tt - it*) = 0.8 (1 + 0.02 - 0.06) = 0.768 (b) The dollar is expected to appreciate by 4 %. 13-9 (a) If a = 0 , i* is independent of i; a change in the value of i has no effect on i*. If a = 1, i* is always equal to i; a change in the value of i causes a 1:1 change in i*. If a = 0.5, i* is partially dependent on i; a change in the value of i causes i* to change by half the change in i. (b) When i = 0.04 , i* = 0.05 and Et = Eet+1 / (1+tt - it*) = 10 /0.99 = 10.1010. When i rises to 0.05, i* will increase to 0.055 and Et falls to 10.0525 – an appreciation of the domestic currency of 0.5 %. (c) True. In the extreme case a = 1, any change in i will cause a 1:1 change in i* and there will be no change in the exchange rate so that monetary policy works as if the economy was closed. Addendum The following “extra” problem is a numerical IS/LM exercise for an open economy. Suppose P = P* = 1 so that å = E and that ðe = 0 so that r = i. 10 The behaviour of the components of aggregate demand are as follows: C = 260 + 0.4 (Y-T) and T = 400 I = 0.2 Y - 1,000 i G = 400 NX = 1,000 + 0.03 Y* - 0.4 Y - 1,500 (1 /E ) and Y* = 10,000 . The LM schedule is given by M = 0.10 Y - 600 i and M = 70 . You are given the following additional information: Interest rate parity holds between this economy and the rest of world. The rest-of-world interest rate is i* = 0.10 and economic agents firmly expect the future exchange rate will be Eet+1 = 1.5 (in units of domestic currency per unit of rest-of-world currency). (a) Compute equilibrium values for Y, i, and E. Then compute equilibrium values for C, I, and NX . (b) Verify that your solution for E represents an equilibrium exchange rate by showing that the sum of the Balance on Current Account and the Balance on Capital and Financial Account equals 0. (Assume that the Balance on Investment Income = 0.) Solutions (a) (b) Y = 1,000 i = 0.05 E = 1.5789 C = 500 I = 150 NX = -50 Since there are no flows of international investment income here, the Balance on Current Account just equals the Balance of Trade, or NX = -50. We know that the Balance on Capital & Financial Account must equal -1 X Bal. on Current Account, or +50, but let’s verify it by looking at the Difference between total saving and investment. Personal Saving = Y - T - C = 100; Government Saving = 0. Total Saving = 100 and S-I = -50. The difference between S and I 11 represents net purchases of foreign assets by domestic residents. The value is -50 here, meaning that domestic residents sold 50 more in assets to the rest of world than they purchased. This represents a net Capital Account inflow of +50 so the Bal. on Capital & Financial Account is +50. 12