* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Chapter 14. Investment and asset prices
Mark-to-market accounting wikipedia , lookup
Internal rate of return wikipedia , lookup
Short (finance) wikipedia , lookup
Investor-state dispute settlement wikipedia , lookup
Socially responsible investing wikipedia , lookup
Early history of private equity wikipedia , lookup
International investment agreement wikipedia , lookup
Hedge (finance) wikipedia , lookup
Stock trader wikipedia , lookup
Investment management wikipedia , lookup
Environmental, social and corporate governance wikipedia , lookup
Investment banking wikipedia , lookup
History of investment banking in the United States wikipedia , lookup
Chapter 14. Investment and asset prices ECON320 Prof Mike Kennedy What is the relationship between asset prices and investment • The idea is simple: – If the market price of an investment opportunity is greater than its replacement costs, then there exists an incentive to invest – it becomes profitable to invest – We will see that prices embody information about the future – This applies to non-residential and residential investment whether we use the stock market or the price of a house as a measure of value – The replacement cost of a firm’s assets equals the price at which the firm can purchase new machinery etc. – If the stock market price of the assets of a firm is greater than these costs then there is an incentive to invest – Note that the market price can be greater (or less) than replacement value for a long time since it takes time for production to adjust – Note as well that additions to the stocks of housing or capital will not occur instantly as there are adjustment or installation costs, which likely rise more than proportionally with the scale of the project • We will examine the relationship between asset prices and investment Changes in the real S&P tend to lead the business cycle 5 Cycle GDP 15 4 ∆Real S&P (right scale) 10 3 2 1 5 0 0 -1 -2 -5 -10 -3 -15 -4 -5 -20 The change in real S&P and the cycle in total investment 20 15 10 5 0 -5 -10 -15 -20 ∆Real S&P (right scale) Cycle INV The importance of asset prices: Canadian non-residential investment and the real value of the S&P 12.5 5 Non-residential investment S&P in real terms (right scale) Correlation = 0.95 4.6 Elasticity = 1.01 SE = 0.14 4.4 11.5 4.2 4 11 3.8 3.6 10.5 3.4 3.2 10 3 Log of real A&P Log of real non-residenntial investment 12 4.8 The importance of asset prices: Canadian M&E investment and the real value of the S&P 11.5 5 Log of real investment in M&E 11 10.5 S&P in real terms (right scale) 4.8 Correlation = 0.95 4.6 Elasticity = 1.30 SE = 0.17 4.4 4.2 4 10 3.8 3.6 9.5 3.4 3.2 9 3 Log of real S&P M&E Changes in real house prices and the business cycle 5 4 3 2 1 0 -1 -2 -3 -4 -5 Cycle GDP ∆Real house prices The importance of asset prices: Canadian residential investment and the real value of house prices 11.8 4.9 Residential structures Real house prices (right scale) 4.7 Correlation = 0.92 Elasticity = 0.88 SE = 0.11 4.5 11.4 4.3 11.2 4.1 11 3.9 10.8 10.6 3.7 3.5 Log of real house prices Log of real housing investment 11.6 US stock market over time 2000 50 1800 45 1600 Real price 40 1400 P/E10 or CAPE (right scale) 35 1200 30 1000 25 800 20 600 15 400 10 200 5 0 0 Source Shiller website CAPE = cyclically adjusted price-earnings ratio The Canadian stock market since the mid 1950s 140 120 100 Real stock… 80 60 40 20 0 Facts about the stock market • • • • Volatility Stock market capitalisation has risen Ownership of stocks has become more widespread Likely more extensive than the data suggest due to pensions • Its importance is also due to its influence on investment and consumption and through these on employment • So what drives stock prices and how do these prices affect investment? The value of a firm and the fundamental stock price • We will assume that firms want to maximize the wealth of shareholders – which is equivalent to maximizing the share price • In doing so the firm will maximize the consumption possibilities of shareholders • This is the same as assuming that they maximize profits • Our theory of investment will be based on a theory of the value of the firm – that is the price of its stocks The arbitrage condition • • • • • In equilibrium investors will be indifferent between investing in shares and bonds Investors know that share prices are much more volatile than those of bonds and they will want to be compensated for this The opportunity costs times the interest rate on safe bonds The required return (compensating for risk, ε) is (r + ε)Vt The arbitrage condition is then (1) • The stock market will only be in equilibrium when this condition is met The arbitrage condition, con’t • We can re-arrange (1) to get (2) • This condition, important for what follows, must hold in all subsequent periods (3) • By successive forward substitution we get: The arbitrage condition, con’t (6) This is the fundamental share price: The market value of a firm equals the present value of expected future dividends. Note that we are assuming that r and ε are constant over time How well do the facts fit the theory? There should be a close correlation between profits (earnings) and dividends 5.00 ln(Real dividends) 4.50 ln(Real earnings) 4.00 3.50 3.00 2.50 2.00 1.50 1.00 Data from Shiller's website How well do the facts fit the theory? • The behaviour of the stock market differs form the Efficient Market Theory (EMT) • It turns out that stock are much more volatile than suggested by the EMT possibly due to fluctuations in: – The expected change in dividends (∆Det) – The real rate of interest (rt) – The required risk premium (εt) The risk premium (the appetite for risk as measured by implied volatilities) seems to vary a lot 70 Peak of financial crisis 60 VIX 50 40 30 20 10 0 Sep 11 2002 terrorist attack NASDAQ peaks Euro area debt crisis Some reasons why equation (6) is not that bad of a representation • It says nothing about rationality • The theory in (6) is compatible with the notion that investors frequently revise their forecasts • The possibility of investors becoming overly optimistic is not excluded • It only assumes that the expected return on shares is systematically related to the return on bonds, which seems to be the case over longer periods of time Our strategy for deriving an investment equation • Look again at the equation for the current market value of the firm • We will assume that the managers of the firm want to maximize the current value of the firm (Vt) • We will proceed by finding relationships for both expected dividends and the expected value of the firm in the next period (the numerator in the above relationship) that are in some way related to investment spending • The managers will then choose a level of investment spending that maximizes Vt – this will give us a simple investment function • We will then use this simple investment function to examine how investment responds to changes in real interest rates, risk, sales and business confidence • We will see that everything will work through equity prices Stock prices, investment and Tobin’s “q” • As noted above, the wealth of owners today (Vt) depends on e Dte Vt1 as well as the discount factor • The question is: What level of It will maximise Vt? • We now introduce the following variable qt Vt / Kt where we have assumed that the price of capital is unity so that Kt = the replacement value of the capital stock • The firm is assumed to inform markets about its investment plans, however shareholders’ expected q is assumed to e remain unchanged q t1 q t which implies that • This is one part of Vt above, the other part being expected dividends Stock prices, investment and Tobin’s “q” con’t • When thinking about Det, the other determinant of Vt, note that a firm’s profits consist of dividends that it will pay out plus its retained earnings, which it can invest – This is called the uses of profits, the sources being sales minus costs • Assume that the firm finances its investment spending from retained earnings and that there are adjustments cost associated with installing new capital • The total cost of investment is then It + c(It), where c(It) is the installation cost function is to be defined • Expected dividends in this period are (by definition) expected profits (Πet) less these expenditures on investment Stock prices, investment and Tobin’s “q” con’t • Installation cost are assumed to rise more than one-for-one with investment and we capture this by a 2 c(I t ) I t 2 • The marginal installation cost (dc/dIt = aIt) rises with investment • Going back to Vet +1 we can use the capital accumulation identity Kt+1 = Kt + It to eliminate Kt+1 and which gets current investment into the relationship e Vt1 qt K t1 q t (I t K t ) Stock prices, investment and Tobin’s “q” con’t • Return to the question of maximizing the market value of stocks and use the information we have on both expected dividends and the expected value of the firm in the next period as they are related to investment • The firm now chooses It so as to maximize Vt which is given by ∂Vt/∂It = 0. • Recalling that dc/dIt = aIt we get: • qt 1 It a The higher the value of qt the further the firm can raise investment, while the higher are installation costs the lower is investment Stock prices, investment and Tobin’s “q” con’t Stock prices, investment and Tobin’s “q” con’t • Note that the previous figure is consistent with the simple graphs shown earlier in that there is a positive relationship between investment spending and stock prices • In the case where the firm issues new shares we simply subtract these costs from the value of shares held by existing shareholders • It is optimal for investors to let the firm expand the capital stock (invest) until the expected marginal gain on their shares is driven down to zero, that is qt – (1 + dc/dIt) = 0, which is the investment function – The profit maximizing firm will invest up to the point where the rise in the stock market value of the firm equals acquisition and installation costs – The level of investment depends on the value that markets place on the firm – Investment will be sensitive to the variables the changes qt • Going forward we will examine how qt responds to various economic variables and how this affects investment spending The role of interest rates and risk and their effect on q • Interest rates will be negatively correlated with investment and in the q theory it works through share prices • To show this simply, suppose that dividends are expected to stay constant, then • Which simplifies to • Since Vt = qtKt it follows that qt will be negatively related to both interest rates and risk The role of profits and sales and how they affect q • To see the effect of profits and sales we start with the definition of qt given on the previous slide • Dividends are assumed to be a fraction (θ) of profits which implies that the numerator in the above is Dte / K t ( t / K t ) • The term in brackets is the profit rate (profits to capital) of the firm • Based on a Cobb-Douglas production function the profit rate would be θ(Πt/ Kt) = αY/K • Higher sales generates higher profits and a rise in qt and in investment The role of confidence and how it affects q • Firms would also look at other variables than the profit rate – θ(Πt/Kt) – in deciding how much to invest • These could be anything that might have a bearing on expected future sales • One measure that captures these hard-tomeasure effects would be business confidence (E) which is shown for a few countries on the following graph Business confidence can also affect investment spending as we saw in the great recession 103 102 101 100 99 98 Recession United Kingdom 97 United States Euro area (18 countries) 96 OECD - Total 95 Source OECD Summing up: The investment function • Recall again the investment equation q t 1 1 It (q t 1) where a a • In a general sense we can think of the Dte/Kt as a function of sales and confidence g(Yt/Kt, Et) where both the first and second derivatives are positive • A rise in Y will increase expected dividends while an increase in Kt will lower them • An increase in business confidence will also raise expected dividends to the extent that such measures contain additional information regarding the outlook for activity • We can substitute this into our definition of qt to get The investment function, con’t • Writing this in a general format we get • The general investment function has the following properties: – An increase in sales (Y) or confidence (E) will raise investment spending by raising q through its effect on dividends [Dte/Kt = g(Yt/Kt, Et)] and possibly through a fall in risk (ε) – An increase in the current level of capital reduces investment since it reduces Dte/Kt – A rise in the interest rate and/or the risk premium discourages investment by lowering qt – the rate at which future dividends are discounted will have risen A q-theory of housing investment • The model will be a special case of the q-theory adapted to fit the housing market • A theory of house price determination will also be developed • We will start with the production of housing (the supply) and then go on to develop a demand for housing equation based on consumers maximizing behaviour • Of note is that the stock of housing wealth is an important determinate of household wealth and therefore consumption The production and pricing of new housing • We will follow a similar qt-strategy for housing investment – that is, we will derive a measure of qt for this sector • We start with the production side of the construction sector which will give us the supply of housing I H A X , 0 1 • New housing is constructed with a composite input (Xt) and the production function exhibits diminishing returns to scale (β < 1) • The composite input uses labour (L) and building materials (Q) in fixed proportions L aX , Q bX The production and pricing of new housing con’t • Given a wage rate (W) and a price for materials (pQ) the price of the composite index, X, is equal to P aW bP Q • Before setting up the definition of profits, note that, based on the production function, we can write X as*: I H 1 H 1/ 1 (1 )/ X I A A A • Profits in the construction industry (Π = pHIH – PX) can be written as 6 4 4Production 4 7 4 cost 4 48 Sales (1 )/ 67 8 1 P 1/ 1 p H I H PX p H I H I H A A A * See final slide for a way to do this easily The production and pricing of new housing con’t • The first order condition to maximize construction profits (∂Π/∂IH = 0) yields H /(1 ) p I H k , P k /(1 ) A1/(1 ) where k is a positive constant • For housing, Tobin’s q is given by (pH/P) and housing investment will rise proportionally with it Looking at the demand of housing and the role of interest rates and income • We need to determine the demand for housing, which will allow us to introduce interest rates and income • After buying a house, a consumer must maintain its value by doing maintenance and repairs (δ). • If the house was completely financed by debt then the total cost of housing consumption will be (r + δ)pHH where H is the stock of housing • The cost of maintaining the original value of the house will be smaller (larger) if the prices are expected to rise (fall), which ˆ ge gives us a repair function The role of interest rates and income con’t • Ignoring saving, the consumer’s budget constraint is where C is non-durable consumption and Y is income • Utility is Cobb-Douglas and is given by • Using the definition for C from the budget constraint we have • The first order condition for a maximum is given by the usual condition dU/dH = 0 The steps taken to maximize utility • To do this simply, start with the definition of consumption C Y (r ) p H H • And note that dC (r )p H dH • Next look at the utility function U H C1 and taking the total derivative wrt to H we get 6 4U7/H48 6 44U7/C4 48 dU 1 1 dC H C (1 )H C H 1C1 (r ) p H (1 )H C dH dH • Which is equivalent to equation (25) in the text • The utility maximization condition then yields the MRS between housing and non-durable consumption as U /H (r ) pH U /C Deriving the demand curve for housing • We can write out the maximization condition as (r ) p H U /C U /H • Which then becomes (r ) p H (1 )H C H 1C1 • We can simplify the above by substituting in the definition of utility U = HηC(1-η) U U (r ) p (1 ) C H H (1 )(r ) p H H C (Y (r ) p H H ) • Now bring over to the left-hand side all the terms associated with H which yields (1 )[(r ) p H H ] [(r ) p H H ] Y The demand curve for housing • The last equation on the previous slide simplifies to equation (28) in the text Y H is the user cost of housing d where (r + δ)p H (r )p H • Housing demand varies positively with income and negatively with the user cost and house prices • Note that even if the purchase of a house was out of saving (not borrowing) the user cost still matters – In that case the r represents money that could have been earned on bonds and the homeowner is still responsible for maintenance • The relationship between the housing stock and its price in the short-run (when the stock of housing is fixed) is Short-run equilibrium in the housing market Housing stocks are slow to respond to demand changes implying price have to adjust 2.5 Real house prices (average growth rate) 2 Housing stock (average growth rate) 1.5 1 0.5 0 -0.5 1986-91 Growth rates are 5-year averages 1991-96 1996-01 2001-06 2006-11 The price of housing • From the figure on slide 42 we see that the larger is the stock of housing, the lower is the price • From slides 6 and 7 we know that house prices fluctuate a lot • The figure, as well as the equation for the short-run level of house prices (when the stock of housing is fixed), suggest that these fluctuations are due to changes in income and interest rates • There is also an expectations channel, which works through ˆ ge the depreciation term • Expected capital gains and losses will impact current house prices House prices seem to respond weakly to real interest rates 40 35 30 25 Change in hosue prices 20 15 10 5 0 -6.00 -4.00 -2.00 0.00 2.00 -5 -10 -15 Change in real interest rates 4.00 6.00 8.00 The housing investment function • In slide 36 we derived the investment function H /(1 ) p I H k P • Substituting into this equation the price relationship we derived from our demand equation gives • In a general format we have Developing a dynamic model of housing • We start with the price equation • Next we need the equation for housing investment (IH) H /(1 ) p H I k P • We can complete the model with the relationship between the stock of housing the next period and current investment Developing a dynamic model of housing, con’t • In the short run, the stock of housing is fixed and assuming no change in income or the user cost of housing, the price of housing (pH) is determined • Given pH and a value for P (the price of the composite input) the second equation determines the level of housing investment (IH) • Now that we have IH, the third equation determines the new stock of housing for the next period (Ht +1) • The new higher (lower) housing stock will give will give a new pH (from the first equation) which will feed into the investment equation and so on… H H ptH I tH H t1 pt1 I t1 H t2 ... • The process comes to an end when Ht +n = Ht +n+1 = H which, from the third equation, implies that IH = δH – investment is just sufficient to cover depreciation and house prices stop changing Simplifying the housing production function • In slide 35, it was found helpful to simplify the production function for housing investment I H 1/ 1 1/ X I H A A 1 ( 1) / A • We can use logs on just the 1/A part of the above to see how this is done 1 1/ 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 ln ln 11ln ln ln A A A A A • Taking the exponent of this expression we get 1 1/ 1 (1 )/ 1 A A A