Download Slide 1

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Financialization wikipedia , lookup

Internal rate of return wikipedia , lookup

Interest wikipedia , lookup

Global financial system wikipedia , lookup

Pensions crisis wikipedia , lookup

Credit rationing wikipedia , lookup

Balance of payments wikipedia , lookup

Bretton Woods system wikipedia , lookup

Interbank lending market wikipedia , lookup

Present value wikipedia , lookup

Continuous-repayment mortgage wikipedia , lookup

History of pawnbroking wikipedia , lookup

Purchasing power parity wikipedia , lookup

Interest rate ceiling wikipedia , lookup

Credit card interest wikipedia , lookup

Adjustable-rate mortgage wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Obstfeld, Shambaugh & Taylor (2005)
 Hypotheses
• Regimes with fixed exchange rates will experience less
monetary policy autonomy.
• Regimes with restrictions on capital mobility will
experience more monetary policy autonomy.
 The
exchange rate is the price of one currency
in terms of another.
• Appreciation: Increase in the value of a currency
• Depreciation: Decrease in the value of a currency.
 Fixed vs. floating exchange rate regimes
• Advanced economies :: floating rates are the norm
 Euro area is a notable exception
• Developing countries and emerging markets :: fixed
exchange rate regimes still common.
 This is true despite the potential for exchange rate crises.
 Fixed
vs. floating exchange rate regimes
 Two
key questions in the fixed versus flexible
exchange rate debate:
• What are the costs of a fixed exchange rate?
• What are the benefits?
 Three
common policy objectives:
1. Low exchange rate volatility
2. International capital mobility
3. Autonomy to implement stabilization policy.
 Trilemma
 Trilemma
:: theory tells us it is not possible to
achieve all three objectives at once.
• Floating exchange rate regime implies policymakers
forgo objective #1.
• Fixed exchange rate regime means giving up either #2
or #3.
 Adjust interest rates to keep the exchange rate fixed, OR
 Limit international capital flows, so restricting trade in the
foreign exchange market.
 Uncovered
Interest Rate Parity (UIP) Condition
• Assumption: capital flows freely across countries
• Idea: Expected return on bank deposits must be equal
in same currency terms.
 Arbitrage: If the returns were different, then investors would
flock to the country where the expected return is higher,
causing an appreciation in that country’s currency.
 Implications
of UIP
• Fixed exchange rate regime (peg): i = i*
 The central bank must adjust the interest rate to keep the
exchange rate from changing.
 Shocks to foreign interest rate are absorbed in the domestic
interest rate, implying domestic monetary policy shocks
(shifts in MP).
• Floating exchange rate regime (nonpeg)
 Central bank free to adjust interest rate to stabilize output.
 But, this means there is potential for larger changes in the
exchange rate.
 According
to UIP, what should we find in the
data on different exchange rate regimes?
• Fixed exchange rate regime, free capital mobility
 Changes in the foreign interest rate (base rate) should lead
to one-for-one adjustments in the domestic rate.
• Fixed exchange rate regime, no capital mobility
 Changes in the foreign interest rate (base rate) have low
predictive power for domestic interest rates.
• Floating exchange rate regime, stabilization policy
 Effects of changes in foreign interest rate are offset by
changes in the domestic rate in the opposite direction.
 Variables:
• Dependent variable: Domestic interest rate
• Explanatory variable: Foreign interest rate (“base rate”)
• Variables are measured in changes because for some
countries, interest rates may be nonstationary.
 Baseline
Specification: (1)
• Rit = Interest rate in country i at time t
• Rbit = Interest rate in country i’s base country at time t
 Test:
Fixed exchange rate regime, β = 1
 If β < 1, then central bank uses monetary policy to offset the
effects of base-rate shocks on output.
 If β > 1, then central bank uses monetary policy to reinforce
the effects of base-rate shocks on output.
 Panel
datasets of interest rates
• Gold standard era
 Sample: 1870-1914, 15 countries plus the United Kingdom
 Source: Neal & Weidenmier (2003)
 Base rate: U.K. (money market)
• Bretton Woods era
 Sample: 1959-1970, 21 countries
 Source: Average monthly data from International Finance
Statistics, Global Financial Data, and FRED.
 Base rate: U.S. (federal funds rate)
 Panel
datasets of interest rates
• Post-Bretton Woods era
 Sample: Average monthly money market rates, 1973-2000
 Source: IFS, Global Financial Data, Datastream, and FRED
 Base rate: varies by country (Germany, France, U.K., U.S.)
 Identification
of regime type
 Identification
of regime type
• Gold standard
 Use both de jure (official) and de facto (in practice)
classifications.
 De facto test: Commitment to peg in practice (2% band for
at least one year).
 13 peg episodes, 7 nonpeg episodes
 Assume capital mobility.
 Identification
of regime type
• Bretton Woods
 Nearly entire sample pegged according to de jure and de
facto classifications.
 20 peg episodes, 1 nonpeg episode
 Cannot use this era to study within-era regime switches.
 Assume no capital mobility.
 Identification
of regime type
• Post-Bretton Woods
 Shambaugh (2004) and de facto test applied to gold
standard coding.
 Robustness of results checked using a variety of methods:
 de facto classifications from the IMF and Taylor (2002),
 official de jure classifications, and
 Reinhart and Rogoff (2004) classifications.
 70 pegs, 25 occassional pegs, 32 nonpegs.
 IMF coding for capital control status.
 Pegs
versus nonpegs
• Estimate (1) for each group of countries in each era.
• Hypothesis: β = 1 for pegs, β < 1 for nonpegs.
 Pooled
estimation (2) with interaction term.
• Hypothesis: β2 > 0
 Nonpegs
have lower β and lower R2, all eras.
• i not as closely linked to i*.
• Changes in the base rate have little predictive power
for changes in the domestic rate.
• Having a floating exchange rate allows the country to
pursue autonomous monetary policy.
 Bretton
Woods: β < 0 and low R2.
• Imposition of capital controls appears to have
prevented one-for-one adjustments in the domestic
rate.
• Use of capital controls could explain why pegs have a
low R2 relative to gold standard and modern eras.
 Post-Bretton
Woods: high β and low R2.
• Nonpeg regimes more responsive to base rate changes
compared with the gold standard nonpegs.
 Pooled
estimates
• Regime choice affects no only intercept, but slope.
 Peg regimes have a larger average change and are more
responsive.
• Nonpegs in the post-Bretton Woods era are generally
more responsive than nonpegs under the gold
standard.
 Further
disaggregate regime according to
capital controls.
• Hypotheses:
 Pegs: higher β and higher R2
 Capital controls: lower β and lower R2
 Interaction terms for peg and capital controls
• PEG = 1 (if fixed exchange rate regime)
• CAP = 1 (if no capital controls)
• Hypotheses
 β2 > 0 :: pegs more responsive to changes in base rate
 β3 > 0 :: countries with capital mobility more
responsive to changes in base rate
 β4 > 0 :: pegs and capital mobility mean country more
responsive to changes in base rate
 Countries
have historically faced the trilemma,
and still do in the post-Bretton Woods era.
 Measure of monetary policy autonomy:
changes in interest rate relative to base rate.
• Countries with pegged exchange rates and capital
mobility have larger interest rate changes and are
more responsive to changes in the base rate.
• Theory predicts one-for-one adjustment for fixed
regimes, but estimates are closer to 0.5.
 True even for gold standard , widely viewed as a stricter than
Bretton Woods or modern-day fixed regimes.
 Bretton
Woods achieve policy autonomy and
pegs through imposing capital controls.
• System broke down when capital controls relaxed in
the 1960s.
 In
post-Bretton Woods era, countries more
responsive to changes in base rate, even for
nonpegs (vs. gold standard).
• Perhaps countries choose not to implement
autonomous policies, even when floating.
 Possible
to classify countries differently
• Peg, float, and managed float
• With the classifications used by Obstfeld, Shambaugh
and Taylor (2005) and Shambaugh (2004), countries
with managed floats might be counted as regime
switches throughout the sample.
• What would this tell us?
 Countries with managed float should be able to “hedge” the
trilemma problem.
 Result
that adjustment to base rate is less than
one-for one is inconsistent with theory.
• Possible omitted variable from the UIP condition?
• Perhaps a risk premium, associated with credibility of
the peg (currency risk) and probability of sovereign
default (default risk).
 Possible
bias in samples
• Fundamentally different countries across eras.
 Gold standard and Bretton Woods samples are dominated
by advanced economics.
 Modern sample dominated by developing countries.
 Implication
• If there were a risk premium, this would drive a wedge
between the interest rate and the base rate, especially
for developing countries, biasing the estimate of b
downward in the post-Bretton Woods sample.