* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Accounting for Emerging Market Countries` International Reserves
Exchange rate wikipedia , lookup
International Development Association wikipedia , lookup
Fixed exchange-rate system wikipedia , lookup
Bretton Woods system wikipedia , lookup
Purchasing power parity wikipedia , lookup
International monetary systems wikipedia , lookup
Reserve currency wikipedia , lookup
Accounting for Emerging Market Countries’ International Reserves: Are Pacific Rim Countries Different? * Atish R. Ghosh Jonathan D. Ostry Charalambos G. Tsangarides December 6, 2013 Preliminary draft Do not cite or circulate beyond conference participants Abstract Popular perception is that emerging market economies (EMEs), and Asian Pacific Rim countries—China, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam (RIMs)— in particular, have been rapidly accumulating reserves, perhaps beyond what is justified by precautionary motives. This paper compares and contrasts the determinants of the demand for international reserves in the RIM countries with other EMEs over the last three decades, based on current and capital account risks, mercantilist motives, and other motives. Our findings suggest shifting motives for holding reserves from insurance against current account shocks, insurance against capital account shocks, and as by-product of possible mercantilism. We also find some differences between country groups: RIM countries tend to hold more reserves against current account vulnerabilities and fewer reserves against capital account vulnerabilities, but more reserves overall. There is also greater evidence of mercantilist motives being at play for RIM countries, though the contribution of this motive in accounting for the rise in their reserve holdings is relatively small, peaked in 2004, and has diminished thereafter. JEL classification: E58, F15, F31, and F43 Keywords: International Reserves, Precautionary Demand, Mercantilism, Quantile Regression _____________________ * Paper prepared for City University of Hong Kong International Conference on Pacific Rim Countries and the Evolution of the International Financial Architecture, Hong Kong SAR, December 19-20, 2013. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the IMF, its Executive Board, or its management. Ghosh: Research Department, IMF, Suite 9-612G, 700 19th Street, N.W., Washington D.C. 20431 (email: [email protected]); Ostry: Research Department, IMF, Suite 10-700F, 700 19th Street, N.W., Washington D.C. 20431 (email: [email protected]); Tsangarides: Research Department, IMF, Suite 9-612B, 700 19th Street, N.W., Washington D.C. 20431 (email: [email protected]). 2 I. INTRODUCTION Over the past few decades, despite somewhat greater exchange rate flexibility, and some draw down during the global financial crisis, emerging market economies (EMEs) have been accumulating large stocks of international reserves. Reserve holdings, which averaged about 5 percent of GDP in the 1980s, have been doubling every decade since, reaching some 25 percent of GDP by 2010. While foreign exchange reserves may provide useful insurance in the face of current or capital account shocks, there is often a perception that reserves are not being accumulated for precautionary purposes but rather as the by-product of deliberate mercantilism. Beyond the possibility of unfair trade practices and exchange rate manipulation, such mercantilism may perpetuate global imbalances and ultimately undermine the stability of the international monetary system (Ghosh et al., 2010). Asian countries, notably those on the Pacific Rim (RIM), are often singled out for purportedly pursing export-led growth strategies by keeping their currencies undervalued, in turn resulting in excessive reserve accumulation. For instance, writing in 2010, Paul Krugman claimed Today [2010], China is adding more than $30 billion a month to its $2.4 trillion hoard of reserves. This is the most distortionary exchange rate policy any major nation has ever followed.1 And as recently as 2013, Dani Rodrik has noted that: Although China phased out many of its explicit export subsidies… mercantilism’s support system remains largely in place. In particular, the government has managed the exchange rate to maintain manufacturers’ profitability, resulting in a sizable trade surplus. But does this view have any merit? In this paper, we take up that question with specific reference to the Asian Pacific Rim countries— China, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam. There are potentially two approaches to addressing this question. The first is to try to establish an absolute norm for how much reserves are required for precautionary purposes, with any further accumulation that is undertaken in the context of an undervalued currency being deemed “mercantilism”. The main difficulty with this approach is that “how much is enough” is an evolving standard: what was sufficient for current account shocks in the 1980s was clearly inadequate for the EME capital account crises of the 1990s. Likewise, prior to the global financial crisis, many commentators thought that Russia’s US$600 billion of reserves were ample, and perhaps even excessive, yet that view was rapidly revised when the central bank spent more than one-third of its reserve stock in the space of a couple of months. Moreover, existing reserve adequacy metrics generally have wide margins—the recently 1 Paul Krugman (14 March 2010). "Taking on China and its currency" http://www.nytimes.com/2010/03/15/opinion/15krugman.html. Dani Rodrik 2013, The New Mercantilist challenge, http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/the-return-of-mercantilism-by-dani-rodrik 3 developed IMF methodology for assessing reserve adequacy, for instance, suggests a range between 100 and 150 percent of its Reserve Adequacy Metric as being appropriate, but for the typical EME, that range translates into 10 percent of GDP. In this paper, therefore, we adopt a more pragmatic tack. Rather than try to assess whether Asian RIM countries are stockpiling excessive reserves against some absolute standard, we compare the behavior of RIM countries to that of other emerging market economies. This allows for evolving notions of reserve adequacy while still assessing whether RIM countries are exceptional in their reserves accumulation behavior. Specifically, we seek to determine whether RIM countries hold more reserves than non-RIM countries, controlling for various current and capital account vulnerabilities; whether they react differently in terms of their reserve holdings to such vulnerabilities; and whether a larger proportion of their reserve accumulation over the past twenty years can be accounted for by mercantilist motives. Building on our earlier work (Ghosh, Ostry, and Tsangarides (2012), henceforth GOT), we define mercantilism as reserve accumulation that is unrelated to current or capital account vulnerabilities and that takes place in the context of an undervalued currency. Our empirical strategy proceeds in three steps. We begin by estimating a reserve demand function for a large sample of (RIM and non-RIM) EMEs over the period 1980-2010 relating reserve holdings (expressed in percent of GDP) to precautionary motives (current and capital account vulnerabilities) and mercantilism. Our estimates allow for the possibility that the motives for reserve accumulation differ over time, or according to the level of reserve holdings. Our first test is simply whether RIM countries hold significantly more reserves than non-RIM countries, controlling for their current and capital account vulnerabilities. Next, we allow for the possibility that RIM countries’ reserve holdings react systematically differently to the various vulnerabilities (as well as to currency undervaluation and the other determinants) by introducing RIM interaction terms. Finally, we decompose countries’ reserve accumulation since 1990 into the various motives to examine their relative importance in the RIM and non-RIM samples. Our findings may be summarized briefly. First, for the EME sample as whole, the analysis suggest shifting motives for reserve accumulation—in the 1980s (and at low levels of reserves), it was mostly insurance against current account shocks; in the 1990s (especially post-Asian crisis), insurance against capital account shocks became more important; in the 2000s (and at higher levels of reserves), there is greater evidence of mercantilism. Second, there is some evidence that RIM countries hold more reserves than would be expected on the basis of their current and capital account vulnerabilities. Allowing for different responses across country groups suggests that, while RIM countries hold more reserves in general, they hold fewer reserves against capital account shocks—the exception being the period immediately following the Asian crisis—but hold more reserves against current account vulnerabilities. Third, decomposing the factors behind the build-up of EME reserves since the 1ate 1990s suggests that (the by-product of) mercantilism has played a more important 4 role in the RIM sample than in the non-RIM sample. Overall, we conclude that there is some merit to the view that reserve accumulation by RIM countries has been different from other EMEs, including because mercantilist motives have been more important. Yet it is important not to exaggerate the importance of mercantilist motives in accounting for the higher reserve accumulation. Our estimates imply that, at its peak (in 2004), mercantilist motives accounted for an average of 3½ percent of GDP of the stock of reserves accumulated by RIM countries (in other words, absent such mercantilist motives, RIM countries’ average reserve holdings in 2004 would have been 3½ percent of GDP lower). Moreover, this contribution to the stock of reserves subsequently shrank, to around 2.3 percent of GDP by 2007, remaining roughly constant thereafter. Hence, we find little evidence that RIM countries on average continue to accumulate reserves due to mercantilist motives. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section II reviews the literature and lays out our empirical strategy. Section III presents our main OLS results. Section IV turns to quantile regressions. Section V concludes. II. EMPIRICAL STRATEGY A. Determinants of demand for reserves Traditional explanations—and policy prescriptions—for holding foreign exchange reserves centered on the “insurance” that reserves provide. The original “three months of imports” rule, for instance, was designed to help insulate developing countries against current account shocks: shortfalls in export earnings or domestic shocks—such as natural disasters—that might necessitate exceptionally large imports. As developing and emerging market countries became more financially integrated, insulation against capital account shocks gained importance—as amply demonstrated by the emerging market crises of the 1990s. By providing confidence to investors, reserves can reduce the likelihood of a sudden stop and rush for the exit or—if they nevertheless materialize—cushion the economy from their consequences (Ben-Bassat and Gottlieb (1992)). Rather than three months of imports, insurance against capital account shocks calls for reserves to be held against short-term debt (or other skittish foreign liabilities) and possibly against M2, in case domestic investors lose confidence in the banking system and the currency—as happened during the Mexican and Indonesian crises—and rush for the exit as well. While in principle reserve demand should be a function of the exchange rate regime, in practice few EMEs can be truly indifferent to the 5 level of the exchange rate, and most studies find few differences in reserve holdings according to the country’s exchange rate regime.2 Recent cost-benefit calibration models cast reserve accumulation as an explicit optimization problem, with reserves chosen to provide the optimal insurance against a sudden drop in consumption given risk aversion and the costs of holding reserves (see Caballero and Panageas (2008), Jeanne (2007), and Jeanne and Rancière (2006)). Empirical contributions confirm the importance of precautionary determinants in explaining reserve holdings in EMEs (see, for example, Bastourre, Carrera and Ibarlucia (2010), Obstfeld, Shambaugh and Taylor (2010), Cheung and Qian (2009), and de Beaufort Wijnholds and Kapteyn (2001)). For East Asia in particular, Aizenman and Lee (2007) and Aizenman and Marion (2003) provide some evidence for precautionary motives in post-Asian crisis reserve accumulation. 3 A quite different explanation for observed reserve holdings is that they are the unintentional by-product of modern mercantilism. In this view, emerging market economies—perhaps following the examples of Europe and Japan during the Bretton Woods period (Dooley et al., 2002)—often seek to maintain deliberately undervalued currencies through foreign exchange intervention (often supplemented by controls on capital inflows) in order to promote exports as part of an export-led growth strategy. Ghosh and Kim (2008) consider an economy in which the government has an incentive to maintain an undervalued exchange rate because it is equivalent to an export subsidy (the cost of sterilized intervention being the analog of the subsidy cost) in an economy where there are positive productivity spillovers, external to the firm, of output in the tradable sector. Aizenman and Lee (2008) show that, in a two-country game, such mercantilism can lead to the inefficient accumulation of reserves as each country engages in beggar-thy-neighbor competitive depreciations. Since it is not possible to observe the intentions of the monetary authorities directly, it is very difficult to establish whether reserves are being accumulated as a by-product of mercantilist motives or for some other reason. It is quite possible, for instance, that the central bank is trying to maintain an undervalued currency not to promote exports or gain some unfair trade 2 If the central bank was truly indifferent to what happened to the exchange rate, it would not need to hold any reserves. But even EMEs with more flexible exchange rates may want to insure against extreme events and hold reserves accordingly. 3 Aizenman and Marion (2003) use the volatility of export receipts as their measure of current account shocks, and implicitly include external debt and broad money in their analysis, but do not account for possible mercantilism. Aizenman and Lee (2007) and Delatte and Fouquau (2012) try to capture possible mercantilist motives, but neither includes banking system liabilities, and both are constrained to rather crude PPP-based measures of undervaluation, which they do not find to be robust determinants of reserves. 6 advantage, but because it needs to accumulate reserves for precautionary purposes. 4 To address this fundamental identification problem, here we follow GOT to define the mercantilist motive as reserve accumulation that is uncorrelated with proxies of current or capital account vulnerabilities, and that takes place in the context of a substantially undervalued currency. For our definition, we also require that the exchange rate undervaluation be substantial—an estimated misalignment of at least10 percent. B. Empirical Specification Full sample and sub-periods For our baseline regression, we follow GOT to include various proxies of current and capital account vulnerabilities as well as currency undervaluation (to capture the mercantilist motive), augmenting their specification to differentiate between RIM and non-RIM countries: ln Rit 0 CACAit KA KAit M Mercantilistit R regimeit O Otherit RIM RIM it CARIM CAit RIM it KARIM KAit RIM it MRIM Mercantilistit RIM it (1) RRIM regimeit RIM it ORIM Otherit RIM it it where CAit ln M it , XVolit ,VolExtDemit , KAit ln BM it , KOpenit , Debtit , regimeit NeerVolit , Pegit , Mercantilistit Undervalit , and Otherit OppCostit ,ln GDPpcit ,ln Popit . - lnRit is the natural log of reserves to GDP for country i at time t valued expressed as a ratio to GDP; - CAit includes proxies for current account precautionary motives, namely, the log of imports to GDP, the volatility of exports (measured as three-year standard deviation), and the volatility of external demand captured by the trading partners’ growth volatility (scaled by exports). Increases in the volatility of external demand are expected to result in more precautionary reserve accumulation as insulation from exogenous (partner) demand, while reserve accumulation is expected to be positively related to imports to GDP and export volatility; 4 Of course the current account is not the only way that the central bank can accumulate reserves: it can also do so by borrowing through the capital account. 7 - KAit includes the log of M2 to GDP; a measure of the de jure openness of the capital account—the Chinn-Ito index, which is based on the IMF Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Restrictions; and short-term debt to GDP. All financial variables are expected to be positively related to reserve accumulation; - Regimeit includes the volatility of the nominal effective exchange rate, and a dummy variable for de facto pegged exchange rate regime. Both coefficients are expected to be negative; - Mercantilist is proxy for exchange rate undervaluation, as defined in GOT. Countries with undervalued exchange rates are expected to hold more reserves (in the target country’s currency) needed to maintain/reduce the value of their exchange rate; and - Other includes a proxy for the opportunity cost of holding reserves (measured as interest rate differential with the US), and two scaling variables, the log of population, and the log of real GDP per capita at purchasing power parity. Reserve accumulation is expected to be positively related to the scale variables, and negatively related to the opportunity cost. Finally, is a random error term.5 To examine how the estimates obtained for (1) change when the sample is divided in several sub periods, namely (i) the 1980s, 1990-1997, 1998-2010; (ii) 1980-1997, and 1998-2010; and (iii) 1980-1997, 1998-2003, and 2004-2010. The cutoffs are chosen to coincide with the Asian crisis, and the post 2000 surge in reserves. Quantile regressions As discussed above, motives for holding reserves may have shifted over time, particularly as EMEs have become more financially integrated. Different motives may also apply at a given point in time, but at different points along the sample distribution of reserve holdings. For example, countries that hold low levels of reserves may do so because they are not very financially integrated and are mostly concerned about current account rather than capital account shocks. Conditional quantile functions may offer a more complete picture of the effect of the reserve demand determinants covariates on the location, scale and shape of the distribution of the reserve accumulation. Using quantile regressions, we allow the elasticities to vary across the various quantiles (q) of reserve accumulation. For a quantile q, equation (2) is modified as follows: 5 We do not include country fixed effects in equation (1) as that would imply identifying the effect of the variables solely through their time variation (and it is not very informative economically). However, we cluster standard errors at the country level. 8 q q ln Rit 0q CA CAit KA KAit Mq Mercantilistit Rq regimeit Oq Otherit q q q q RIM RIM it CARIM CAit RIM it KARIM KAit RIM it MRIM Mercantilistit RIM it (2) q q RRIM regimeit RIM it ORIM Otherit RIM it it For various values of q, we obtain estimated intercepts and slopes and conduct tests to examine differences across quantiles. Data Following GOT, we construct several estimates for misalignments based on application of three equilibrium exchange rate methodologies, namely, the macro balance (MB), the equilibrium real effective rate (ERER), and external sustainability (ES). We begin by constructing misalignment estimates based on each of the three methodologies and then combine estimates from the three methods to construct the average and median misalignments. Median misalignments are then translated into three-way classifications for aligned, overvalued and undervalued exchange rates. Given the uncertainty surrounding estimates, we consider percentage deviations of [-10, 10] as aligned, less than -10 (more than +10) undervalued (overvalued). Appendix A in GOT describes the methodologies used and the construction of each of the misalignment estimates in detail. The remaining variables are constructed from the IMF’s WEO, IFS, and INS databases. The exchange rate regime classifications are derived from the IMF’s revised classification published in the 2009 Annual Report on Exchange Rate Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions. Using the IMF’s de facto exchange rate regime classification at the end of each period of the analysis, we classify exchange rate regimes into fixed and non-fixed, as well as separating the pegs into hard and soft pegs. Tables A1 and A2 in Appendix A provide details on the sample, the variables used, and summary statistics. III. THE STORY IN SIMPLE AVERAGES Popular perception is that EMEs, and RIM countries in particular, have been rapidly stockpiling reserves, perhaps beyond what is justified by precautionary motives. A first glance at the data indeed shows not only that EMEs have increased their reserve holdings markedly (in relation to GDP) over the past three decades, but also that RIM countries have, on average, held more reserves (in relation to their GDP) than their non-RIM counterparts (Figure 1). Over the full sample period, 1980-2010, RIM countries’ reserve holdings averaged 17 percent of GDP compared to 12 percent of GDP for non-RIM countries. By the eve of the global financial crisis, this difference was even more marked: at end-2007 reserves amounted to 32 percent of GDP in RIM countries and 18 percent of GDP in the non-RIM sample. Subsequently, however, while EME reserves have more than recovered from their use during the global crisis, the difference between RIM and non-RIM countries has narrowed to 9.7 percent of GDP. 9 Why might RIM countries hold more reserves? As discussed above, traditional explanations would be that they face larger current or capital account vulnerabilities, and therefore have greater country insurance needs. Again, a first glance at the data suggests this explanation might have merit: over the full sample and various sub-periods (1980-97; 98-2004; 2005-10), RIM countries exhibit greater current and capital account vulnerabilities (Figures 2(a)-2(d)). For instance, imports average 35 percent of GDP in RIM sample compared to less than 30 percent of GDP in the non-RIM sample, with the difference between them rising to some 15 percent of GDP by 2007. Although RIM countries tend to have lower short-term debt (especially in the latter part of the sample), their banking system monetary liabilities (M2/GDP) are almost twice as large as those in non-RIM countries. But the mercantilist story also gets some (potential) support. RIM countries’ are, on average, 7 percent more undervalued than non-RIM countries during the whole period of analysis, and about 22 percent more undervalued during the 2000s.6 Looking across the distribution of reserve holdings suggests that the relationships may be different at various levels of reserves (Figure 3). Median reserve holdings have been increasing much more rapidly in RIMs compared to non-RIMs—in fact, the bottom 25th percentile of the RIM countries almost exceeds the top 75th percentile of the non-RIM countries. Unlike non-RIMs, the dispersion in reserve holdings across RIMs has also risen, with the difference between the top and bottom quartiles widening from 13 percent of GDP in 1980-1997 to 20 percent of GDP in 2005-10. Overall, there is considerable time series and cross sectional variation in reserve holdings between RIM and non-RIM countries, as well as within the distribution of each sample. These results suggest that reserve demand determinants may be different between RIM and non-RIM countries, a point that reinforces the motivation of our paper. In addition, while the average behavior of RIM versus non-RIM countries is certainly informative, there may be a richer story taking account of differences between these groups of countries at various points in the reserves holdings distribution that bears examination. IV. PERIOD ANALYSIS OF RESERVE DEMAND We estimate our full model (1) in steps, adding groups of variables (scale, regime, opportunity cost, current account, capital account, and mercantilist) sequentially. For the moment, in the estimation we allow RIM and non-RIM countries to differ only in the intercept term by the inclusion of a dummy variable for RIM countries (Table 1). The 6 These are the estimates of exchange rate misalignment in percent. Given the large margins surrounding these point estimates, in the empirical work below, we use a dummy variable for (more than) 10 percent undervaluation. 10 regressions are estimated on centered variables so the exponentiated value of the constant gives the average reserve holdings for the non-RIM sample.7 Adding explanatory variables in sequence suggests that exchange rate regime, current and capital account precautionary variables, and mercantilist motives are important in explaining reserve accumulation in the broader sample of RIM and non-RIM countries. The full model including all explanatory variables is given in Table 1[7]. The model explains about 56 percent of the variation in reserve holdings (without the inclusion of annual or country fixed effects), with both current account and capital account precautionary motives as well as mercantilist motives statistically significant and with the expected signs. Countries with higher per capita income hold more reserves; although the fixed exchange rate regime dummy is insignificant, countries with more flexible exchange rate regimes (as measured by the volatility of the nominal effective exchange rate) do hold fewer reserves. All of the current account vulnerability variables are significant: a one standard deviation increase in the imports-to-GDP ratio, the volatility of exports, or the volatility of partner country growth increases reserve holdings by roughly one-half percent of GDP. Turning to capital account vulnerabilities, short-term debt is insignificant, but a one-standard deviation increase in broad money-to-GDP or financial openness, is associated with 0.2 to 1.5 percent of GDP higher reserves. Other things equal, reserves of a country with an undervalued currency are 2 percent of GDP greater than those of a country whose currency is not undervalued. Looking at the sub-periods (Table 1 [8-10]), suggests shifting motives for reserve holdings by EMEs. In the 1980s, it was insurance against current account shocks was the predominant motivation for holding reserves with capital account motives almost non-existent. Following the capital account crises of the 1990s, insurance against capital account shocks became more important. These effects are large: a one standard deviation increase in the short-term debtto-GDP ratio (corresponding to an increase in short-term debt of 5 percent of GDP) is associated with 0.7 percent of GDP higher reserves. And as of the late 1990s, there is greater evidence of mercantilism with the undervaluation dummy turning economically and statistically significant.8 Are RIM Countries Different? Turning to our main question of interest, the regressions in Table 1 include a dummy variable for RIM countries. In specifications [1]-[3], which include only the “scale” variables (per 7 For example, a specification with only the scale variables (log(per capita income) and log(population)) included implies that average reserves holdings by non-RIM countries were exp(-2.453)=8.6 percent of GDP, compared to 20.4 (=exp(-2.453+0.864)) percent of GDP in RIM countries. 8 These results are robust to a variety of specifications, instrumentation for possible endogeneity of the regressors, and the inclusion of additional control variables; see GOT for a full discussion. 11 capita income and population), the RIM dummy is statistically significant, and indicates that RIM countries hold some 10 to 12 percent of GDP more reserves than corresponding nonRIM countries. Once the current and capital account vulnerabilities are included in the regression (Table 1 [4]-[7]), the RIM dummy turns insignificant—suggesting that RIM countries are no different controlling for their vulnerabilities. While that may be partly true, it is also possible that multi-colinearity between the various explanatory variables is masking statistically significant differences. It is noteworthy, for instance, that population—which is insignificant in specifications [1]-[3]—suddenly turns positive and statistically significant. To address this concern, Table 2 reports the coefficients of a similar regression, but where the various proxies of scale, current account vulnerabilities, and capital account vulnerabilities are replaced by their respective first principal components. In the full model (Table 2 [7]), the current account, capital account, and undervaluation proxies are all statistically significant. Moreover, the RIM dummy retains its statistical significance and implies that controlling for current and capital account vulnerabilities, RIM countries hold 4.5 percent of GDP higher reserves than non-RIM countries (Table 2 [5]). Adding our proxy for mercantilism, the difference between RIM and non-RIM countries shrinks to 3.8 percent of GDP but remains statistically significant. Across sub-samples, the RIM dummy is significant until 2004, but turns insignificant for the period 2005-10. The results are similar, but starker, for China. The China dummy is significant even in the full model with multiple proxies current and capital account vulnerabilities and mercantilism. The estimates imply that China holds 11 percent of GDP more reserves than would be expected on the basis of its current and capital account vulnerabilities (Table 2 [11]). The results for the RIM sample are not being driven by the inclusion of China within the group, however: excluding China leaves the RIM dummy statistically significant and of almost the same magnitude. Overall, therefore, controlling for precautionary motives, there is a statistically significant difference between the reserve holdings of RIM and non-RIM countries, part—but only part—of which is explained by greater mercantilist behavior on the part of RIM countries. Do RIM Countries Respond Differently to Vulnerabilities? The analysis above imposes the same slope coefficients for RIM countries as non-RIM countries. One reason for the statistically significant RIM dummy may be that RIM countries respond differently to the current and capital account vulnerabilities. For example, if RIM countries were more risk averse, they may wish to hold higher reserves against a given level of vulnerability. If so, imposing the same (lower) coefficient as the non-RIM sample would force the difference to be captured by the RIM dummy. To allow for this possibility, Table 3 re-estimates the regression but now allowing both the 12 intercept and the slope coefficients to differ between RIM and non-RIM countries, and Table 4 repeats this analysis using the principal component proxies.9 In either case, the analysis suggests that RIM countries do respond to vulnerabilities somewhat differently from nonRIM countries. Specifically, RIM countries hold more reserves against current account vulnerabilities than non-RIM countries: a one standard deviation increase in the current account proxy raises reserve holdings by 2.5 percent of GDP in non-RIM countries but by 3.7 percent of GDP in RIM countries (Table 4 [7]). This is partly offset, however, by lower reserve holdings against capital account shocks: a one standard deviation increase in the capital account proxy raises reserve holdings by 3.0 percent of GDP in non-RIM countries but by only 2 percent of GDP in RIM countries (Table 4 [7]). The negative interactive RIM dummy on capital account vulnerabilities is significant in all sub-periods except 1998-2004 when, presumably in response to the Asian crisis, RIM countries sought to insure themselves against capital account shocks to the same degree as other EMEs who were learning from the financial crises of the 1990s. There are a few other differences between RIM and non-RIM countries, with some evidence that RIM countries are more sensitive to the costs of holding reserves (especially in the latter part of the sample, 2005-10), and in some specifications and sub-periods, the RIM interaction term on the undervaluation variable turns negative and statistically significant (Table 3 [8]-[9]).10 With (largely) offsetting differences in RIM countries’ responses to current account and capital account vulnerabilities compared to non-RIM countries, the story above remains unchanged: even allowing for the different responses to these vulnerabilities, over the full sample period, RIM countries hold 9.5 percent of GDP than non-RIM countries—though this differential shrinks over time, falling to 4.7 percent of GDP and turning insignificant by 2005-10. V. QUANTILE ANALYSIS OF RESERVE DEMAND Thus far, our discussion has been based on the average behavior of RIM and non-RIM countries. But as noted in Section II, there is also substantial variation in reserve holdings both within and across the two groups of countries. We therefore turn to quantile regressions, as specified in (2), which allow the relationship between reserve holdings and the various 9 We do not interact the “scale” variables (population, per capita income) with the RIM dummy as that simply assigns a lot of weight on the population variable, given the high correlation between RIM countries and population (0.41; or 0.31 excluding China). 10 The interpretation of this negative interaction term for the period 1980-2004 is that RIM countries held fewer reserves for a given degree of exchange rate undervaluation—or, turning the statement around, they were able to achieve a given undervaluation with less reserve accumulation than non-RIM countries. One reason may be that RIM countries were more financially closed during this period. 13 explanatory variables to vary by the level of reserve holdings.11 As before, we first estimate the full model (Table 5), then collapse the various proxies to their first principal component (Table 6), and finally allow for the slope coefficients to differ between RIM and non-RIM countries. The quantile regressions show that, at relatively low levels (in percent of GDP) of reserve holdings, precautionary motives against current account shocks dominate (Table 5[12-15]).12 In part, this echoes the story above: reserves were low during the early part of the sample (the 1980s), and precautionary motives against current account shocks were the main driving force behind reserve holdings. But while the low-reserves observations are predominantly in the early part of the sample, they are not exclusively so, thus low-reserve holders in general (regardless of the time period) tend hold them against current account shocks. Perhaps more surprising is that the mercantilist motive also seems to be important for the low-reserve observations; closer examination, however, shows that in many of these cases, the country was losing reserves—that is, the “undervaluation” reflected collapsed exchange rates (mainly during crises) as the country exhausted its reserves, rather than deliberate undervaluation for mercantilism.13 The picture is more mixed for capital account vulnerabilities. For high reserves holders, capital account vulnerabilities (particularly broad money) are more important, but financial openness and short-term debt are more important at the lower end of the distribution—while being smaller and/or insignificant for high reserves holders (this is intuitive inasmuch as many high reserve holders have very little short-term debt, and certainly ample reserves to cover their debt). Are RIM Countries Different? As before, to ensure that results are not influenced by possible co-linearity of the proxies, we repeat the analysis using their principal components in Table 6. As in the case of the period 11 Quantile regression techniques developed by Koenker and Bassett (1978) and Koenker and Hallock (2001). Quantile regressions allow the estimation of conditional quantile functions—models in which various quantiles (or percentiles) of the conditional distribution of reserve accumulation are expressed as functions of the determinants. While classical linear regression methods are based on minimizing sums of squared residuals and estimate models for conditional mean functions, quantile regression methods are based on minimizing asymmetrically weighted absolute residuals and can estimate conditional functions at any part of the reserves’ distribution. 12 The 25th, 50th, 75th, 90th, and 99th percentiles correspond to reserves of 5.6, 11.0, 18.4, 27.3, and 54.0 percent of GDP, respectively. Of the 175 RIM country observations, 119 (i.e., 68 percent) are above the sample median, and 56 (i.e., 32 percent) are below the median. 13 Recall that our definition of mercantilism requires that the country be accumulating reserves in the context of an undervalued currency (and that such accumulation be uncorrelated with precautionary needs). 14 analysis, collapsing the vulnerability proxies improves the precision of the estimation. The results (Table 6 [1]-[4]) seem to suggest that RIM countries differ from non-RIM countries only in the lower quartiles of the reserves distribution. For countries with belowmedian reserves, RIM countries hold some 3-4 percent of GDP more reserves than would be expected given their vulnerabilities (and assuming the same response to these vulnerabilities as other EMEs). For countries with above-median reserves, RIM countries do not appear to hold more reserves than their peers. The latter conclusion, however, is heavily dependent on the homogeneity assumption. In Table 7, we allow the slope coefficients to differ across country groups. Doing so suggests that (above the 25th percentile) RIM countries hold more reserves against current account shocks than do non-RIM countries, but (across the reserves holding distribution), fewer reserves against capital account shocks than their non-RIM counterparts. The net result is that the RIM dummy becomes significant across the distribution, with the implication that, controlling for current and capital account vulnerabilities (and the RIM countries response to them), RIM countries hold some 3½ - 8½ percent of GDP more reserves than would be expected. VI. RESERVE ACCUMULATION TRENDS AND MODEL FIT How well does the model account for RIM and non-RIM reserve accumulation? And what has been driving reserve accumulation in recent years by RIM and non-RIM countries? In this section we try to answer these questions by comparing the model’s fitted reserve holdings to actual reserve holdings, and by decomposing the cumulative change in the stock of reserves since 1990 into the various precautionary and mercantilist motives. Figure 4 compares fitted and actual reserve holdings on the eve of the global financial crisis, where the slope coefficients on the regressors are constrained to be the same for RIM and non-RIM countries (i.e., Table 1 [7]). The picture reinforces the impression that RIM countries generally hold more reserves than would be expected on the basis of their vulnerabilities: except for Korea (and Indonesia, which is exactly on the line), all of the RIM countries held more reserves than the model would imply—with the difference, in many cases, exceeding 2 standard deviations of the fitted value; on average, RIM countries were holding some 5½ percent of GDP more reserves than their corresponding non-RIM peers. Figure 5 repeats this exercise but now using the specification where the slope coefficients are allowed to vary between the RIM and non-RIM samples (Table 3 [7]). While this naturally reduces the gap between actual and fitted values, it is noteworthy that most RIM countries remain above the 45° line—with actual reserves of China, Malaysia, Thailand, and the Philippines in 2007 exceeding the model’s fitted value by more than two standard deviations. While the average residual for RIM countries shrinks from 5½ percent of GDP to 15 about 4½ percent of GDP, it remains substantial—consistent with the results above that, even allowing for possible differences in responses to vulnerabilities, RIM countries hold higher reserves than would be expected. Accounting for Reserve Accumulation What has been driving reserves accumulation by EMEs—and by RIM countries in particular—over the past few years? Figure 6 (a, b, c) decompose the factors behind RIM countries’ accumulation of reserves since 1990 using model specifications without the RIM dummy, with the RIM dummy, and with the RIM slope coefficients respectively. The various specifications tell a consistent story, with most of the difference between them being the split between the contribution of current account vulnerabilities (greater when the RIM-specific slopes are used) and the model residual. Perhaps contrary to popular perception, and regardless of which specification is adopted, the contribution of mercantilism is quite limited. The contribution of mercantilism, at its peak in 2004, was around 3½ percent of GDP; that is, in the counterfactual in which no mercantilist motive was operative, RIM countries’ average reserves holding in 2004 would have been 3½ percent of GDP lower. Moreover, this 3½ percent of GDP contribution to the stock of reserves either shrinks or stays relatively constant thereafter. In other words, there is little evidence that, on average, RIM countries continue to accumulate reserves for mercantilist reasons (as defined here). At the same time, it should be acknowledged that for non-RIM countries, mercantilism never appears to have been a driving force behind their reserves accumulation (Figure 7). VII. CONCLUSIONS Over the past three decades, emerging market economies have accumulated large stocks of reserves, prompting suspicions that more than precautionary motives are at play. Asian Pacific Rim countries, in particular, are often singled out for accumulating reserves as a byproduct of modern mercantilism—deliberate undervaluation of the currency as part of an export-led growth strategy. In this paper, we seek to assess the validity of this view by comparing Asian RIM countries to their non-RIM emerging market counterparts. Our analysis points to three main conclusions. First, the reasons why EMEs hold reserves has shifted over time, and depends on the level of reserves. In the 1980s, and at low reserve holdings, reserves were mainly intended as insurance against current account shocks. In the 1990s, and following the emerging market financial crises in particular, insurance against capital account shocks gained importance. Added to this, in the 2000s, is greater evidence of mercantilist motives—that is, reserve accumulation that is uncorrelated with vulnerabilities and that takes place in the context of a substantially undervalued currency. Second, RIM countries do differ from their non-RIM counterparts: they hold more reserves against current 16 account vulnerabilities but fewer reserves against capital account vulnerabilities, and overall hold more reserves than would be expected on the basis of these vulnerabilities. Adding the mercantilist motive shrinks this difference, but only somewhat—so mercantilism provides, at best, only a partial explanation. Third, confirming this, decomposition of the reasons behind RIM countries’ reserve accumulation in recent decades suggests only a modest role for mercantilist motives—with very little evidence that RIM countries, on average, continue to accumulate reserves as a by-product of mercantilism. We are thus left with a puzzle: why do RIM countries consistently hold more reserves than precautionary (or even mercantilist) motives would imply? One reason may be that they want to insure against shocks that are not captured here. Another reason may be that reserves provide benefits beyond their insurance value. Yet a third possibility is that restrictions on capital outflows mean that the public sector holds external assets that would otherwise be accumulated by the private sector. Future research will need to explore these possibilities more fully. What is clear is that, when it comes to holding reserves, RIM countries do differ from their non-RIM emerging market counterparts—and simply blaming this on mercantilism will not suffice. 17 REFERENCES Aizenman, Joshua, and Jaewoo Lee, 2008, “Financial Versus Monetary Mercantilism LongRun View of Large International Reserves Hoarding,” The World Economy, Vol. 31, pp. 593–611. ———, 2007, “International Reserves: Precautionary Versus Mercantilist Views, Theory and Evidence,” Open Economies Review, Vol. 18, pp. 191–214. Aizenman, Joshua, and Nancy P. Marion, 2003, “The High Demand for International Reserves in the Far East: What Is Going On?” Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, Vol. 17, pp. 370–400. Bastourre, Diego, Jorge Carrera, and Javier Ibarlucia, 2009, “What is Driving Reserves Accumulation.” Review of International Economics, Vol. 17, pp. 861–77. Ben-Bassat, Avraham, and Daniel Gottlieb, 1992, “Optimal International Reserves and Sovereign Risk.” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 33, pp. 345–62. De Beaufort Wijnholds, J. Onno, and Arend Kapteyn, 2001, “Reserve Adequacy in Emerging Market Economies.” IMF Working Paper 01/143 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Caballero, Ricardo J., and Stavros Panageas, 2008, “Hedging Sudden Stops and Precautionary Contractions.” Journal of Development Economics, Vol.85, pp. 28–57. Cheung Yin-Wong, and Xingwang Qian, 2009, “Hoarding of International Reserves: Mrs. Machlup’s Wardrobe and the Joneses.” Review of International Economics, Vol. 17, pp. 824–43. Dooley, Michael P., David Folkerts-Landau, and Peter Garber, 2005, International Financial Stability (New York: Deutsche Bank). Ghosh, Atish R., and Jonathan D. Ostry, 1997. “Macroeconomic Uncertainty, Precautionary Saving, and the Current Account.” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 40, pp. 121– 139. Ghosh, Atish R., Jonathan D. Ostry, and Charalambos Tsangarides, 2010, “Exchange Rate Regimes and the Stability of the International Monetary System.” IMF Occasional Paper No. 270 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). 18 ——— 2012, “Shifting Motives: Explaining the Buildup in Official Reserves in Emerging Markets since the 1980s.” IMF Working Paper 12/34 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Jeanne, Olivier, 2007, “International Reserves in Emerging Market Countries: Too Much of a Good Thing?” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 1, Brookings Institution. Jeanne, Olivier, and Romain Rancière, 2006, “The Optimal Level of International Reserves for Emerging Market Countries: Formulas and Applications.” IMF Working Paper 06/229 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Koenker Roger, and Kevin F. Hallock, 2001, “Quantile Regression.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15, pp. 143–56. Koenker, Roger, and Gilbert Bassett Jr., 1978, “Regression Quantiles.” Econometrica, 46, pp. 33–50. Obstfeld, Maurice, Jay Shambaugh, and Alan M. Taylor, 2010, “Financial Stability, the Trilemma, and International Reserves.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, Vol. 2, pp. 57–94. 19 Figure 1. Reserves to GDP RIM, non-RIM, full sample (Various periods)1 35 30 25 20 Full sample 15 RIM non-RIM 10 5 0 1980-2010 1 RIM 1980-1997 1998-2004 2005-2010 countries are China, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam. 20 Figure 2a. Proxies for precautionary and mercantilist motives (RIM VS. non-RIM, 1980-2010)1 110 Figure 2b. Proxies for precautionary and mercantilist motives (RIM VS. non-RIM, 1980-1997)1 RIM non-RIM 90 110 non-RIM 90 70 70 50 50 30 30 10 10 -10 -10 -30 RIM -30 Imports/GDP M2/GDP ST Debt/GDP Misalignment Imports/GDP 1 RIM countries are China, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam. Misalignment Figure 2d. Proxies for precautionary and mercantilist motives (RIM VS. non-RIM, 2005-2010)1 RIM non-RIM 90 ST Debt/GDP countries are China, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam. Figure 2c. Proxies for precautionary and mercantilist motives (RIM VS. non-RIM, 1998-2004)1 110 M2/GDP 1 RIM 110 RIM non-RIM 90 70 70 50 50 30 30 10 10 -10 -10 -30 -30 Imports/GDP 1 RIM M2/GDP ST Debt/GDP Misalignment countries are China, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam. Imports/GDP 1 RIM M2/GDP ST Debt/GDP Misalignment countries are China, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam. 21 120 Figure 3: Reserves Distribution, various samples and periods 0 20 40 60 80 100 Reserves distribution 1980-2010 (full, RIM, and non-RIM samples) 120 Full sample non-RIM sample RIM sample 0 20 40 60 80 100 Reserves distribution by periods (full, RIM, and non-RIM samples) 1980-1997 1998-2004 Full sample non-RIM sample 2005-2010 RIM sample 22 Figure 4. 2007 Actual vs. Predicted Reserves (no differentiation RIM/non-RIM)1 60% MYS LBN 50% CHN JOR BGR 40% Actual 2007 RUS MAR 30% THA VNM BIH PER IND 20% KOR UKR PHL ROM TUN ARM HRV EGY LVALTU HUN URY ARG CRI KAZ JAM POL GEOIDN BRA GTM TURVEN ZAF SLV PAK COL PAN CHL MEX DOMECU 10% 0% 0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% Fitted 2007 1 RIM countries in reserves. red. Triangle RIM countries' actual reserves are above 2 standard deviations of the predicted 60% 23 Figure 5. 2007 Actual vs. Predicted Reserves1 60% MYS LBN 50% CHN JOR BGR 40% Actual 2007 RUS THA VNM MAR 30% BIH PER IND 20% KOR UKR ROM PHL TUN ARM HRV EGY LTU LVA HUN URY ARG CRI KAZ JAM POL GEO BRA IDNGTM TURVEN ZAF SLV CHL PAK COL PAN MEX DOMECU 10% 0% 0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% Fitted 2007 1 RIM countries in reserves. red. Triangle RIM countries' actual reserves are above 2 standard deviations of the predicted 60% 24 Figure 6a. Cumulative differences decomposition 1990-2010 (RIM sample - specification without dummy or interactions) 1.1 1.0 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 -0.1 -0.2 1990 1992 1994 Capital account 1996 1998 Current account 2000 2002 Mercantilist 2004 Residual 2006 2008 2010 Reserves-scale Figure 6b. Cumulative differences decomposition 1990-2010 (RIM sample - specification with RIM dummy only) 1.1 1.0 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 -0.1 -0.2 1990 1992 1994 Capital account 1996 1998 Current account 2000 2002 Mercantilist 2004 Residual 2006 2008 Reserves-scale 2010 25 Figure 6c. Cumulative differences decomposition 1990-2010 (RIM sample - specification with both dummy and interactions) 1.1 1.0 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 -0.1 -0.2 1990 1992 1994 Capital account 1996 1998 Current account 2000 2002 Mercantilist 2004 Residual 2006 2008 2010 Reserves-scale Figure 7. Cumulative differences decomposition 1990-2010 (Non-RIM sample specification with RIM dummy only) 1.1 1.0 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 -0.1 -0.2 1990 1992 1994 Capital account 1996 1998 Current account 2000 2002 Mercantilist 2004 Residual 2006 2008 Reserves-scale 2010 26 Table 1. Current Account, Capital Account and Mercantilist Determinants of Reserve Demand (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) RIM Sample Scale Log(per capita income) Log(population) scale scale scale regime scale regime opp. cost regime opp. cost +CA 0.579*** 0.579*** (0.088) (0.090) -0.073 -0.061 (0.071) (0.067) Regime Hard and Soft peg dummy Volatility of neer 0.591*** (0.091) -0.048 (0.064) +KA full 0.575*** 0.383*** (0.089) (0.081) -0.055 0.142** (0.063) (0.061) 80-97 0.438*** (0.139) 0.026 (0.088) 98-04 05-10 full 0.117 (0.093) 0.093 (0.076) 0.054 (0.092) 0.045 (0.070) 0.385*** (0.077) 0.135** (0.055) 80-97 98-04 05-10 full baseline 0.417*** (0.146) 0.086 (0.076) 0.113 (0.093) 0.104 (0.076) 0.047 0.378*** (0.095) (0.081) -0.001 0.148*** (0.070) (0.052) 0.033 (0.121) -0.007 (0.005) 0.016 (0.143) -0.017*** (0.005) 0.056 (0.118) -0.008* (0.005) 0.308 0.057 (0.184) (0.120) -0.001 -0.019*** (0.006) (0.005) -0.110 (0.100) -0.005 (0.006) 0.041 (0.119) -0.008* (0.005) 0.306* 0.065 (0.175) (0.137) -0.002 -0.019*** (0.006) (0.005) -0.124 (0.095) -0.005 (0.006) 0.057 (0.119) -0.008* (0.005) -0.390*** (0.061) -0.065 (0.071) -0.039 (0.082) -0.393*** (0.069) -0.025 (0.080) -0.017 (0.095) -0.068 (0.843) -0.342 (0.933) -0.013 (0.079) 0.039 (0.102) -0.079 (0.860) -0.110 (0.948) -0.021 (0.078) 0.770*** 0.648*** (0.150) (0.134) 0.170** 0.239** (0.078) (0.093) 0.311** 0.319** (0.141) (0.128) 0.677*** (0.133) 0.212*** (0.058) 0.233* (0.119) 0.532*** (0.153) 0.197** (0.079) 0.395** (0.192) 0.457** (0.169) 1.385 (1.070) 0.206 (0.255) 0.509*** (0.149) 0.459 (1.989) 0.269 (0.579) 0.691*** (0.121) 0.215*** (0.058) 0.215* (0.119) 0.690*** (0.149) 0.182** (0.072) 0.292* (0.156) 0.476*** (0.134) 1.371 (1.093) 0.231 (0.261) 0.426*** 0.690*** (0.138) (0.121) 0.386 0.215*** (1.898) (0.058) 0.163 0.231* (0.580) (0.118) 0.100** (0.048) 0.278*** (0.100) 0.227 (0.212) 0.113** (0.049) 0.258*** (0.093) 0.274 (0.203) 0.060 (0.071) 0.195* (0.104) -1.068 (0.693) 0.123** (0.056) 0.263** (0.118) 0.509** (0.242) -0.023 (0.046) 0.426*** (0.143) 0.361** (0.171) 0.113** (0.046) 0.243** (0.094) 0.285 (0.203) 0.114* (0.059) 0.158 (0.108) -0.275 (0.622) 0.125** (0.057) 0.274** (0.109) 0.497** (0.227) -0.030 0.115** (0.047) (0.046) 0.391** 0.261*** (0.147) (0.092) 0.402** 0.276 (0.177) (0.199) 0.074 (0.109) 0.453* (0.224) 0.324*** (0.081) 0.050 (0.164) 0.358*** (0.101) -0.194 (0.174) 0.240*** (0.065) 0.054 (0.110) 0.333*** (0.081) 0.303*** 0.252*** (0.090) (0.065) 0.091 (0.142) 0.191** 0.249*** (0.089) (0.066) 0.746*** 0.041 (0.157) (0.135) Volatility of exports/GDP (3-yr sd) Volatility of partner growth (3-yr sd) Capital account Financial openness Log(broad money to GDP) Short term debt to GDP Mercantilist Exchange rate undervaluation 0.864*** 0.825*** (0.180) (0.163) 0.769*** (0.157) 0.273 (0.166) China dummy Observations R-squared R-squared adjusted Tests for groups' joined significance p-value Scale p-value Regime p-value CA p-value KA (15) 0.074 (0.133) -0.011** (0.005) Current account Log(imports to GDP) Constant (14) -0.025 0.003 (0.144) (0.142) -0.021*** -0.016*** (0.005) (0.005) Opportunity cost Interest rate differential w/ US RIM countries dummy (13) China scale regime opp. cost +mercantilist 0.515*** 0.409*** (0.087) (0.087) 0.135** 0.138** (0.062) (0.063) (12) -2.453*** -2.441*** -2.430*** -2.449*** -2.554*** (0.133) (0.131) (0.130) (0.106) (0.100) -2.422*** -2.553*** -2.608*** -2.361*** -2.096*** (0.128) (0.096) (0.120) (0.149) (0.170) 0.357** 0.700*** -0.112 0.433** (0.162) (0.223) (0.229) (0.200) -2.540*** -2.567*** -2.367*** -2.038*** -2.554*** (0.099) (0.127) (0.149) (0.171) (0.096) 1,009 0.31 0.31 1,009 0.35 0.35 1,009 0.38 0.37 1,009 0.50 0.49 1,009 0.55 0.54 1,009 0.39 0.38 1,009 0.57 0.56 449 0.45 0.43 296 0.53 0.50 264 0.53 0.51 1,009 0.57 0.56 449 0.44 0.43 296 0.53 0.50 264 0.53 0.51 1,009 0.57 0.56 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.23 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.09 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.13 0.00 0.05 0.36 0.00 0.02 0.00 0.79 0.44 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.10 0.00 0.00 0.02 0.11 0.00 0.12 0.32 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.84 0.33 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.09 0.00 0.00 Notes: 1. Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses (*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.10). 2. RIM countries are China, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam. 27 Table 2. Principal Components Analysis: Current Account, Capital Account and Mercantilist Determinants of Reserve Demand (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) scale regime opp. cost +mercantilist full 80-97 98-04 05-10 full RIM Sample Scale Regime Opportunity cost scale scale regime scale scale regime regime opp. cost opp. cost +CA -0.560*** -0.549*** -0.534*** (0.113) (0.111) (0.105) -0.157** -0.124* (0.070) (0.069) -0.359*** (0.095) Current account -0.319** (0.122) -0.088 (0.067) -0.112 (0.090) 0.304*** (0.083) Capital account -0.181 (0.114) -0.093 (0.060) -0.085 (0.089) 0.252*** (0.086) 0.237*** (0.050) Undervaluation RIM dummy 0.927*** (0.175) 0.893*** (0.181) 0.842*** (0.175) 0.557*** (0.198) 0.385** (0.173) -0.535*** (0.104) -0.124* (0.068) -0.377*** (0.109) 0.227** (0.092) 0.812*** (0.172) -0.147 -0.321** -0.006 0.177* (0.106) (0.132) (0.101) (0.090) -0.088 0.026 -0.029 -0.019 (0.058) (0.078) (0.062) (0.057) -0.079 -0.075 -1.169 -0.266 (0.093) (0.092) (0.975) (1.018) 0.287*** 0.162 0.205** 0.322*** (0.083) (0.111) (0.099) (0.077) 0.251*** 0.235 0.242*** 0.179*** (0.050) (0.156) (0.047) (0.032) 0.342*** 0.119 0.312*** 0.337*** (0.084) (0.106) (0.081) (0.124) 0.293* 0.453* 0.290* 0.103 (0.159) (0.250) (0.155) (0.208) China dummy Constant Observations R-squared -2.226*** -2.236*** -2.208*** -2.187*** -2.344*** (0.092) (0.094) (0.094) (0.089) (0.093) 1,009 0.250 1,009 0.277 1,009 0.301 1,009 0.353 1,009 0.413 -2.216*** -2.363*** -2.593*** -2.297*** -2.011*** (0.093) (0.092) (0.129) (0.105) (0.073) 1,009 0.315 Notes: 1. Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses (*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.10). 2. RIM countries are China, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam. 1,009 0.444 449 0.320 296 0.457 264 0.394 (12) (13) China 80-97 98-04 (14) 05-10 -0.120 -0.267** 0.058 0.141 (0.089) (0.123) (0.090) (0.085) -0.097* 0.030 -0.036 -0.055 (0.058) (0.078) (0.067) (0.057) -0.036 -0.023 -1.090 0.229 (0.093) (0.094) (1.028) (1.007) 0.339*** 0.230* 0.263*** 0.349*** (0.079) (0.114) (0.090) (0.067) 0.258*** 0.335** 0.255*** 0.168*** (0.054) (0.142) (0.053) (0.033) 0.340*** 0.068 0.361*** 0.337*** (0.080) (0.100) (0.076) (0.111) 0.777*** 0.920*** 0.240 0.708*** (0.139) (0.203) (0.206) (0.204) -2.342*** -2.552*** -2.296*** -2.003*** (0.096) (0.134) (0.107) (0.073) 1,009 0.451 449 0.327 296 0.445 264 0.416 28 Table 3. Adding Interactions: Determinants of Reserve Demand (1) Sample Scale Log(per capita income) Log(population) scale (2) (4) scale scale regime scale regime opp. cost regime opp. cost +CA 0.579*** 0.579*** (0.088) (0.090) -0.073 -0.060 (0.071) (0.067) Regime Hard and Soft peg dummy Volatility of neer (3) 0.585*** (0.091) -0.047 (0.063) (5) +KA 0.514*** 0.403*** (0.088) (0.096) 0.132** 0.137** (0.063) (0.066) full 80-97 98-04 05-10 0.569*** 0.383*** (0.090) (0.089) -0.056 0.142** (0.064) (0.066) 0.414** (0.154) 0.041 (0.099) 0.118 (0.115) 0.097 (0.083) 0.046 (0.112) 0.033 (0.071) 0.052 (0.136) -0.008 (0.005) 0.368* 0.073 (0.200) (0.150) -0.001 -0.021*** (0.007) (0.006) -0.180 (0.117) -0.005 (0.006) -0.389*** (0.061) -0.046 (0.080) -0.031 (0.089) -0.390*** (0.068) -0.018 (0.088) 0.010 (0.097) -0.085 (0.930) 0.136 (1.031) 0.790*** 0.649*** (0.165) (0.147) 0.150** 0.210** (0.065) (0.087) 0.262* 0.292** (0.154) (0.130) 0.675*** (0.146) 0.190*** (0.064) 0.216* (0.125) 0.581*** (0.161) 0.165* (0.085) 0.355* (0.203) 0.448** (0.190) 0.414 (1.607) 0.322 (0.281) 0.529*** (0.154) 0.441 (2.594) 0.441 (0.681) 0.113** (0.056) 0.256** (0.124) 0.275 (0.241) 0.124** (0.057) 0.240** (0.116) 0.319 (0.226) 0.092 (0.092) 0.120 (0.131) -0.894 (0.789) 0.122* (0.062) 0.256* (0.136) 0.514* (0.287) -0.013 (0.052) 0.412** (0.173) 0.386* (0.217) 0.173* 0.256*** (0.101) (0.083) 0.092 (0.130) 0.371*** (0.087) 0.385*** (0.123) Capital account Financial openness Log(broad money to GDP) Short term debt to GDP Mercantilist Exchange rate undervaluation -0.067 (0.246) 0.003 (0.011) Opportunity cost interaction Interest rate differential w/ US x RIM -0.116 (0.230) 0.002 (0.010) -0.043 (0.177) -0.003 (0.008) -0.050 (0.168) -0.002 (0.006) -0.023 (0.243) 0.004 (0.010) 0.001 (0.168) 0.001 (0.006) -0.390* (0.225) -0.008 (0.009) 0.093 (0.227) 0.019** (0.008) 0.068 (0.163) -0.016* (0.008) -1.315 (1.404) -1.775 (1.138) -1.217* (0.675) -1.189 (1.363) -1.265* (0.672) -1.627** (0.667) -0.528 (1.194) -1.754 (1.665) -0.193 (0.168) 3.377* (1.961) 0.403 (0.293) -0.011 (0.147) 2.782* (1.426) 0.225 (0.268) 0.028 (0.138) 2.162 (1.309) 0.247 (0.239) -0.216 (0.203) 0.986 (1.403) 0.569 (0.571) 0.076 (0.191) -0.663 (1.878) -0.460 (0.319) -0.263 (0.163) 0.310 (3.080) -1.354 (1.118) -0.095* (0.053) -0.032 (0.187) -1.119 (0.861) -0.094* (0.053) -0.033 (0.170) -1.104 (0.812) -0.054 (0.096) 0.262 (0.184) 0.076 (1.332) 0.067 (0.076) 0.065 (0.299) 0.777 (0.610) -0.113 (0.070) 0.111 (0.248) -1.388 (0.904) Current account interaction Log(imports to GDP) x RIM Volatility of exports/GDP (3-yr sd) x RIM Volatility of partner growth (3-yr sd) x RIM Capital account interaction Financial openness x RIM Log(broad money to GDP) x RIM Short term debt to GDP x RIM Mercantilist interaction Exchange rate undervaluation x RIM 0.864*** 0.819*** 0.844*** 0.050 0.226 (0.180) (0.242) (0.238) (0.253) (0.271) -2.453*** -2.440*** -2.430*** -2.440*** -2.552*** (0.133) (0.132) (0.130) (0.107) (0.104) Observations 1,009 R-squared 0.31 R-squared adjusted 0.31 Tests for groups' joined significance Scale variables p-value 0.00 Regime variables p-value Regime variables interaction p-value Current account variables p-value Current account variables interaction p-value Capital account p-value Capital account interaction p-value All RIM terms p-value 0.00 (10) 0.021 (0.164) -0.017*** (0.005) Volatility of partner growth (3-yr sd) Constant (9) 0.039 (0.138) -0.006 (0.005) Volatility of exports/GDP (3-yr sd) RIM countries dummy (8) 0.070 (0.151) -0.011* (0.006) Current account Log(imports to GDP) Volatility of neer x RIM (7) -0.012 0.022 (0.164) (0.163) -0.022*** -0.016*** (0.006) (0.005) Opportunity cost Interest rate differential w/ US Regime interaction Hard and Soft peg dummy x RIM (6) scale regime opp. cost +mercantilist 0.089 -0.087 -0.293* -0.263** 0.018 (0.192) (0.118) (0.169) (0.110) (0.201) 0.706** 0.191 0.738* 0.042 0.045 (0.288) (0.249) (0.395) (0.341) (0.232) -2.417*** -2.557*** -2.588*** -2.368*** -2.081*** (0.131) (0.102) (0.132) (0.158) (0.190) 1,009 0.35 0.35 1,009 0.379 0.373 1,009 0.502 0.494 1,009 0.556 0.546 1,009 0.388 0.382 1,009 0.570 0.560 449 0.461 0.431 296 0.535 0.495 264 0.554 0.512 0.00 0.00 0.91 0.00 0.01 0.84 0.00 0.05 0.94 0.00 0.14 0.00 0.00 0.88 0.00 0.00 0.37 0.00 0.38 0.92 0.00 0.24 0.00 0.10 0.00 0.00 0.19 0.98 0.00 0.36 0.00 0.08 0.00 0.03 0.13 0.24 0.00 0.34 0.33 0.36 0.00 0.38 0.00 0.04 0.10 0.45 0.00 0.15 0.00 0.88 0.28 0.10 0.01 0.35 0.00 0.05 0.00 Notes: 1. Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses (*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.10). 2. RIM countries are China, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam. 0.00 29 Table 4. Principal Components Analysis and Interactions: Determinants of Reserve Demand Sample Scale Regime Regime x RIM Opportunity cost Opportunity cost x RIM (1) (2) scale scale regime (3) (4) scale scale regime regime opp. cost opp. cost +CA -0.560*** -0.551*** -0.531*** (0.113) (0.110) (0.104) -0.160** -0.122* (0.070) (0.069) 0.020 0.002 (0.037) (0.030) -0.355*** (0.092) -2.087 (1.824) Current account Current account x RIM -0.307** (0.120) -0.081 (0.067) 0.005 (0.021) -0.127 (0.090) -1.929 (1.970) 0.289*** (0.086) 0.090 (0.097) Capital account Capital account x RIM (5) +KA -0.161 (0.110) -0.073 (0.059) -0.001 (0.018) -0.110 (0.090) -0.386 (0.989) 0.226** (0.089) 0.103* (0.056) 0.253*** (0.050) -0.090*** (0.021) Undervaluation Undervaluation x RIM RIM Constant Observations R-squared 0.927*** 0.902*** 0.907*** 0.785*** 0.906*** (0.175) (0.181) (0.180) (0.186) (0.192) -2.226*** -2.236*** -2.209*** -2.194*** -2.370*** (0.092) (0.094) (0.094) (0.090) (0.093) 1,009 0.250 1,009 0.278 1,009 0.303 1,009 0.357 1,009 0.446 (6) scale regime opp. cost +mercantilist -0.533*** (0.103) -0.116 (0.069) 0.028 (0.025) -0.371*** (0.103) -1.403 (1.624) 0.166 (0.103) 0.354* (0.199) 0.726*** (0.155) -2.207*** (0.093) 1,009 0.323 Notes: 1. Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses (*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.10). 2. RIM countries are China, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam. (7) (8) (9) (10) full 80-97 98-04 05-10 -0.135 -0.318** -0.010 0.171* (0.103) (0.132) (0.108) (0.085) -0.071 0.045 -0.036 -0.069 (0.059) (0.080) (0.064) (0.055) 0.018 0.015 0.039* -0.004 (0.013) (0.010) (0.023) (0.024) -0.102 -0.087 -1.153 0.829 (0.094) (0.089) (1.056) (1.007) -0.374 -0.797 1.553 -4.258** (0.822) (0.726) (1.413) (1.741) 0.257*** 0.147 0.191* 0.315*** (0.087) (0.112) (0.107) (0.072) 0.101* 0.116 0.060 -0.033 (0.054) (0.087) (0.044) (0.063) 0.262*** 0.235 0.247*** 0.190*** (0.051) (0.162) (0.048) (0.026) -0.073*** -0.081*** -0.015 -0.119*** (0.019) (0.027) (0.022) (0.015) 0.284*** 0.106 0.328*** 0.383*** (0.098) (0.114) (0.090) (0.138) 0.107 -0.169 -0.084 0.026 (0.132) (0.216) (0.118) (0.195) 0.726*** 1.207*** 0.473** 0.309 (0.183) (0.324) (0.203) (0.199) -2.380*** -2.615*** -2.307*** -2.036*** (0.092) (0.131) (0.108) (0.073) 1,009 0.470 449 0.349 296 0.463 264 0.465 30 Table 5. Reserve Demand Across Quantiles Percentile Scale Log(per capita income) Log(population) Regime Hard and Soft peg dummy Volatility of neer Opportunity cost Interest rate differential w/ US Current account Log(imports to GDP) Volatility of exports/GDP (3-yr sd) Volatility of partner growth (3-yr sd) Capital account Financial openness Log(broad money to GDP) Short term debt to GDP Mercantilist Exchange rate undervaluation RIM countries dummy Constant Quantile regression estimated coefficients (1) (2) (3) (4) 25 50 75 90 1 Inter-quantile regression results (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) 25 vs. 50 25 vs. 75 25 vs. 90 50 vs. 75 50 vs. 90 75 vs. 90 0.324*** (0.052) 0.161*** (0.036) 0.377*** (0.033) 0.151*** (0.023) 0.298*** (0.034) 0.128*** (0.019) 0.257*** (0.048) 0.092*** (0.032) 0.052 (0.047) -0.009 (0.032) -0.026 (0.053) -0.032 (0.034) -0.068 (0.063) -0.069 (0.044) -0.079** (0.034) -0.023 (0.020) -0.120** (0.047) -0.060* (0.033) -0.041 (0.037) -0.036 (0.029) 0.083 (0.069) -0.011* (0.006) 0.020 (0.045) -0.004 (0.003) 0.028 (0.039) -0.001 (0.002) 0.004 (0.061) -0.003 (0.004) -0.063 (0.058) 0.007 (0.005) -0.055 (0.068) 0.010* (0.005) -0.079 (0.082) 0.008 (0.006) 0.008 (0.041) 0.002 (0.003) -0.017 (0.062) 0.000 (0.004) -0.024 (0.050) -0.002 (0.003) 0.052 (0.061) -0.131 (0.086) -0.098 (0.060) -0.152** (0.061) -0.183** (0.080) -0.151** (0.074) -0.204** (0.081) 0.032 (0.078) -0.021 (0.091) -0.053 (0.058) 0.804*** (0.087) 0.364 (1.033) 0.272* (0.155) 0.647*** (0.063) 0.190 (0.506) 0.195* (0.105) 0.634*** (0.050) 0.067 (0.582) 0.134 (0.123) 0.481*** (0.081) -0.091 (0.781) 0.120 (0.189) -0.157** (0.078) -0.175 (0.864) -0.077 (0.149) -0.170** -0.323*** (0.084) (0.108) -0.298 -0.455 (1.143) (1.256) -0.138 -0.152 (0.175) (0.227) -0.013 (0.057) -0.123 (0.488) -0.061 (0.118) -0.166* (0.087) -0.281 (0.811) -0.076 (0.200) -0.153** (0.073) -0.158 (0.711) -0.015 (0.175) 0.139*** (0.024) 0.306*** (0.065) 0.541*** (0.136) 0.082*** (0.016) 0.303*** (0.046) 0.359*** (0.083) 0.061*** (0.016) 0.349*** (0.038) 0.115* (0.067) 0.052** (0.022) 0.329*** (0.058) 0.034 (0.094) -0.057*** -0.078*** -0.087*** -0.021 -0.030 (0.021) (0.025) (0.030) (0.015) (0.023) -0.003 0.043 0.023 0.046 0.026 (0.059) (0.063) (0.076) (0.039) (0.059) -0.181 -0.425*** -0.507*** -0.244*** -0.326*** (0.126) (0.140) (0.146) (0.076) (0.105) -0.009 (0.019) -0.020 (0.048) -0.081 (0.081) 0.337*** 0.213*** 0.240*** 0.179*** (0.070) (0.052) (0.037) (0.053) 0.077 -0.022 -0.273*** -0.277*** (0.105) (0.064) (0.050) (0.086) -2.948*** -2.503*** -2.113*** -1.803*** (0.057) (0.033) (0.035) (0.042) -0.125** -0.097 -0.158* 0.027 -0.033 (0.062) (0.066) (0.083) (0.042) (0.062) -0.099 -0.350*** -0.354*** -0.251*** -0.255*** (0.091) (0.103) (0.130) (0.058) (0.096) 0.444*** 0.834*** 1.144*** 0.390*** 0.700*** (0.049) (0.056) (0.063) (0.033) (0.044) -0.061 (0.049) -0.005 (0.082) 0.310*** (0.036) Observations 1,009 1,009 1,009 1,009 1,009 1,009 1,009 1,009 1,009 1,009 Pseudo R2 0.37 0.37 0.37 0.38 Tests for groups' joined significance Scale variables p-value 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.47 0.61 0.21 0.05 0.02 0.30 Regime variables p-value 0.05 0.33 0.53 0.62 0.13 0.11 0.22 0.71 0.96 0.78 Current account variables p-value 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.16 0.09 0.01 0.90 0.18 0.18 Capital account p-value 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.42 Notes: 1. Quantile regression estimates for 1980-2010. Standard errors obtained using bootstrapping with 1000 replications (*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.10). 2. RIM countries are China, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam. 31 Table 6. Principal Component Analysis: Reserve Demand Across Quantiles 1 Percentile Scale Regime Opportunity cost Current account Capital account Undervaluation RIM countries dummy Constant Observations Pseudo R2 Quantile regression estimated coefficients (1) (2) (3) (4) 25 50 75 90 (5) 25 vs. 50 Inter-quantile regression results (6) (7) (8) (9) 25 vs. 75 25 vs. 90 50 vs. 75 50 vs. 90 (10) 75 vs. 90 -0.230*** (0.060) -0.129*** (0.040) -0.032 (0.070) 0.345*** (0.055) 0.227*** (0.029) 0.344*** (0.064) 0.506*** (0.092) -2.725*** (0.042) -0.152*** (0.055) -0.095*** (0.031) -0.157** (0.079) 0.280*** (0.044) 0.202*** (0.024) 0.350*** (0.054) 0.283*** (0.082) -2.300*** (0.036) -0.057 (0.047) -0.032 (0.027) -0.195* (0.105) 0.317*** (0.029) 0.193*** (0.021) 0.332*** (0.050) 0.062 (0.067) -1.866*** (0.030) 0.028 (0.047) -0.048 (0.033) -0.122 (0.095) 0.332*** (0.036) 0.164*** (0.029) 0.350*** (0.053) -0.024 (0.060) -1.583*** (0.041) 0.078 (0.057) 0.034 (0.034) -0.125* (0.073) -0.065 (0.050) -0.024 (0.025) 0.006 (0.057) -0.223** (0.088) 0.426*** (0.038) 0.173*** (0.064) 0.097** (0.041) -0.163 (0.108) -0.028 (0.055) -0.034 (0.031) -0.012 (0.069) -0.444*** (0.093) 0.860*** (0.044) 0.258*** (0.068) 0.081* (0.047) -0.090 (0.105) -0.013 (0.061) -0.063 (0.039) 0.006 (0.073) -0.530*** (0.102) 1.142*** (0.055) 0.095** (0.046) 0.063** (0.028) -0.038 (0.090) 0.037 (0.038) -0.009 (0.024) -0.018 (0.050) -0.221*** (0.071) 0.434*** (0.032) 0.180*** (0.061) 0.047 (0.038) 0.035 (0.096) 0.052 (0.051) -0.038 (0.035) -0.000 (0.064) -0.307*** (0.090) 0.717*** (0.045) 0.085* (0.046) -0.017 (0.030) 0.073 (0.090) 0.015 (0.034) -0.029 (0.029) 0.018 (0.050) -0.086 (0.067) 0.283*** (0.037) 1,009 0.295 1,009 0.276 1,009 0.267 1,009 0.271 1,009 1,009 1,009 1,009 1,009 1,009 Notes: 1. Quantile regression estimates for 1980-2010. Standard errors obtained using bootstrapping with 1000 replications (*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.10). 2. RIM countries are China, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam. 32 Table 7. Principal Components Analysis and Interactions: Reserve Demand Across Quantiles 1 Quantile regression estimated coefficients Percentile Scale Regime Regime x RIM Opportunity cost Opportunity cost x RIM Current account Current account x RIM Capital account Capital account x RIM Undervaluation Undervaluation x RIM RIM countries dummy Constant Observations Pseudo R2 Inter-quantile regression results (1) 25 sqreg25 (2) 50 sqreg50 (3) 75 sqreg75 (4) 90 sqreg90 (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) 25 vs. 50 25 vs. 75 25 vs. 90 50 vs. 75 50 vs. 90 75 vs. 90 iqreg2550 iqreg2575 iqreg2590 iqreg5075 iqreg5090 iqreg7590 -0.177*** (0.057) -0.103** (0.044) 0.036** (0.018) -0.053 (0.073) -1.191 (1.513) 0.281*** (0.064) 0.065 (0.057) 0.259*** (0.032) -0.056*** (0.018) 0.277*** (0.090) 0.133 (0.133) 0.869*** (0.132) -2.776*** (0.044) -0.093 (0.062) -0.090*** (0.031) 0.008 (0.011) -0.167** (0.078) -0.518 (0.838) 0.275*** (0.044) 0.098*** (0.037) 0.231*** (0.025) -0.060*** (0.010) 0.309*** (0.070) 0.026 (0.115) 0.632*** (0.109) -2.320*** (0.036) -0.040 (0.057) -0.015 (0.027) 0.009 (0.011) -0.210** (0.101) 0.284 (0.614) 0.282*** (0.031) 0.107*** (0.030) 0.222*** (0.026) -0.073*** (0.011) 0.273*** (0.061) 0.119 (0.100) 0.389*** (0.093) -1.898*** (0.032) 0.069 (0.043) -0.008 (0.032) 0.014 (0.013) -0.123 (0.091) -0.165 (0.999) 0.291*** (0.041) 0.107*** (0.036) 0.182*** (0.041) -0.095*** (0.015) 0.268*** (0.075) 0.181 (0.120) 0.258*** (0.095) -1.612*** (0.047) 0.084 (0.057) 0.013 (0.037) -0.029* (0.016) -0.114 (0.077) 0.673 (1.268) -0.006 (0.055) 0.033 (0.052) -0.029 (0.026) -0.004 (0.016) 0.031 (0.079) -0.107 (0.120) -0.237* (0.124) 0.456*** (0.038) 0.137** (0.068) 0.088** (0.043) -0.027 (0.019) -0.157 (0.111) 1.475 (1.470) 0.001 (0.063) 0.042 (0.058) -0.038 (0.033) -0.017 (0.018) -0.004 (0.091) -0.014 (0.142) -0.480*** (0.138) 0.878*** (0.045) 0.247*** (0.065) 0.095* (0.050) -0.022 (0.021) -0.070 (0.106) 1.026 (1.671) 0.010 (0.070) 0.042 (0.065) -0.077 (0.048) -0.039* (0.022) -0.009 (0.106) 0.048 (0.161) -0.612*** (0.150) 1.164*** (0.058) 0.053 (0.055) 0.075*** (0.028) 0.002 (0.012) -0.043 (0.094) 0.802 (0.781) 0.007 (0.036) 0.009 (0.033) -0.009 (0.027) -0.013 (0.011) -0.035 (0.061) 0.093 (0.101) -0.242** (0.095) 0.422*** (0.033) 0.163** (0.066) 0.082** (0.038) 0.006 (0.015) 0.044 (0.094) 0.353 (1.173) 0.016 (0.051) 0.009 (0.043) -0.048 (0.044) -0.035** (0.015) -0.041 (0.087) 0.155 (0.136) -0.374*** (0.121) 0.708*** (0.051) 0.110** (0.050) 0.007 (0.030) 0.005 (0.012) 0.087 (0.081) -0.449 (0.879) 0.009 (0.036) -0.000 (0.034) -0.039 (0.036) -0.022* (0.013) -0.005 (0.071) 0.062 (0.112) -0.132 (0.091) 0.286*** (0.040) 1,009 0.310 1,009 0.300 1,009 0.299 1,009 0.314 1,009 1,009 1,009 1,009 1,009 1,009 Notes: 1. Quantile regression estimates for 1980-2010. Standard errors obtained using bootstrapping with 1000 replications (*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.10). 2. RIM countries are China, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam. 33 APPENDIX A: DATA AND SUMMARY STATISTICS Table A1. Countries in the sample, and variable definitions and sources Countries in the sample Argentina, Armenia, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, China, Colombia, Costa Rica, Croatia, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Egypt, El Salvador, Georgia, Guatemala, Hungary, India Indonesia, Jamaica, Jordan, Kazakhstan, Korea, Latvia, Lebanon, Lithuania, Malaysia, Mexico, Morocco, Pakistan, Panama, Peru, Philippines, Poland, Romania, Russia, South Africa, Thailand, Tunisia, Turkey, Ukraine, Uruguay, Venezuela, Vietnam. RIM countries are China, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam. Variable definitions and sources Variable Description Source Log(reserves to GDP) Log(per capita income) Log(population) Log(imports to GDP) Volatility of neer Interest rate differential w/ US Natural log of ratio of foreign exchange reserves to USD GDP Natural log of per capita income (at PPP) Natural log of population Natural log of ratio of imports to GDP Twelve month standard deviation of end of period nominal effective exchange rate ln[(1 + i)/(1 + iUS)], where iUS is the US interest rate corresponding to the definition used for the national interest rate (deposit, money market, t-bill rate, lending) 3 year standard deviation of export to GDP (goods) Chinn-Ito index index measuring a country's degree of capital account openness Natural log of ratio of M2 to GDP Dummy variable equal to 1 if the currency pegged and zero otherwise Ratio of total short-term debt outstanding to GDP 3 year standard deviation of growth of trading partners' real GDP Dummy variable equal to 1 if the currency is undervalued and zero otherwise IMF, IMF, IMF, IMF, IMF, IMF, Volatility of exports/GDP (3-year sd) Financial openness Log(broad money to GDP) Peg dummy Short term debt to GDP Volatility of partner growth (3-year sd) Undervaluation dummy Variable IMF, World Economic Outlook and authors' calculations Chinn and Ito (2009) IMF, World Economic Outlook Ghosh, Qureshi, and Tsangarides (2011) IMF, World Economic Outlook IMF, World Economic Outlook and authors' calculations Authors' calculations Table A2. Summary Statistics in the RIM sample Mean Std. Dev. Min Log(reserves to GDP) Reserves to GDP Log(per capita income) Log(population) Log(imports to GDP) Volatility of neer Interest rate differential w/ US Volatility of exports/GDP (3-year sd) Financial openness Log(broad money to GDP) Peg dummy Short term debt to GDP Volatility of partner growth (3-year sd) Undervaluation dummy Variable World Economic Outlook World Economic Outlook World Economic Outlook World Economic Outlook International Financial Statistics and authors' calculations International Financial Statistics and authors' calculations -1.96 14% 8.07 18.41 -0.97 12.41 0.03 0.03 0.17 -0.35 0.54 0.13 0.11 0.42 0.79 220% 0.90 1.28 0.56 7.14 0.05 0.03 1.24 0.67 0.50 0.08 0.10 0.50 -3.91 2% 6.08 16.44 -2.45 2.41 -0.09 0.00 -1.84 -2.30 0.00 0.02 0.01 0.00 Table A3. Summary Statistics in the non-RIM sample Mean Std. Dev. Min Log(reserves to GDP) Reserves to GDP Log(per capita income) Log(population) Log(imports to GDP) Volatility of neer Interest rate differential w/ US Volatility of exports/GDP (3-year sd) Financial openness Log(broad money to GDP) Peg dummy Short term debt to GDP Volatility of partner growth (3-year sd) Undervaluation dummy -2.39 9% 8.59 16.72 -1.23 13.18 0.15 0.03 0.14 -0.92 0.60 0.14 0.14 0.29 0.88 240% 0.68 1.46 0.59 8.27 0.43 0.10 1.58 0.57 0.49 0.19 0.18 0.46 -5.42 0% 6.03 14.56 -3.07 0.81 -0.12 0.00 -1.84 -2.62 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Max -0.62 54% 10.30 21.02 0.01 45.45 0.28 0.17 2.48 0.66 1.00 0.45 0.66 1.00 Max 0.07 107% 9.88 20.92 -0.06 41.22 5.08 2.83 2.48 1.05 1.00 1.73 2.37 1.00