Download Great Depression and Great Recession - UvA-DARE

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

History of the Federal Reserve System wikipedia , lookup

Financial economics wikipedia , lookup

Systemic risk wikipedia , lookup

Interest rate ceiling wikipedia , lookup

United States housing bubble wikipedia , lookup

Global financial system wikipedia , lookup

Bank wikipedia , lookup

Shadow banking system wikipedia , lookup

Financial crisis wikipedia , lookup

Financialization wikipedia , lookup

Interbank lending market wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Great Depression and Great Recession
A comparison between an old and a modern global systemic risk
Abstract
Several studies find evidence that the economic downturn after a financial crisis tends to be more
severe than a normal ending business cycle. Financial stability therefore is crucial for a stable
economy. The speculative bubble and the financial collapse at the roots of the Great Depression
changed the vision in the United States about the desired role of federal authorities in the life of
citizens. Next to poverty relief programs, a far reaching framework for banking regulation and
supervision was developed and implemented ever since. Also in the 1930s, the foundations were laid
for macroeconomic theory to guide policymakers to achieve full employment. For over 70 years, no
banking panic occurred in the United States significantly contributing to a more stable economic
environment. For the first time since, the recent financial panics and the credit crunch brought back
into life the danger of an international systemic risk with potential dramatic consequences for the real
economy. To avoid a new depression, policymakers immediately intervened to safeguard the financial
system but the rules of the game have changed. For the stabilization policies to be sustainable, lessons
from the 1930s in combination with more recent insights must reshape an adequate theoretical and
regulatory framework.
Angela Maria Caboni
0111880
March, 11, 2010
Master Thesis
Supervisor: Dr. M. Giuliodori
Second Reviewer: Prof. Dr. C. Van Ewijk
Universiteit van Amsterdam
1
Acknowledgments
This thesis was my way to combine my never ending passion for history with all that I learned during
my years of study. Besides the fear and uncertainty for the future, the recent financial crisis had the
small benefit of renewing my interest for the economic science. It made me realize this highly
theoretical study may still be helpful to understand the world we live in and that we are certainly not at
a dead end as was thought just before or during the crisis. I must admit it was not easy for me to distill
a valid ‘crisis’ comparison from the enormous quantity of historic elements, which of course caught
my eye much more than the economic aspects did. Therefore I thank my supervisor, prof. Giuliodori,
who gave me the possibility to write about this topic in the first place, and who helped me find the
right path in the labyrinth of the Great Depression. I also would like to express my gratitude to my
family, in particular my parents and my sister, for their loving support during all these years. They
always believed in me through all the ups and downs, giving me the strength to keep on going and
believe in myself. Last but not least, a special thanks to all my most dear friends for the
encouragement, the good advice, the times together at the library, at work, the many laughs and so
much more. To all, you shallowed every recession during this ‘Depressing’ thesis and make my fears
for the future disappear as long as we have each other, our love and our friendship.
2
3
Table of Contents
1. INTRODUCTION............................................................................................................................................. 5 2. THE DAWN OF THE GREAT DEPRESSION ............................................................................................. 7 2.1 HISTORICAL BACKGROUND ........................................................................................................................... 7 2.2 INSTITUTIONAL FRAMEWORK........................................................................................................................ 9 2.2.1 Central Bank......................................................................................................................................... 9 2.2.2 Gold Exchange Standard.................................................................................................................... 10 2.3 MACROECONOMIC BACKGROUND ............................................................................................................... 11 2.3.1 Stabilization of the Currencies ........................................................................................................... 11 2.3.2 Economic and Credit Boom................................................................................................................ 12 2.3.3 Structural Changes and the Agricultural Depression ........................................................................ 14 2.3.4 Global Imbalances.............................................................................................................................. 16 2.4 FINANCIAL CRISIS IN THE UNITED STATES .................................................................................................. 16 2.4.1 Initiation of Financial Crisis .............................................................................................................. 17 2.4.2 Banking Crisis .................................................................................................................................... 18 2.4.3 Debt Deflation .................................................................................................................................... 20 2.5 REPERCUSSIONS ON EUROPE ....................................................................................................................... 20 2.6 RECOVERY .................................................................................................................................................. 21 3. FINANCIAL CRISES 2007 AND 2008 ......................................................................................................... 23 3.1 HISTORICAL BACKGROUND ......................................................................................................................... 23 3.2 INSTITUTIONAL FRAMEWORK ...................................................................................................................... 24 3.2.1 Independent Central Banks................................................................................................................. 25 3.2.2 Banking Regulation and Supervision.................................................................................................. 25 3.2.3 Basel Capital Accord.......................................................................................................................... 26 3.3 MACROECONOMIC BACKGROUND ............................................................................................................... 28 3.3.1 Great Moderation ............................................................................................................................... 28 3.3.2 Loose Monetary Policy....................................................................................................................... 29 3.3.3 Global Imbalances.............................................................................................................................. 30 3.4 CREDIT BOOM ............................................................................................................................................. 31 3.4.1 Securitization of Debts........................................................................................................................ 31 3.4.2 Rising Complexity of Derivatives ....................................................................................................... 34 3.4.3 Subprime Deals .................................................................................................................................. 35 3.4.4 Subprime Bubble ................................................................................................................................ 36 3.5 FINANCIAL CRISES 2007-2008 .................................................................................................................... 37 3.5.1 Financial Panic 2007 ‘Subprime Crisis’ ............................................................................................ 37 3.5.2 Financial Panic of 2008 ‘The Perfect Storm’..................................................................................... 41 3.6 RECOVERY .................................................................................................................................................. 44 4. CONCLUSION................................................................................................................................................ 46 5. REFERENCES................................................................................................................................................ 49 4
1. Introduction
The dramatic decade of economic depression that hit the United States in the 1930s, put an end to the
laissez-faire mentality that ruled the banking and business life of the country at that time. The severe
impact of the financial crises of 1929-1933 finally made the policymakers understand the importance
of sound banking systems for the whole economy, and the mass poverty of the population changed the
feelings towards the desired role of the government in people’s life. Social programs, banking
regulation and supervision were implemented already during the Depression and a new field of study,
macroeconomics, continued to develop ever since serving as a guideline to policymakers to achieve
full employment and stability. Successfully, no banking panic has occurred in the United States for
more than 70 years.
In the meantime financial panics throughout the world continued to pop up every now and then, their
impact more or less contained by prompt (inter) national fiscal and monetary actions with the help of
experiences learned from each past crisis. In addition, from the 1980s a long and stable period of
growth called the Great Moderation made many believe the key to permanent growth and stability was
found forever. Some of the pillars of this infallible economic environment were liberalization,
deregulation, privatization and globalization. In other words, the ideological ‘invisible hand’ that self
regulates the economy was back.
Financial markets are very vulnerable to market failures in the absence of adequate regulation. In the
recent years, the financial system was permitted to become overleveraged feeding a housing boom in
the United States that reached enormous proportions before its collapse in 2007. Ironically, every
financial crisis exhibits a general pattern of excessive optimism that transforms a sound period of
growth into a speculative bubble. When the bubble bursts, the optimism suddenly turns into excessive
pessimism and hysteric panic reactions on the stock and the financial markets. What is different this
time with the financial crises of 2007-2008, is the fact that it was the first systemic risk in the United
States since the Great Depression years.
The aim of this thesis is to draw a comparison between the Great Depression and the present crisis.
The first part will discuss the Great Depression starting with the historical, institutional and
macroeconomic background, followed by the triggers for the crisis and the policy responses. The
second part will be a similar description of the 2007-2008 crises. In the conclusion some lessons for
the future will be accompanied by the answers to the following questions: Is it sustainable to compare
the events preceding the Great Depression to the situation prior to the financial crisis of 2007-2008?
Could the present crisis have been prevented on the basis of our knowledge about the Great
5
Depression? And, comparing the policy actions of that time with now, what have we learned and will
we succeed in mitigating the negative effects of the severe crisis?
This thesis will describe how mismanaged technological innovations in the 1920s and financial
innovations in the 1990s resulted in an unsustainable credit boom. In both periods the lagging behind
of regulations in the banking sector led to an overexposure to credit and market risk of these
institutions, which were the source of panic and banking runs once uncertainty about future profits was
revealed by declining asset prices. Both periods marked drastic structural changes in the United States
on the way to progress; from agriculture to industry in the 1920s in the real economy, and now in the
financial markets from the traditional originate-to-hold to the originate-to-distribute model. The
financial crises were on the retail level in 1920s and on the wholesale level now, nevertheless both
systemic.
The Great Depression set the example of how dramatic the impact of a financial collapse may be for
the real economy as well. Even if insecurity is still ongoing on the financial markets and we do not
have the knowledge about the full effects, provisional lessons at this point are essential to minimize
the risk that this greatest global economic recession since the 1930s turns into a new depression. A
combination of lessons learned from past and recent events, is essential to stabilize the present
insecurity on financial markets and set the stage for a new theoretical and regulatory framework that is
more adequate to cope with market failures deriving from modern financial markets, just like the
regulations during the Great Depression helped to foster stability in the decades that followed.
6
2. The Dawn of the Great Depression
Banking panics and financial crises certainly were not a unique phenomenon in the United States.
What distinguishes crises in 1929-1933 from the earlier episodes is that they occurred after the
placement of the Federal Reserve System in 1914 and more importantly, they were followed by a
decade of economic depression. Disagreement still exists on the true causes of the Great Depression
despite academic efforts of the most prominent economists since. Broadly two views prevail. The
‘monetarists’ basically blame the failure of the Federal Reserve to prevent banking panics. According
to them, had the Fed intervened adequately as a lender of last resort, the monetary contraction would
have been less severe, and so would its negative effects on the aggregate economy. This view however
is considered too narrow because it solely concentrates on the monetary factors.
In contrast, a broader view considers financial crises to be the result of a series of causes, varying from
sharp declines in asset prices, failures of both financial and non-financial firms, deflations and
uncertainty in foreign exchange markets (Mishkin, 1990, p. 2). This view helps explaining why
Europe was experiencing banking problems prior to the financial panics in America, but is too broadly
defined to create a useful theoretical framework.
To understand the Great Depression is the Holy Grail of macroeconomics; it gave birth to
macroeconomics as a distinct field of study and it continues to influence macroeconomic beliefs,
policy recommendations and research agendas (Bernanke, 2000, p. 5). Prior to the Depression,
authorities were facing a series of problems they did not know how to cope with. Especially in the
beginning, they worsened the matter by sticking to an old set of instruments which resulted in
excessively restrictive policies. To better understand the decisions in the United States of that time, we
must first take a look at what happened in Europe after the First World War and in particular the
German hyperinflation of 1922.
2.1 Historical Background
While the general interest remains the fact that the Great Depression led almost directly to the World
War II, interestingly large part of the causes that led to the Depression find their roots in the aftermath
of the First World War (1914-1918). In Table 1 a short overview of some important events illustrates
how especially Germany was afflicted in the first half of the twenties. In addition to normal post-war
economic disruptions, the country was characterized by hyperinflation in 1922-1923 and was saddled
with war reparations.
7
In January 1923, international tensions again were high when French and Belgian troops entered the
Ruhr Valley to ensure Germany paid the due reparations in goods, such as coal from the Ruhr, because
the mark was practically worthless due to hyperinflation. To put an end to these tensions, a
commission was appointed to help Germany stabilize its currency and set a new schedule for war
reparations. The Dawes Plan, launched in 1924, included a loan of 800 million marks that was to be
floated in various financial capitals against the collateral of German railroads securities, as Germany
had no gold to back its currency. Confidence was restored and the hyperinflation resolved quickly,
although the memory of its dramatic effects would echo in Germany and beyond for many years to
come.
Table 1: Overview Turbulent Twenties
1918
End First World War
1922
German Hyperinflation
1923
Invasion Ruhr Valley
1924
Dawes Plan
1925
Restoration British Gold Standard
1927
Credit and Stock Market Boom
1928
Fed increases interest rate
1929
Stock Market Crash
The Dawes loan not only solved the hyperinflation, it was also the spark that ignited foreign lending
from New York giving rise to a boom on the international capital markets. Together with the
restoration of the pre-war Gold Standard in 1925 that stabilized the currencies, the stage was set for an
economic boom to take place once the recovery from the war was over.
This economic growth had the dark shade of leading to excess supply on the primary goods markets.
In fact, during the war the production in Europe stood still and other countries had to quickly gain
productivity to fill in the gap. When Europe resumed the production, however, this resulted in an
excess supply that led to worldwide deflationary pressures, protectionist measures and competitive
depreciations. Especially in the United States, where the agricultural sector was still very large in the
1920s, the negative effects of this agricultural depression on the rural banking sector played a major
role in the financial panics that would start in 1930 as will be explained in greater detail later.
8
The excessive fear in the United States for hyperinflation like happened in Europe, justified all the
restrictive monetary and fiscal policies that aimed at preventing high inflation at all costs and held
back the expansionary policies needed at that time to fight off the negative effects of this structural
deflation on the primary goods market and the rural banking sector. Despite the existence of the
Federal Reserve System, the institutional framework lacked regulations and expertise to foster
financial stability. In addition, many central banks were limited in their actions by their dependency
from (national) political goals and the commitment to the Gold Standard.
2.2 Institutional Framework
The Federal Reserve System was institutionalized through the Federal Reserve Act in 1913, with the
aim to put an end to the long history of regular banking panics. Still, this young institution was not
able to prevent the most severe economic contraction in U.S. history and its severe repercussions on
the rest of the world furthermore revealed other the weaknesses in the international institutional
framework. The lacking regulation of banks, the gold standard and the absence of a safety net all
contributed to a vulnerable banking system that eventually would become pray of asymmetric
information problems and runs once the conditions of the real economy started deteriorating.
2.2.1 Central Bank
By the 1920s most countries had central banks for the management of their gold and foreign reserves
and for the provision of currency and credit. These institutions were very different from how we know
them now. First of all, they were not independent from their national governments, subjecting
monetary policy to domestic goals and their destabilizing effects. Second, there was a lack in
regulation and supervision of the banking sector. In the United States for example, chartering of banks
and capital requirements were very poor or fragmented. 1 In general the importance of a sound banking
system for the real economy was underestimated during the Federal Reserve meetings. The only
exception was the Federal Reserve of New York who had more knowledge about international finance
and repeatedly tried to convince other members of the Board into more extensive open market
operations, but to no avail. Banks were systematically allowed to fail under the ‘laissez-faire’ ideology
1
Mitchener (2004, pp. 2-4) finds evidence that state regulatory and supervisory regimes help account for the
regional variation in financial distress during the Depression. For example, counties located in states that
permitted branching, adopted higher capital requirements and where supervisors had more power to liquidate
banks, experienced lower bank rate suspensions during the Great Contraction years 1929-1933 as the contagion
and credit-channel dislocations were minimal. On the contrary the suspension rates were higher in states where
branching was not allowed, reserve requirements were elevated and where supervisors were appointed for longer
terms with unlimited authority to charter banks, as this increased the incentives for banking lobbyists to
influence supervisory decisions.
9
that markets would regulate themselves through the invisible hand, despite the possibility of the
Federal Reserve to act as a lender of last resort having plenty of gold reserves.
A crucial difference with modern banking regulation is the absence prior to the Great Depression of a
safety net to protect deposit holders. Banks are particularly subject to market failures due to
asymmetric information problems that make them vulnerable to deposit withdrawals. In the absence of
government guarantees, a banking run certainly becomes rational behaviour even if everyone knows
not all the deposits are in cash, because the first to arrive have more chance to get their money back
while the last ones will not receive a penny.
The possibility to engage in expansionary policy helping out banks in trouble or guaranteeing deposits
however was not a luxury permitted to every central bank. Another important factor that tight the hand
of both monetary and fiscal policymakers was the commitment to the Gold Exchange Standard.
2.2.2 Gold Exchange Standard
Prior to the Great War, the City of London successfully managed the international Gold Standard
fostering some kind stability on the financial markets. After its suspension during war, one of the
major national objectives was its restoration to put an end to widespread high inflation and monetary
chaos. However, the price level had increased in the meantime and there was not enough gold
available. With the solution of a gold-exchange standard in which convertible foreign exchange
reserves as well as gold could be used to back national money supplies, most countries could return to
gold (Bernanke, 1990, p. 5).
The most debated example remains the restoration of the pound at par in 1925 that led to a
significantly overvalued currency. The impact on the British economy turned out to be disastrous
through its repercussions on British exports, unemployment and speculative attacks on the gold
reserves. The weakness of the standard increased because of the rising accumulation of gold in the
United States and France, which continued their restrictive monetary policies imposing deflation to the
rest of the world through the interlinkages of the exchange system. The automatic mechanism prior to
the war, with countries with more gold inflating and countries with gold outflow deflating was
disrupted and the presuppositions for British dominance on the financial markets were changing
rapidly. Eventually Britain abandoned the gold standard in 1931 after it became impossible to
maintain the fixed exchange with the pound without putting the economy through further restrictive
measures.
10
Summarizing, central banks were still very inexpert in fostering stable financial markets for several
reasons. They lacked knowledge about the importance of prudential banking regulation and
supervision and they had limited liberty of action. The gold standard on one side linked them to (gold)
reserve flows to be materially in the position to inflate or deflate, while on the other side their
dependency on national political goals further constrained their decision-making. A typical example is
perhaps the Bank of France which was not permitted to engage in open market operations despite its
large gold reserves, to prevent an undesired appreciation of the French franc as the French government
did not want to reverse the positive effects of the devaluated franc on exports and national output.
The system that worked so well prior to the War now was dysfunctional, revealing a lack of
international coordination on the financial markets which would worldwide spread deflation and
financial distress. Central banks and governments together, underestimated the impact of a systemic
risk to the real economy and banks were allowed to work themselves into overleveraged positions
during the credit boom, becoming extremely vulnerable to asymmetric information problems.
2.3 Macroeconomic Background
The post-war reparations, the foreign lending, the excess supply of primary goods and the gold
exchange standard all gave rise to a fragmented economic boom. This section will provide a short
description of the macroeconomic environment of the second half of the twenties.
2.3.1 Stabilization of the Currencies
Following the British example of a return to gold, many other countries restored the commitment to a
fixed exchange with gold albeit not at the pre-war level. France for example stabilized its currency
gradually over 1926 at an undervalued level, which permitted the country to attract large gold inflows
through the positive effects for the French exports. The stabilization of the German currency after the
hyperinflation also was successful. Although Germany did not have large gold reserves the confidence
was maintained through the real estate collateral to back up the Reichsmark. This further alimented
large short term lending flows from the U.S., in addition to the initial Dawes loan. Figure 1 illustrates
the rising U.S. and British foreign lending to Europe that started around 1926, and anticipates the
sudden lending stop in 1928.
11
Figure 1: U.S. and British Foreign Lending to Europe (in millions of dollars)
Source: Kindleberger, 1986, p. 40.
But before going too much ahead in this story, let us first see how for the United States the stable
currencies together with domestic technological and financial innovations led to an economic and
credit boom that extended beyond the U.S. border.
2.3.2 Economic and Credit Boom
Although not general and often interrupted, many countries experienced economic growth in the
twenties. Especially around 1925-1926, once the recovery from the Great War was over and currencies
were stabilized, the way was paved for an economic boom to arise. Important exceptions were Britain,
Italy and Japan while amongst the most booming countries were France and the United States. Figure
2 shows how the GNP in the United States rose steadily from 1921 to 1929 then started falling.
Growth in the United States was built around the automobile. This included the manufacture of
vehicles, tires and other components, roads, gasoline stations, oil refineries, garages and suburbs. Also,
the combustion engine spread into transport with the use of trucks and to the farm where the horses
were replaced by tractors (Kindleberger, 1986, p. 44). Structural changes that were underway affected
farming productivity, which considering the high percentage of agriculture in the United States,
contributed to the agricultural depression.
12
Figure 2: U.S. GNP Per Capita
Source: EH.Net Encyclopedia (2009).
The modernization of the economy also resulted in booming electrical appliances like radios,
refrigerators and vacuum cleaners. Practically unknown at the beginning of the 1920s, these luxury
goods were commonplace by 1929 also due to the financial innovation of instalment credit which
facilitated sales to a larger public. In the period from 1925 to 1929, the volume of instalment paper
outstanding more than doubled.
Figure 3: Short Term Interest Rates in the U.S.
Source: Homer S. and R. Sylla, 2005, pp. 396-404.
13
From July to September 1927 the Federal Reserve System implemented an expansionary policy in
response to a recession and rapidly declining commodity prices. The open market purchases and the
cut in the discount rate shaped an environment of easy money that added to the credit boom and
probably stimulated the rise in the stock market that began in the spring of 1928 (Kindleberger, 1986,
p. 53). Figure 3 shows the short term interest rates in the United States for the period 1910 to 1940,
with the rediscount rate of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York starting from 1914. The positive
effects on the stock market are represented in Figure 4.
Figure 4: New York Stock Exchange Sales and Securities Issued
Source: EH.Net Encyclopedia (2009).
In general the declining short term rates from 1921 to 1927, with the exception of call loans, reflect the
expansionary policy and the favourable environment for foreign long term lending and the start of a
stock market boom.
2.3.3 Structural Changes and the Agricultural Depression
Problems in the agricultural sector started well before the Great Depression years. The technological
innovations had improved the agricultural productivity and the European production of primary goods
had recovered quickly after the War. This resulted in strong deflationary pressures with declining
output. In Figure 5 evidence for this agricultural depression is provided by the steady declining rate of
employment.
14
Figure 5: Farm Population and Unemployment in the United States
Source: EH.Net Encyclopedia (2009).
For the United States, where the agricultural sector was very important, this significantly added to the
general level of unemployment and financial distress. The many fractioned small banks in rural areas
started having difficulties quite early, as in some states up to 85 percent of the farms were mortgaged.
Foreclosures started rising, as represented in Figure 6, and did not stop until 1927, when the interest
rates were cut and the stock market started booming.
Figure 6: U.S. Farm Mortgage Foreclosure Rate
Source: EH.Net Encyclopedia (2009).
15
The Federal Reserve was not interested in helping out small banks with liquidity and solvability issues
even if they could have done so. Often these banks were not even members of the Fed. With these
financial institutions particularly vulnerable to panics and bankruptcies once they were hit by a run,
the systemic risk was very high and it was only a matter of time until panic spread also to the city
banks despite their flourishing activities.
2.3.4 Global Imbalances
The final macroeconomic aspect that will be discussed is the rising global imbalance that contributed
to the worldwide monetary contraction and the contagion of financial problems. The scarcity of gold
and the linkages of the Gold Standard were a perfect transmission channel for international deflation
as in a scramble for gold, countries tried to attract inflows competing with high interest rates. In
addition, the two countries with most gold reserves, United States and France, accumulated gold
without inflating.
Hence, structural deflation was further exacerbated by these voluntary or imposed restrictive monetary
and fiscal policies. Probably for fear of a repetition of hyperinflation scenario’s, countries preferred to
respond to the declining output by depreciating their currencies and imposing tariffs on imports in
order to help their exporting sectors, rather than pursuing a more expansionary policy. Therefore,
given all countries were trying to protect their exports and were facing the same excess supply and
deflation problems, these depreciations only led to more deflation, triggering further depreciations.
The result was a spiralling deflation that was, in the end, the major explanation for the Great
Depression.
Concluding, despite its negative effects on spreading deflation, the Gold Standard had the initial
positive result of stabilizing the currencies, contributing to the economic growth. However, like often
happens in a rising business cycle, irrational over optimism led to a credit boom and excessive risk
taking. With weak regulation on financial institutions on the background and the negative effects of
the agricultural depression on their balance sheets, the stage was set for financial crises to occur once
uncertainty about the future triggered panics.
2.4 Financial Crisis in the United States
The chronological overview of some important events reported in Table 2 starts with the Great Crash
in 1929, which would definitively put an end to the dreams and illusions that dominated the positive
16
wind of the twenties. So although it was not the direct trigger, it significantly contributed to the first
banking panic of 1930.
Table 2: Diary of the Great Depression
1929 Stock Market Crash
1930 First U.S. Banking Panic
Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act
1931 Second U.S. Banking Panic
Banking Panic in Europe
Britain abandons Gold Standard
1932 Start Large-Scale Open Market Purchases
Reconstruction Finance Corporation (RFC)
Glass-Steagall Act
Roosevelt wins Presidential Elections
1933 Third U.S. Banking Panic
Emergency Banking Act
Bank Holiday
Agricultural Adjustment Act (AAA)
1934 Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC)
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC)
1939 Start Second World War
The financial crisis that initiated the decade of depression is very similar to more recent financial
crises. Not every crisis however leads to a depression. What follows is an explanation of why
particularly the episodes in beginning of the 1930s had such a worldwide devastating impact.
2.4.1 Initiation of Financial Crisis
In Figure 7 below, a general pattern is represented of how financial unrest develops into a banking
crisis and how this further creates severe economic disruptions. In the first stage the economy is
situated in the peak of a business cycle. At this point markets start becoming nervous and in trying to
maintain the high profit level, moral hazard and adverse selection problems arise. In the specific case
of the 1930s, these problems were the result of several factors.
First, there was the deterioration of the balance sheets of financial institutions, as the negative effects
of the agricultural depression in rural areas started affecting city banks through the withdrawals of
rural banks’ deposits. Second, the increase of interest rates of the Fed in 1928 not only added to the
17
difficulties for banks through its contractionary effect on money supply, it also set in motion an asset
price decline that found its climax when the New York Stock Market crashed in October 1929.
Figure 7: The Evolution of Financial Crises
Source: Mishkin, 2010, p. 203.
The dramatic welfare effects of this crash for the United States reached far beyond the purpose of the
policymakers at that time, namely to put an end to the stock market speculation. Finally, everything
led to general uncertainty about the future typical of every ending business cycle. In the attempt to
keep up the high level of profits that seemed sustainable during the boom, adverse selection and moral
hazard problems increase, and in the absence of an adequate regulatory framework, these asymmetric
information problems may lead to banking panics.
2.4.2 Banking Crisis
In the second stage of the crisis, the initial moral hazard and adverse selection problems are translated
to a real economic decline because the dysfunctional financial system is not allocating capital
efficiently. The declining asset prices force banks to write down and the losses on loans begin to affect
18
their solvability and liquidity; banks start deleveraging. At this point lending is cut down abruptly for
fear of lemons and deteriorating capital positions. The economic decline in turn increases the
uncertainty about soundness of financial institutions and fear spreads among the depositors, inducing
them to withdraw their money. Banking runs of course increase moral hazard and adverse selection
problems and are very contagious due to more or less irrational fears.
Figure 8: Stock Prices and the Interest Rate Spread
Source: Mishkin, 1990, p. 22.
In Figure 8 some important stages in the U.S. financial panic are indicated by RC- the Stock Market
Crash, P1- the first banking panic of November 1930, P2- the second banking panic of March 1931,
P3- Britain’s abandonment of the Gold Standard in September 1931 and PH- the bank holiday of
March 1933. According to Mishkin (1990, p. 23) it is remarkable that the level of the interest rate
spread before October 1930 remained so low despite the sharp economic contraction up to that point
and the decline in the value of stocks. This low spread indicates that asymmetric information problems
had not yet become severe in financial markets, probably because of lagged negative market
sentiments.
During the first banking crisis in October 1930, the United States experienced an extraordinary rise in
the deposits suspended by banks. In November 1930, 256 banks failed with $180 million of deposits,
followed by 352 failed banks in December 1930 with over $370 million deposits. According to
Friedman and Schwartz, the failure of the Bank of United States on December 11, which alone
19
accounted for $200 million deposits, was of particular importance because it was the largest
commercial bank ever to have failed up to that time in the U.S. history and its name led many at home
and abroad to regard it as an official bank. Also being a member of the Federal System, the failure was
a serious blow to the System’s prestige (2008, pp. 25-27). As banks reacted each seeking to strengthen
their own liquidity position, this led to an even worse second panic in March 1931.
2.4.3 Debt Deflation
What made the Great Depression the worst economic contraction in U.S. history was not the structural
deflation or the stock market crash. A process called debt deflation is what distinguished this period.
Essentially, an additional unexpected price level decline led to an increased burden of indebtedness at
the firm level, which negatively affected the net worth of firms (Mishkin, 2010, p. 206). Debt deflation,
probably caused by the lacking quick and substantial expansionary policy response at that time, caused
longer lasting and more severe moral hazard problems and adverse selection problems. Their negative
impact on lending and investment opportunities kept the economy far below its full potential for a
decade, with unemployment in the United States reaching peaks of 25 percent. In Europe, where the
negative impact of the American depression accrued to the own difficult economic and financial
positions, the situation was not much better.
2.5 Repercussions on Europe
The scope of this thesis is to compare the two major financial crises in the United States. Therefore,
not much attention has been given so far to the financial distress in Europe although this was almost
simultaneous to the American. The increase of the interest rates around 1928 that contributed to a stop
in foreign lending from the United States, as shown in Figure 1, led to an abrupt stop of the credit
boom in Europe. Especially for Germany, which was very dependent on these funds for monetary
purposes as it could not rely on gold reserves, the effects on the banking system were dramatic. With
the failure in May 1931 of the Austrian bank Creditanstalt that triggered banking panics Austria, the
contagion to Germany and the rest of Europe was almost immediate. Only France was temporarily
saved by its large gold reserves.
On the contrary, the situation was particularly tensed in Britain which was constrained to abandon the
gold standard in September 1931. It however turned out to be a relief because of the immediate
devaluation of the pound and the benefits for the exports, in addition to the stop of restrictive
commitments to the gold standard. Interestingly, the spreading of panic across the Atlantic region is an
20
important element that returns in both the Great Depression period and the more recent financial
panics.
2.6 Recovery
At long last, in April 1932, the System embarked on large scale open market purchases and more
legislation was implemented to stabilize the financial system. Two examples are the Reconstruction
Finance Corporation (RFC), chartered to provide loans to different financial institutions and other
businesses, and the Glass-Steagall Act, which was mainly designed to broaden the collateral the
Reserve System could hold against Federal Reserve notes.
In the meantime Franklin Delano Roosevelt won the presidential elections but this was not sufficient
to stop a third banking panic in 1933. This last flow of banking runs was counteracted with the
proclamation of a nationwide banking holiday, made possible by the Emergency Banking Act passed
during a special session at the Congress. This Act confirmed the powers assumed by the President in
declaring the holiday and facilitated the closing down of insolvent banks and the reorganization and
opening of stronger institutions. Finally in 1934, the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) and
the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) were institutionalized.
The unprecedented emergency legislation under Roosevelt, better known as the New Deal, not only
regulated banking. It also aimed at alleviating the economic disease through programs that reduced
unemployment and assisted business and agriculture; security was provided for the weaker segments
of the population, as half the population was living below the minimum subsistence level. Although
the U.S. gross debt increased from $22.5 billion in 1933 to $40.44 billion in 1939, Roosevelt was
reluctant to accept anymore deficit spending than the absolutely necessary to prevent mass suffering.
The United States finally abandoned the Gold Standard in 1933.
This account of the Great Depression cannot be concluded without mentioning John Maynard Keynes
and his General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, published in 1936, in which he provided
a convincing theoretical framework in justification of counter-cyclical fiscal and monetary policies,
needed to shallow business cycles and correct market failures. According to him, to put an end to the
Depression, massive government spending was needed to compensate the hoarding behavior of people
and fill the consumption gap that kept the economy below its potential equilibrium. His
‘interventionist’ theory was an attack to the neo-classical ‘laissez-faire’ paradigm that was founded
rational behavior of economic agents and on the free market’s natural achievement of full employment.
21
However, it was not until the U.S. government was forced to large defense expenditures by the
imminent Second World War that the Depression in fact ended, and that the Keynesian theory would
be implemented by Western policymakers.
Mainstream macroeconomics based on the General Theory continued to develop ever since,
successfully preventing depressions, but losing popularity after the high volatility of economic
fundamentals in the seventies. Starting from the eighties, a new flow of deregulations and
liberalizations increased market efficiency and contributed to the Great Moderation. The ideology of
free markets that take care of themselves was gaining absolute popularity again. Unfortunately, the
positive effects were not general, as the dramatic financial panics of 2007-2008 illustrate. What
happened is that in the absence of adequate regulations in the financial sector, market failures arose
again, feeding an American house price bubble that continued to expand thanks to financial
innovations and excessive liquidity. Chapter 3 will describe what went wrong in the financial markets
in more detail.
22
3. Financial Crises 2007 and 2008
In the long period from the Great Depression to now the world has completely changed. The lessons
learned from past mistakes helped improving regulation, supervision, monetary policies and
international cooperation in such a way that financial crises so far, had a limited impact on the world’s
financial stability and real economy. Besides, the absence of significant financial disruptions was also
beneficial for a very stable economic environment, better known as the Great Moderation.
The events of 2007 and 2008 pulled the United States and Europe abruptly out of the illusion that a
systemic risk on the financial market belonged to the black and white history of the 1930s. This
chapter aims at explaining why the 2007-2008 panics are different from other recent crises and why
these differences makes them more similar to those that preceded the Great Depression, despite the
completely different settings. What follows is an overview of the recent history, institutional
framework and macroeconomic antecedents that contributed to the environment of excess liquidity,
one of the major causes of the rise of the new bubble.
3.1 Historical Background
The Second World War put a definitive end to the economic depression of the 1930s, when it forced
the massive spending that was required to restore the economy to its full employment level.
Nevertheless, economic instability persisted long after the war, predominantly in the form of high
inflation. Things gradually changed from the early eighties, when a happy period of stable output
growth and prices called the Great Moderation, made us believe we had found the key to eternal
economic equilibrium. This dream shattered with the burst of the house price bubble in the United
States, and worsened a year later when panic persisted. Some historical events represented in Table 3
may help understanding the prerequisites for this bubble to occur despite the stable environment.
First, there is the structural deflation that hit Japan in the 1990s. Among the factors that contributed to
the deflation was the burst of the equities and real estate bubble in 1989, which had a double impact on
the prices through its negative effect on the money supply and the general price level, and in the form
of restricted credit conditions, due to the solvency problems at many companies and banks that had
invested in real estate. In addition, deflation was imported from China and other upcoming Asian
countries with lower prices. The government and the Bank of Japan responded reducing interest rates
with a zero-rate policy but did not succeed in reanimating the economy, the country was stuck in a
liquidity trap.
23
Table 3: Early Nineties and 2000
1990
Deflation Japan
1992
Implementation Basel Accord (1988)
2000
‘New Economy’ bubble bursts
2001
Twin Tower attack
The second event was the burst of the New Economy bubble in early 2000, after the growth of
technology and internet possibilities in the 1990s led to over valuated stock prices. Central banks
responded with massive interest rate reductions in line with the lesson learned from the Japanese
economical downturn, which was to act quickly and aggressively in order to shallow the recession
after the burst. Successfully the fall in asset prices had no important effect on the real economy and no
deep recession occurred. Finally, another important monetary event was the massive injection of
liquidity on the capital markets after the attack on the World Trade Centre in 2001. Similarly here,
policymakers succeeded in keeping the system stable and around 2003 the real economy had
recovered.
The unstoppable deflationary forces in Japan were the scary evidence that the kind of structural
deflation that left policymakers powerless during the Great Depression could still be active in our
modern days. The expansionary influence on monetary policies worldwide, i.e. the continued large
amount of money on the market and the low interest rates, stimulated the beginning of a new credit
cycle, that fed by new possibilities in the form of financial innovations would lead again to a
speculative bubble. The better regulated and supervised banking sector through the independency of
central banks, deposit guarantee schemes and international capital requirements were not enough to
stop financial panic.
3.2 Institutional framework
Ever since the importance of a sound financial system was acknowledged after the Depression,
authorities worldwide started developing a better institutional framework in order to foster financial
stability and prevent systemic risk. Importantly, legislative changes protected deposit holders,
reshaped the role of governments and central banks, subjected the banking sector to stricter regulation
and supervision rules, and increased international coordination through the establishment of
institutions like the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) in 1930 and the International Monetary
Fund (IMF) in 1944. With the scope of increasing efficiency on the capital markets, deregulation and
24
liberalization started in the 1980s, changing for good the rules of the game in the global financial
markets.
3.2.1 Independent Central Banks
In general central banks in industrialized countries now are independent institutions who received
mandates from their government to implement monetary policy. Although decisions at the central
bank are bounded by the specific mandate, predominantly price stability, their discretionary power
remains large. More decision power is also due to the flexible exchange rates, in contrast with the tight
hands for the maintenance of a fixed exchange rate regime as was the case during the Gold Standard
and later the Bretton Woods System.
In their role as the lender of last resort, central banks also are granted much liberty. Through the
possibility of helping financial institutions in liquidity problems, they significantly may contribute to
stable financial systems. Central banks also have supervisory and regulatory powers of the banking
sector, albeit in combination with the governments and other national institutions designed to mitigate
asymmetric information problems on the financial markets.
3.2.2 Banking Regulation and Supervision
The rationale for authorities’ intervention is to reduce the negative effects of market failures to which
the financial system is extremely vulnerable to. The most important, asymmetric information, at the
same time makes banks uniquely important for a good functioning market economy. Banks contribute
to an efficient allocation of capital through their knowledge advantage about assessing risks of
investments, permitting also non-financial agents to invest without having to gather this costly
information themselves. On the banks’ balance sheet, long term loans on the asset side are financed
trough short term deposits and other securities on the liabilities’ side.
According to standard economic theory, banks have every incentive to monitor and produce
information about the borrower to minimize the risk of losses in case of default, while making large
profits from interest and amortizations. Through deposits and securities banks create informationinsensitive debt; deposit-holders need not to be concerned about the value of the check and bonds are
not subject to adverse selection because to produce private information for speculation purposes it is
not profitable (Gorton, 2009, p. 7).
25
The disturbances caused by asymmetric information however cannot be ignored by regulators. Banks
are vulnerable to solvency risks due to the mismatch in the maturity transformation. For example, the
depositors’ lack of knowledge about the quality of banking activities and their assets can lead to
banking panics. Also the lack of knowledge about risk taking activities of banks makes agents
reluctant to trust their funds to the banks, as in the event of a failure they risk losing their money.
Chartering, bank examination, bank disclosure and capital requirements are just some elements of
prudential supervision central banks implement in addition to their lender of last resort role.
Governments also may intervene directly in the functioning of financial markets through injections of
liquidity, nationalisations and deposit insurance. Deregulation and liberalization of financial markets,
together with the differences in national regulations, called for international rules to create a level
playing field on global financial markets. The Basel Capital Accord of 1988 was developed to respond
to this need.
3.2.3 Basel Capital Accord
Prudential supervision is nation-bound and may differ significantly from country to country. Due to
increased deregulation and globalization that started in the 1980s it was necessary to come with
international rules to address the rising complexity of financial markets. To mitigate the vulnerability
to solvency risk that could come forth from the rising transaction activities of banks, the emphasis was
on capital regulations. In 1988 the Basel Accord was published by the Basel Committee. This set of
minimal capital requirements would be first implemented in 1992 by a group of ten countries and
continued to spread since. In a nutshell, banks with international presence were required to hold capital
equal to a minimum of 8 percent of their risk-weighted assets.
These assets were classified in four categories according to their credit risk; 0 percent risk-weight for
reserves and sovereign debt of OECD countries, 20 percent for claims on banks of OECD countries,
50 percent on municipal bonds and residential mortgages and 100 percent risk-weight for corporate
and household debt. This emphasis on credit risk, that is the risk of losses due to the debtor’s nonpayment of the loan, whether further specified in sovereign risk and counterparty risk, soon was being
thought of as outdated in light of the shortcomings of this construction to deal with increasing
complexity of the financial products, the financial markets and the intrinsic incentives for capital
arbitrage. 2 An amendment to the Capital Accord of 1988 introduced the computation of market risk in
2
Excessive risk taking could not be prevented with these capital requirements as no distinctions were made
between AAA rated bonds and CCC rated bonds. Also, country risk of OECD members was treated with an
equal weight when in fact, given different macroeconomic conditions, the sovereign risk of different OECD
member counties may differ significantly. As with higher risk comes higher profit, banks were tempted into
more risky business while still meeting the capital requirements.
26
1996, responding to possible losses due to changes in the value of investments resulting from changes
in the market. 3
In 2004 the New Basel Capital Accord (Basel II) was endorsed by the banking supervisory authorities
of the G10 countries, in response to the need for better risk control. The challenge of Basel II was to
achieve this through the introduction of operational and market risk in addition to credit risk
assessments and the incentive to develop and improve tailored risk management functions within
individual banking organisations (first pillar), a more active role for supervisory authorities to
encourage banks to improve their risk management (second pillar) and improved market discipline
through disclosure of banks, in order to provide all market participants sufficient information for
assessing risks and performances of the financial institutions (third pillar) (ECB Monthly Bulletin,
2005, p. 49).
Two important differences with the previous Accord reside in the first pillar. The first, although the
minimum capital requirement of 8 percent of risk-weighted assets remained unchanged, is the
inclusion of operational risk; the risk of a loss resulting from failures in the part internal processes (for
example people or systems) or from external events. The second is the introduction of sophisticated
and risk-sensitive options for the calculations of credit and operational risk. Where under Basel I the
risk weight depended on the category of the borrower, now risks were tailored using a credit rating
provided by a recognised external credit assessment institution (ECAI) that met supervisory eligibility
standards (ECB Monthly Bulletin, 2005, p. 50).
With this comes an important point of critique on the Basel rules in light of the current financial crises,
the role rating agencies played in the risk assessment of smaller banks. Smaller banks could in fact
choose to rely on rating agencies instead of making complicated internal calculations. In other words,
they could ‘outsource’ the mere thing a good bank should be about: risk management. This
fundamental flaw took away the responsibility out the bank for its actions, and later proved even more
disastrous once the ratings given to certain types of assets came under fire. Another point of discussion
is the procyclical effect of Basel that has been already witnessed in this period of deleveraging.
To conclude, the focus on capital requirements of the traditional segment of banking, created an
incentive to find loopholes in the regulations. Through the construction of larger financial
conglomerates and separate vehicles that fell out of the supervision scope, the financial system became
overleveraged taking excessive risks. If it is true that regulations lag behind, however, macroeconomic
3
Examples of changes in the market conditions that may affect the value of investments are movements in the
exchange rate (currency risk), interest rates, and equity and commodity prices.
27
policy also was dormant and did not recognize in time the overheating economy. Reassured by the
Great Moderation period, not enough was done to fight the unsustainable inflation in the asset markets.
3.3 Macroeconomic Background
Beyond any doubt the current recession finds its roots in the dysfunctions on the financial markets but
a closer look at the macroeconomic antecedents also is essential for understanding how the credit
bubble was initiated and more importantly, how the crisis propagated. What follows is a brief
discussion of the Great Moderation, the loose monetary policy and the global imbalances that
contributed to the credit boom.
3.3.1 Great Moderation
The Great Inflation of 1970s was a period of high macroeconomic imbalance in which price
regulations, trade restrictions, oil shocks and the Bretton Woods system of fixed-exchange rates all
contributed to price volatility. In addition, the benchmark used for monetary policy was a long-term
trade-off between unemployment and inflation. Since the early 1980s this volatility in the
industrialized countries declined and was replaced by a period of stable growth that lasted 25 years,
the Great Moderation. Explanations for this change include globalization, as it outsourced production
to cheaper production countries and increased the competition on world trade markets. Also, the
domestic output gap which is an important determinant for monetary policy became less important
because positive gaps could be flattened with exports and negative gaps could be filled with imports.
Another explanation is the mitigating impact of structural changes on the macroeconomic effect of
positive or negative shocks. Some examples are the increased competition in labour and product
markets, the shift from manufacturing to services and the improved inventory management that
attenuated the inventory cycle. Furthermore, these shocks were lowered by innovations in financial
markets that facilitated the greater spreading of risk and enabled economic agents to smooth spending
(Bean, 2009, p. 4).
The Great Moderation may also be the result of better monetary policy. In the past, central banks were
often not entirely independent from their governments making their monetary decisions sensible to
their government’s desired level of output. The trade-off between inflation and output consequently
resulted in the incentive to create a higher ‘surprise’ inflation to get lower real wages, stimulate
production in the short-term and lower unemployment. The problem is that economic agents soon
understand this time inconsistency problem the policymakers face and surprise inflation will cease to
28
have the desired effects once households start anticipating higher inflation. From the early 1980s the
experience was that through a mandate of price stability and other stability-oriented policies, a
credible central bank may successfully anchor low inflation expectations and pursue both a stable
output and stable prices goal at the same time.
In light of the current crisis more people are sceptical about the true benefits of the 25 years of
equilibrium. Cornerstones like the liberalization of the goods and capital market, further reaching
deregulation of especially the financial markets and the benefits of globalization, all are under scrutiny
again. Some people go as far as to believe it was all just a matter of good luck due to less severe
shocks in these years. In my opinion, it would be an exaggeration to ascribe the Great Moderation
solely to good luck because there have been important shocks in those years. Also the importance of
independent, credible central banks has been proved in many studies. Nevertheless, we are forced
again to reconsider what determines stability and growth equilibrium, and especially how to stay there.
3.3.2 Loose Monetary Policy
The previous account provided ‘better monetary policy’ as one of the explanations for stable economic
fundamentals. Despite the formation of the bubble and the subsequent collapse of the financial market,
this does not mean this explanation should be rejected a priori. Evidence suggests that especially in the
United States monetary policy has been too loose in the past years, implicating it was not necessarily
the policy framework that was bad, rather it was badly implemented. According to Taylor (2007, p. 2),
during the period from 2003 to 2006 ‘the federal funds rate was well below what experience during
the previous two decades of good economic macroeconomic performance - the Great Moderation –
would have predicted’. The low interest rates and the provision of large amounts of liquidity that
continued even after the recovery from the asset bubble of 2000 helped the extraordinary rise in
demand for housing, which in turn led to further house price inflation.
Related to this problem of interest rates below sustainable levels, is the view that the central banks
underestimated the inflation rates they based their policy decisions on. High inflation was often
addressed as a problem of ‘global inflation’ about which national monetary authorities had no power.
However, if inflation is imported from other countries while the whole world is experiencing inflation,
are we then importing inflation from another planet?
The Fed’s focus on ‘core inflation’ since start of the new millennium has been criticized a lot. Core
inflation eliminates the more variable prices from the headline inflation, and is therefore a good
predictor of future headline inflation. The impact of globalization on world prices is ambiguous, as it
29
may also drive up the inflation through the increased demand for goods from booming countries. In
the past years emerging markets persistently entered the global economy as demanders of non-core
commodities and suppliers of core goods. Considering core goods are subject to price rigidities, while
non-core goods have flexible prices, a continued upward movement in the relative price of non-core
goods to core goods may cause a temporary increase of the headline inflation, and at the same time a
temporary reduction of the core inflation (Buiter, 2008, pp. 66-68). For this reason, the medium-term
inflationary pressures may have been higher than the Fed thought they were, keeping the interest rates
below the reasonable framework levels.
3.3.3 Global Imbalances
The rapid growth in the last decade of emerging market economies like China, India and Brazil should
have led to inflow of capital from advanced countries according to standard economic theory. This is
because capital in growing economies is needed to provide the investment necessary to equip the extra
workers. Instead, we saw the opposite happen as especially China was exporting capital to the United
States and the United Kingdom (Bean, 2009, p. 6). Among the explanations for this phenomenon we
find the ‘savings glut’ hypothesis advanced by Bernanke. According to him, the fact that surplus
countries engage in attracting even more capital may be a reflection of their wish to accumulate
precautionary holdings of international reserves and on the micro level, the outcome of a lacking
household safety net.
It is possible that global imbalances contributed to the credit boom through the decline in long term
interest rates in advanced countries, linked to the ‘savings glut’. For example, the low level of real
returns on government bonds may have encouraged financial institutions to shift investment into
riskier assets areas like the ABS market, in search for yield.
In summary, the Great Moderation and the easy monetary policy all contributed to the bubble in
several ways. First, the low rates meant the return on risk-free assets was very low, making it more
attractive for people to invest in riskier assets. This ‘search for yield’ was further enforced by the
excess liquidity on the markets, in part imported from emerging economies, and the financial
innovations that made these investments possible. A second contribution is through the cheaper credit
possibilities which created situations of over lending and over consumption. Third, there is the
persistent underestimation of future risks to which the long period of prosperity contributed. Finally,
the low rates made it very unattractive to save money. A problem that maybe was not considered when
everything went well because banks financed themselves with liquid short term assets, but that created
serious problems at banks once the short term assets markets froze. At this point, to complete the
30
puzzle that reconstructs the onset of the credit boom, we will turn in greater detail to the contribution
of the financial innovations.
3.4 Credit Boom
Similar to the technological innovations in the past like electricity, railroads and internet that increased
productivity and gave rise to new credit cycles, also this time it were innovations that started the new
cycle albeit in the financial sector. Also similarly, the beginning was very positive through the creation
of new opportunities. What follows is a simplistic example of how banks moved from the originate-tohold model to an originate-to-distribute model applying the technique of securitization, enabling the
shadow banking to reach enormous proportions.
3.4.1 Securitization of Debts
Although they started flourishing after 2003, innovations in the financial markets already existed in
the 1990s. For example the use of derivatives was a way financial institutions found to hedge all kinds
of risks in response to the high interest rate volatility of the 1970s and 1980s. Encouraged and
sometimes sponsored by the government, securitization of debt started to play an important role in the
U.S. housing market. Residential and commercial mortgages were not the only type of debt that could
be securitized, also student loans, credit card receivables and loans to businesses could be used as
collateral for Asset Backed Securities (ABSs).
To explain how securitization works, let us start with the balance sheet of an imaginary traditional
mortgage bank as shown in Table 4. On the asset side the bank has ‘issued mortgages’, on the
liabilities’ side the bank has deposits and capital. To meet the capital requirements, there is a limit to
the mortgage lending the bank may offer its clients. Also because of the short term liabilities versus
the long term mortgage annuities, the banks has every incentive to screen and monitor potential
lenders in order to minimise default and credit risks. This is the classical example of a distribute-tohold model, or in other words, a relationship oriented banking model with incentives on both sides to
invest in mutual trust and long term business relations. The mortgage owner in most cases holds all his
financial business at the same bank.
Now let us turn to the innovation of securitization. The bank may sell the finished mortgage products
in bundles to a separate institution, for example a Structured Investment Vehicle (SIV) in return for
cash. This institution was not physically present but rather a legal construction, a Master Trust, set up
by the bank who wanted to apply the technique of securitization. Importantly, it was thought to be
31
completely independent from the bank. Table 4 illustrates how cash is received in turn for the bundle
of mortgages and the debt risk is swept away from the official balance sheet. In case the capital
requirements in this example are 10 percent of the total assets, the bank now may create another
package of mortgages that can be sold on. Securitization enables the bank to generate mortgages and
issue all other kinds of debt moving it off-balance without ever having to raise its capital in order to
meet the capital requirements.
In this originate-to-distribute model banks became transaction oriented and acted more as financial
intermediaries. The cash flows emanated from assets are sold on to the SIVs and the bank loses the
incentives to monitor the loans. The risks are removed from the bank’s balance, at least in theory.
Table 4: Balance Sheet Mortgage Bank
Mortgage Bank
Before
securitization
Assets
Liabilities
Mortgages
100
Deposits
Capital
90
10
Total
100
Total
100
Cash
After
securitization
100
Deposits
Capital
90
10
Total
100
Total
100
Table 5: Balance Sheet Special Investment Vehicle
Special Investment Vehicle
Assets
Liabilities
MBS
100
ABCP
Capital
95
5
Total
100
Total
100
32
To complete the story, in Table 5 the balance sheet of an imaginary SIV is represented. It shows how
the purchase of the long term assets was financed through issuance of short term securities to investors
in the form of asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP).
Figure 9 below is a scheme of how this worked in practice. The general characteristic of ABSs is that
their payment relies upon cash flows from a specific pool of assets rather than on the general credit of
the issuing corporation (Gorton, 2009, p. 8). The mortgage ‘pools’ were subdivided according to the
priority of cash flow payments into senior, mezzanine tranches and so on. The highest rating was for
senior tranches, AAA, who had the lowest risk of loss because they were the first to be paid out of the
incoming cash flows.
Figure 9: Securitization of Assets
Source: Gorton, 2009, p. 8.
Banks, whether or not related to these SIVs, received fees from these mortgages. This is a classical
example of regulatory arbitrage, because banks acted like SIVs were independent when in fact, as
would become very clear later, they were not. When the SIV got into liquidity problems after ABCP
was pulled back, banks injected liquidity through credit lines in such amounts that finally transmitted
liquidity problems to the banks as well.
33
A problem that returns in cycles is that markets are one step ahead of regulators and there is always an
incentive to find loopholes in the regulation (Hoogduin, 2009). SIVs did not have to meet any
regulators capital requirements and supervisors did not look at these off-balance sheets focussing
instead on the capital positions of banks which were of course always solvent. The levels of leveraging
in the financial sector were increasing to dangerous levels under the nose of authorities as the capital
risk in the shadow banking was taking large proportions. However, as long as the access to liquidity
functioned well there were no serious problems.
3.4.2 Rising Complexity of Derivatives
The expansion of the issuance of debt continued rising as banks could create loans to businesses and
households and sell these to the conduits, thus shifting the risk off their balance sheet. Not only
housing benefited from the low interest rates and the innovations, also M&A sectors of banks and
companies increasingly used the credit markets to fund their activities, rather than relying on more
traditional mediums like deposits and stock issuances respectively. The demand for collateral rose
together with the markets for structured products, and new products came into life to meet the demand.
Collaterized Debt Obligations (CDOs) 4 became very popular providing lots of new opportunities and
Credit Default Swaps (CDSs) allowed investors to hedge themselves against a wider range of default
risk (Bean, 2009, p. 3). Risks could be sliced and diced, made tradable and be redistributed towards
those in better positions to bear them according to the rating of these products, resulting in a more
flexible and efficient credit market. What happened in time is that the difficulty to assess risks rose as
the complexity of the products increased. In addition, the explosion of credit was not associated with
an even expansion in demand for goods, leading to a dangerous build-up of household and business
debt to GDP (Bean, 2009, p. 3). The price of the assets was becoming dangerously high in comparison
to the real value of the underlying collateral, especially in the U.S. housing sector.
At some point it became possible to allow riskier borrowers access to mortgage finance through the
financial innovation of ‘subprime mortgages’. This innovation was warmly welcomed in the beginning
not only by banks; it was on the U.S. political agenda to allow every American to own a house. This
adds to the idea that financial innovations also offered great opportunities in the beginning, but fact
remains the panic started in the subprime sector so it is worth to go into these products in more detail.
4
A cash CDO is a special purpose vehicle, which buys a portfolio of fixed income assets and finances the
purchase of the portfolio via issuing different tranches of risk in the capital market. For example, ABS CDOs
have underlying portfolios consisting of asset-backed securities (ABS), including residential mortgage-backed
securities (RMBS), and commercial mortgage-backed securities (CMBS) (Gorton, 2008, p. 34).
34
3.4.3 Subprime Deals
Subprime mortgages and their financing structures were designed in a way as to respond to the need to
deal with riskier borrowers and therefore they significantly differed from traditional ‘prime’ contracts.
Gorton (2008, p. 12) pins the defining feature of subprime lending as the idea that the counterparties
can benefit from house price appreciation over short horizons, mostly two or three years. Most
subprime mortgages are adjustable-rate mortgages (ARMs) with 30-years amortizations in a hybrid
structure ‘2/28’ or ‘3/27’. 5 The first number stands for the initial period of two or three years in which
the rate is fixed, often a lower ‘teaser’ rate, while the remaining 28 or 27 years will have a floating
interest rate. Despite its name, however, the teaser rate was not much lower than the average 8.5
percent rate used in prime mortgages.
After the initial period, on the ‘step-up date’, the floating rate regime came into force. Usually this was
calculated as the benchmark LIBOR plus 6.1 percent on average and updated every six months.
Intuitively, if the LIBOR rate would float significantly this was transmitted to the flexible mortgage
rate, but even if the LIBOR remained constant the resulting rate was very high. Borrowers were
essentially forced after the reset date to go back to the lenders and ask for a refinance, which in most
cases was possible due to the house value increase, because of the impossibly high mortgage fees. In
some cases even an equity extraction could be obtained from the increased house value that could be
used for other types of consumption.
The risk of losses for the lenders was thought to be very low as they ultimately had the decision power
to refinance or not, and in the worst case of a default on the mortgage they would get the house. 6
Between 1998 and 2006, when house prices were still steadily moving upwards, subprime mortgages
were working quite well (Gorton, 2008, p. 18). The security design of subprime bonds reflected the
particular construction of their collateral, the subprime mortgages. The difference with other types of
collateral, like credit card receivables and prime mortgages, was that these were not very sensitive to
price changes. In the meantime these investments were thought to be low risk bearing. When finally
CDOs started purchasing significant amounts of subprime RMBS bonds, the complexity of the
products rose as well as ‘subprime’ fraction of the booming financial markets.
5
‘Hybrid’ stands for the combination of both a fixed and a floating rate-element.
This form of lending is sometimes called ‘predatory lending’ because the borrower is tempted to engage in the
mortgage without realising that in the end the lender had every power not to refinance and basically put the
borrower on the street.
6
35
3.4.4 Subprime Bubble
The difficulty is that with hindsight the dangers of rising asset prices are very clear, but while its
happening increased efficiency and cheaper credit in financial markets is a good thing, especially
when it can provide houses to more people. In these times over optimism makes it difficult to
distinguish ‘real progress’ from the formation of bubbles and overexposure to risk in the financial
sector. Fact remains that at some point the best deals were made and mortgages started being sold to
very risky borrowers.
Table 6: The Unstoppable Subprime Market
2004
Implementation New Basel Accord (1996)
Fed increases interest rate
2005
ECB increases interest rate
2006
Exponential growth subprime derivatives
By 2006 the extremely low perceived risks in financial markets by no means reflected the true risks
coming from the highly leveraged banking system. Nonetheless, economic fundamentals were better
than ever, asset and house prices were increasing and when everything goes well, people tend to
believe it cannot go wrong. For policymakers also it is not easy to take action in this stage. When you
know there is a bubble you are basically too late; even if interest rates are raised, the profits would still
be higher and trading could not be stopped. The gradual rise in interest rates implemented by the Fed
in 2004 and the ECB in 2005 shown in Table 6 illustrate this impotence. The subprime issues boomed
in 2006.
Incentive distortions intrinsic to the transactions oriented banking model also contributed to the boom,
as banks leveraged up to high levels without increasing their monitoring and screening. They could
have felt protected by their ‘too big’ or ‘too interconnected’ to fail position, their good liquidity
options, the knowledge that house prices in the U.S. did not decline nationwide since the Second
World War and of course, the considerable movement of risk to the conduits. They however
misjudged their true risk position first because of the credit lines these ‘independent’ SIVs had with
their supporting banks through which liquidity problems could be transferred directly back ‘on
balance’. Secondly, the debt securities issued by one bank were often bought by the propriety trading
desks of other banks instead of being sold on to investors outside the banking system, leading to a
crossholding of underlying loans of which the risk remained widely in the banking system instead of
being distributed (Bean, 2009, p. 8).
36
Incentive distortions on the level of the rating agencies also played a significant role, as they could
make high profits from giving high ratings to these products. Even once the risk is perceived, however,
it is not easy to get out. Managers could get fired if they refused to trade options because they would
miss lots of profits and the reason is also psychological, similar to the first to jump from the Titanic.
‘As long as the music plays, we are still dancing’ said the former CEO of the Citygroup Chuck Prince
in the summer of 2007. The music would stop playing shortly afterwards when housing inflation
halted and the dark shadow of fundamental uncertainty spread panic among financial markets.
3.5 Financial Crises 2007-2008
Despite the completely different settings, the mechanisms that gave rise to the recent financial crises
resemble a lot those of the 1929-1933 represented in Figure 7. The interest rates were increasing, the
asset prices declining and the balance sheets of financial institutions deteriorating. The general
uncertainty that accompanies every ending business cycle was now extremely dangerous due to the
immeasurable non-regulated shadow banking. After the first panic in the fall of 2007, policymakers
worldwide acted promptly but could not prevent the even more dramatic panic attack that would take
place a year later.
3.5.1 Financial Panic 2007 ‘Subprime Crisis’
The simple chronological overview of events in Table 7, reports how the feeling of uncertainty came
rather late considering what was happening on the markets since 2003.
Table 7: The Subprime Crises of 2007
February
Subprime defaults increase
July
U.S. house prices decrease
August
BNP Paribas announcement
Run on SIVs and drying up ABCP market
ECB and Fed injections on the money markets
Fed starts cutting interest rates
September
Bank run at Northern Rock
December
Term Auction Facility (TAF)
37
The trouble only started in 2006 after the house price peak was reached and then worsened quickly
after February 2007, when defaults in subprime mortgages started increasing. Owners were not able or
willing to pay back a debt that was becoming higher than the house value and the assessment of the
value of subprime related products became very problematic.
The ABX index (see Figure 10) played a crucial role in revealing the information to the public that the
risk on subprime derivatives could be higher than expected. The index was based on the price of CDSs;
a decline of this rate represents the higher costs of insuring a basket of mortgages against default
(Brunnermeier, 2008, p. 8).
Figure 10: Decline in Mortgage Credit Swap ABX Indices
Source: Brunnermeier, 2008, p. 9.
The first financial institutions started suffering from subprime-related losses and rating agencies
immediately proceeded downgrading tranches. This had a negative impact on the prices of mortgagerelated products, further triggering downgrades of other tranches and preoccupation in the credit
markets. The turning point came in July 2007 when house prices in the United States were decreasing
nationwide like did not happen for a long time. The risks of derivatives now were impossible to
calculate given the lack of information on what would happen next. All existing models for risk
assessment were based on some form of increasing prices. This fundamental uncertainty produced a
new kind of panic on the financial markets; instead of a lack of confidence from the private citizens
towards credit institutions on a ‘retail’ level, the lack of trust was among financial institutions on the
‘wholesale’ level of which funding was largely based on collateral.
38
The blow came on August 9, 2007, when the hedge fund of one of the largest European banks, the
French BNP Paribas, announced they would not repay asset holders because of what was happening in
the United States. It became clear that the troubles with U.S. housing had spilled over the underlying
assets and the inability to value structurized products triggered a run on the SIVs. This resulted in the
drying up of the ABCP market as can be seen from Figure 11 and the related banks had to fill in the
liquidity gap through credit lines.
Figure 11: Outstanding Asset-Backed Commercial Paper (ABCP) and Unsecured Commercial
Paper
Source: Brunnermeier, 2008, p. 11.
The higher perceived liquidity and default risk of banks dried up other short term funding markets as
well. Uncertainty about the exposure to risk of other banks froze interbank lending and the LIBOR
shifted upwards. Banks desperately in need for liquidity started selling stocks, even at much lower
prices but nobody wanted to buy MBS anymore. Other stock prices went down as well and so
contagion spread even to banks that did not have MBS. In Figure 12 the trouble on the liquidity
markets is revealed by the peaking interest rate spreads. The beginning of the credit crunch coincides
with the announcement of BNP Paribas on August 9, 2007, but if we already look forward to the
spikes of the ‘Great Panic’ of 2008 it is clear that the worse had yet to come. For now the focus
remains on the ‘little’ subprime panic of 2007.
39
Figure 12: Interest Rates Spreads
Source: Brunnermeier, 2008, p. 13.
The LIBOR-OIS spread is the difference between the London Interbank Offered Rate, the rate at
which banks make unsecured short term loans (mostly overnight to three months) to each other, and
the Overnight Indexed Swap, which in the U.S. is based on the federal funds rate. The credit crunch is
indicated by a higher spread, which reflects the unwillingness of banks to lend money to each other.
The contraction in the T-Bill-OIS spread reflects the popularity of Treasury bills as collateral, while
the spread between mortgage-backed repos and general collateral repos on the lower panel, indicate
the opposite sentiment towards MBS as collateral. 7 Finally, the ‘agency spread’ between 30-year
agency bonds issued by government-sponsored enterprises (Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac) and 30-year
Treasury bonds, reveal the mortgage-related panic.
The ECB and the Fed injected respectively €95 billion and $24 billion into the interbank market. To
alleviate the liquidity crunch, the Fed also reduced the discount rate to 5.75 percent and extended both
the type of collateral that banks could post and the horizon for lending facilities on August 17. All the
same, banks were reluctant to borrow at the Fed’s discount window because of the negative signals
about their creditworthiness on the interbank market. This fear for a stigma was not a new
phenomenon as it already existed at the times of the Great Depression. On September 18, the federal
7
Repos, are repurchase agreements that allow market participants to obtain collateralized funding by selling
securities with the agreement to repurchase them when the loan matures.
40
funds rate was reduced to 4.75 percent and the discount rate set on 5.25 percent. Meanwhile, the ECB
chose not to change its rates in light of the high inflation forecasts showing strong commitment to its
price stability mandate, but government interventions in Britain and Germany were required to save
respectively Northern Rock and IKB from closing down.
While downgrading of conduits continued, banks succeeded in cleaning their books through writedowns of mortgage-related securities. The relief was only temporary; in November 2007 it became
clear that the total estimated loss in the mortgage sector of $200 billion was too low, forcing additional
larger write-downs on banks’ balance sheets. Interest rate spreads peaked again in December (see
Figure 12). The Fed responded with a further cut in the funds rate of 0.25 percentage points but it was
clear lower rates alone were not effective in helping banks out of the liquidity crunch. The Term
Auction Facility (TAF) was announced, through which commercial banks could bid anonymously for
loans against a broad range of collateral, including some MBSs (Brunnermeier, 2008, p. 14). Although
the lending effect was basically the same as the use of the discount window, the ‘anonymous’ aspect
of the TAF made it more successful in reanimating the interbank lending.
In summary, uncertainty about the subprime collateral triggered runs on the SIVs, seriously affecting
the liquidity and solvability of banks through the use of credit lines. The first writing-downs of 2007
further decreased asset prices and liquidity problems spilled over to other financial companies like
insurers, pension funds and hedge funds. Financial institutions stopped trusting each other, leading to a
halt in the functioning of the money markets and worldwide crashes on the stock exchange. Central
banks addressed it like a liquidity problem but matters would worsen even beyond the completely stop
of the credit markets’ functionality and the thousands of people that lost their homes and their jobs. In
2008 an even more dangerous systemic collapse forced central banks to rapidly reinvent themselves as
‘market-maker of last resort’, providing help to banks in the form of the new liquidity that is used in
modern financial markets, the collateral based assets.
3.5.2 Financial Panic of 2008 ‘The Perfect Storm’
House prices continued declining, defaults continued rising and banks were deleveraging and dumping
their assets to meet capital requirements. Given the inability to get funding from the distressed money
markets, central banks tried to help but they did not accept all collateral and could attach conditions.
Also uncertainty about the exact valuation of derivatives remained as there was no history available
about declining house prices; the existing accounting models were not accurate anymore. In this
environment the ‘subprime panic’ contaminated other products, markets and countries.
41
Table 8: The Perfect Storm of 2008
January
Fed 'Emergency Cut'
March
Run on Bear Stearns
September
Conservatorship Fannie and Freddie
Bank of America takes over Merrill Lynch
Lehman Brothers files for bankruptcy
AIG receives financial support
October
700 billion rescue package U.S. (Troubled Asset Relief Program TARP)
ECB starts cutting interest rates
Commercial Paper Funding Facility (CPFF)
Europe increases deposit guarantees and capital injections
Obama wins Presidential Elections
G-20
December
Federal Funds Rate at 0,25 percent
Early 2008 the worries of investors shifted to the insurance sector, after the rating agency Fitch
downgraded one of the ‘monoline insures’. Monoline insures were specified in insuring one product
against default, mostly municipal bonds, in order to guarantee AAA-ratings. In the past years they also
extended guarantees to MBSs and other structured products. Fitch, Moody’s and Standards Poor put
monoline insurers on downgrade reviews when the losses in the mortgage sector increased, implying
the loss of AAA-rating for a wide range of bonds (including low risk municipal and corporate bonds).
Besides the obvious negative effects for the bondholders, these funds promise to maintain the value of
every dollar invested (or never to ‘break the buck’), and so they could ask underwriters of assets to
buy back the assets if needed. An important condition for this is the AAA-rating of these assets.
Intuitively, the downgrade would have triggered an enormous asset sell-off by money market funds
(Brunnermeier, 2008, p. 18). This danger induced the Fed to an ‘emergency cut’ of 0.75 percentage
point in its funds rate on January 22. Due to the persistent drops in equity markets around the world,
the funds rate was again reduced during the regular FOMC on January 30, to 3 percent.
Early March the investment bank Bear Stearns was hit by a run and being considered too
interconnected to fail, everything was done by the Fed to minimize counterparty risk. In the end,
JPMorgan Chase acquired the bank paying $10 for shares that just a year before were worth about
$150, and agreed to assume the first $1 billion of losses. Equity holders of Bear Stearns lost almost
everything, but the debt-holders were saved from losses.
42
Mortgage delinquencies continued rising in the subsequent months causing even problems for the
government-sponsored, publicly traded enterprises. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, who were
institutions that securitized a large fraction of U.S. mortgages, saw their stock prices fall until they had
to be put in federal conservatorship on September 7. Given the $1.5 trillion in bonds outstanding this
government intervention also resulted in a ‘credit event’, for a large number of people that had bought
CDSs now were receiving the payments (Brunnermeier, 2008, p. 16).
This liquidity increase not only was not able to prevent the panic that would follow in the fall of 2008,
it probably even intensified it, because in the meantime the unsustainability of the financial situation
was not yet acknowledged and the risky business continued. At some point, the government and the
Fed could not bail-out or help troubled institutions anymore. Even if they wanted to, it required
exaggerated amounts of money and the range of institutions that fell under the scope of systemic risk
reached far beyond the mere commercial bank sector. If the Fed still wanted to be a credible guardian
of price stability, a halt was necessary.
When Lehman Brothers filed for bankruptcy on September 15, after the failed tentative of rescue, it
triggered a ‘perfect storm’ that materialized the true risk of a global financial collapse like was not
seen since the Great Depression years. Lehman had narrowly survived the trouble in March that was
fatal for Bear Stearns, but did not succeed in strengthening its balance sheet enough in the meantime to
face future critical moments. When Lehman’s share price plunged, no other bank was willing to take it
over without a form of government guarantee. The government decided not to offer a guarantee
because Lehman and its relations, clients and counterparties, had had enough time to protect
themselves from liquidity problems.
This loaded decision probably was driven by future moral hazard and market discipline problems, but
it generated panic on the global financial markets and a run on repos. Meanwhile, Merrill Lynch had
sold itself to Bank of America in anticipation of problems of the Lehman sort, and AIG revealed
having serious liquidity shortage problems. Being a large internationally operating insurance company
highly active in the credit derivatives, the Federal Reserve organized a bailout of $85 billion that
would be extended further in October and November with $37 billion and $40 billion respectively. In
exchange the Fed’s would retain 80 percent of the AIG shares.
According to Brunnermeier (2008, p. 19) the effects of Lehman’s demise worldwide were first, large
losses at money market funds; second, a surge in prices of CDSs as banks tried to protect themselves
against counterparty risk; third, a sharp fall in financial non asset-backed commercial paper. To this
the Fed responded with the introduction of the Commercial Paper Funding Facility, while the U.S.
Treasury set aside $ 80 billion to guarantee brokers’ money market funds.
43
On September 19, 2008, a $700 billion financial industry bail-out plan was proposed by the U.S.
Treasury. Among other things it purchased mortgage assets, helped foreclosing homeowners and
coordinated recapitalization of banks. In Europe similar government guarantees on interbank lending
were introduced, additional government capital injections for troubled financial institutions were given
and deposit guarantee schemes were raised to prevent people from withdrawing their savings from
banks. Also the ECB gradually cut its interest rates. If the Fed’s funds rate now ranges between 0 and
0.5 percent, also the ECB reached its historically lowest level of 1 percent. Nevertheless, credit
markets continued to deteriorate in the following weeks and panic on the stock markets persisted,
pulling the world in a recession.
Although the traditional banking crises now were not the element bringing systemic risk, the systemic
risk was on the interbank lending through the run on SIVS and later on the repo markets. In order to
avoid the last similarity with the financial crises that preceded the Great Depression, policymakers are
focussing on preventing debt deflation.
3.6 Recovery
Table 9 gives a simplified chronology of the past year. Starting from January 2009 the world was
officially in a recession as the negative effects of the crisis affected the real sector through several
channels. For example through the credit channel, as the process of deleveraging of banks restricts
credit conditions to households and firms; through welfare effects, due to stock related losses and
decreasing asset prices (especially house values); and the expectations channel as over optimism
turned into over pessimism. These were some of the reasons for monetary authorities and governments
to quickly pass laws aimed at stabilizing the economy as much as possible despite potential dangerous
consequences for the future.
Table 9: The Path to Recovery 2009
January
World in recession
May
ECB rate at 1 percent
June
ECB lends 442 billion euro to banks
Obama announces financial reforms, more power to the Fed
November
Basel announces stricter rules for 2012
December
House approves Reform Bill
44
In response to the crisis also central banks have not handled conventionally by applying both credit
and quantitative easing. With credit easing the central bank starts to buy long term government bonds
to push up the prices and influence long term yields. For example the Fed is buying commercial paper
for his purpose. The downward pressure on the interest rate is intended as an incentive to economic
growth and credit issuing, but these actions may turn into losses for the central bank that in the end
will come to the taxpayer. The semi-fiscal central bank actions furthermore, endanger its independent
position and its credibility in fostering price stability on the long run. With quantitative easing, central
banks simply provide more liquidity to oil markets and help banks in giving more credit to private
agents.
To conclude, both expansionary fiscal and monetary policies helped preventing deflation and the total
collapse of the financial system. In this, policymakers were helped by more advanced macroeconomic
models and tools that estimated the impact of the credit crunch in order to understand what funds were
needed to restore the economy to its full potential level. A central issue however remains the exit
strategy and prevention of a future crisis. Once the markets are stable again, the expansionary policy
needs to be pulled back or else we will again incur the danger of new bubbles arising from excess
liquidity. Despite the critics and the room for improvements, like the liquidity risk and counterparty
risk assessments that were embarrassingly inadequate in the ‘perfect storm’ of 2008, the regulatory
framework remains an important and necessary element for international coordination on the global
financial markets. The Basel Committee is already working on more adequate rules to deal with the
changed financial world. The other form of prevention could come from macroeconomic perspective.
As we have witnessed counter-cyclical policy alone may not be a sufficiently strong tool to mitigate
irrational price increases. In their book Animal Spirits, Akerlof and Shiller describe how the current
and past crises were the result of psychological and social factors rather than rational behaviour.
According to them, a positive economic boom may transform itself in a speculative bubble because of
several feedback mechanisms, more or less driven by animal spirits. For example the price-to-price
feedback, which is the movement of price in the same direction due to future price expectations
creating a vicious cycle, and the feedback between the asset prices in the bubble and the real economy
(2009, pp. 134-135). The new frontiers of macro prudential regulation are on studying and controlling
both positive and negative feedbacks. A greater role for psychology and behavioural economics at this
point can no longer be postponed.
45
4. Conclusion
All financial crises follow a similar path in which different stages can be distinguished. They usually
start with a mismanaged innovation and credit boom that turns into a speculative bubble which
eventually will explode when a negative shock hits the real economy, for example the end of a
business cycle. In an environment of over optimism and overvalued assets, people tend to forget past
bubbles and do not rationally weigh the true risk attached to their investment decisions. When
uncertainty arises and the true risk is acknowledged, over optimism suddenly turns into over
pessimism and panic reactions. Asset prices decline and bank’s balance sheets worsen, possibly
triggering bank runs and further fire sales in order to solve liquidity and solvability issues.
The deleveraging financial system and the increasing interest rates then reverse the credit boom into a
credit crunch, further aggravating the problems in the real economy. Both positive and negative
feedback mechanism move the stock and financial markets, rather than rational behavior. If authorities
do not intervene to solve these market failures, deflationary pressures (or declining prices) turn into a
recession (declining output) and in the worst case a depression, like happened in the 1930s.
The Great Depression laid the foundations for macroeconomic theory and the regulatory framework
for the financial sector. Their continued development through the years improved monetary and fiscal
policy to such an extent that it became possible to effectively safeguard economic equilibrium and
financial stability, peaking in the Great Moderation. The present credit crunch has been for many an
unexpected awaking from a nice dream, namely the belief the key to stable growth was found forever
just by letting markets work freely. The truth is, these theories are based on rational behavior of
economic agents and do not take into account the fact that market imperfections are always behind the
corner. In this case, the financial innovations led to shadow banking which largely exposed the
financial sector to excessive risk taking and asymmetric information problems. By finding loopholes
in the regulation, banks were able to bypass the supervisor’s credit requirements and provide supply
for the growing, irrational demand for collateralized debt products.
The historical, institutional and macroeconomic backgrounds of the 1930s and the recent years are
very different from each other and for some aspects even the opposite. Interestingly, the fear for
hyperinflation of the 1920 versus the fear for deflation around the new millennium shaped an
environment of respectively hidden structural deflation and structural inflation which policymakers
did not counteract sufficiently. Another difference is the turbulent political and economic environment
of the 1920s in comparison to the political stability and the Great Moderation of the recent years. Last
but not least, the banking system has changed a lot from the traditional originate-to-hold model into
46
the more modern originate-to-distribute model. The screen and monitor incentives are very different,
nevertheless, in both periods the world experienced a substantial credit boom that turned into a
financial panic with systemic risk, and in the case of the Great Depression due to inadequate
intervention, the financial system was allowed to collapse.
Although counter-cyclical policies now still form the base of the most prominent responses to the
recession, the Keynesian framework is confronted with big flaws; the absence of the consequences of
dysfunctional financial markets for the general equilibrium and the understanding of business cycle
movements. We must bear in mind that bubbles in the future cannot be completely prevented because
they are intrinsic to the irrational human behavior that drives markets. Another fundamental problem
is that regulation lags behind. More knowledge about how financial markets move could be found by
studying the psychological and social reasons behind investment decisions. Especially now
securitization made funding liquidity more and more based on collateral, understanding further the
price movements of these underlying assets has become essential to safeguard future financial stability.
It is too early to fully understand all the effects of the 2007-2008 financial panics and to evaluate the
related policy decisions. The financial sector and the real economy are still far away from the stable
equilibrium and we are not out of the danger zone yet. For now however, it is possible to draw a few
lessons. First, the focus should not be on eliminating the financial innovations, which furthermore
have the beneficial side of increasing efficiency on the capital markets, but enriching our science about
asset price movements and adjusting the regulatory framework to the vast, modern financial markets.
Like happened in the 1920s, we are facing again important structural changes albeit in the financial
sector this time. If before the Great Depression the boom was fed by mass consumption of durables,
now the boom was fed by mass consumption of debt products. Like then, the solution is not the
elimination of the innovations that led to economic boom, but to revise and update theories and
regulations to safeguard the financial system and to foster future stability.
Secondly, regulation and supervision must be extended in order to comprise all aspects of financial
markets, not merely traditional banks and deposits, which now are only a minimal part of the financial
business. Securitization gave rise to a new form of liquidity, collateralized debt products, of which the
shortage could not be solved by central banks with existing instruments. Also, different (non-bank)
financial institutions operate without having to meet credit requirements, while they seriously may
destabilize the system due to their interconnections. Working in this direction, central banks updated
their ‘lender of last resort’ role during becoming also ‘market makers of last resort’, while the Basel
Committee is already working on higher capital requirements for the future and probably other
changes as well. For example, SIVs should also meet capital requirements and incentives to screen and
monitor must be restored. The role of rating agencies must also be reconsidered given their
47
responsibility in this crisis; models that calculate risk must again include the systemic event, and risk
management of banks cannot be outsourced to external firms.
A third lesson is to apply the exit strategy on time. This is a delicate step however because of the
negative effects a premature stop of economic recovery may have, before the stabilization phase is
complete. On the other hand, the exit strategy is also crucial to minimize future moral hazard problems
in the financial sector. A final lesson from the Great Depression, is when the United States had
sufficient gold reserves to implement the expansionary policy needed to get out of the depression and
drag along the rest of the world, but instead waited too long for Britain to act as financial stabilizator.
Now, the ‘surplus’ countries have the sufficient reserves but continue to play a minor role on the
international decision making process. The United States are expected to solve the global recession,
but the country already is indebted and may not be able to supply the funds needed. To safeguard
macroeconomic stability we should recognize in time, the shifting global economic and political
powers.
In summary, the Great Depression provided useful lessons because it permitted to avoid a collapse and
will hopefully prevent a depression. The actual crisis could not have been prevented exclusively on the
basis of what we learned from the 1930s because of the underlying features of speculative bubbles,
namely the irrational investment decisions and the lagging behind of even the most sophisticated
regulations. The positive results of the institutional improvements of 1933 and 1934 for the banking
stability however, give hope for the future stability which actual regulations for a broader range of
financial institutions may have.
48
5. References
Akerlof, G.A. and R.J. Shiller (2009). Animal Spirits. How Human Psychology Drives the Economy,
and Why It Matters for Global Capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Bean, C. (2009). The Great Moderation, the Great Panic and the Great Contraction. Schumpeter
Lecture at Annual Congress of the European Economic Association, Barcelona, August.
Bernanke, B.S. and H. James (1990). The Gold Standard, Deflation, and Financial Crisis in the Great
Depression: An International Comparison. NBER Working Paper Nr. 3488. Cambridge:
National Bureau of Economic Research.
Bernanke, B.S. (2000). Essays on the Great Depression. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Brunnermeier, M.K. (2008). Deciphering the Liquidity and Credit Crunch 2007-08. NBER Working
Paper Nr. 14612. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Buiter, W.H. (2008). Central Banks and Financial Crises. Paper presented at the Federal Reserve
Bank of Kansas City’s Symposium, August.
ECB (2005). The New Basel Capital Accord: Main Features and Implications. ECB Monthly Bulletin,
January.
Friedman, M. and A. Jacobson Schwartz (2008). The Great Contraction 1929-1933. Princeton:
Princeton University Press
Gorton, G.B. (2008). The Panic of 2007. NBER Working Paper Nr. 14538. Cambridge: National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Gorton, G.B. (2009). Slapped in the Face by the Invisible Hand. Prepared for the Federal Reserve
Bank of Atlanta ‘s 2009 Financial Market Conference: Financial Innovation and Crisis, May.
Homer S. and R. Sylla (2005). A History of Interest Rates. Fourth Edition. Hoboken: John Wiley &
Sons.
49
Hoogduin, L. (2009). Monetary Economics and Financial Institutions Mastercourse. Lecture Notes.
Amsterdam: Universiteit van Amsterdam.
Kindleberger, C.P. (1986). The World in Depression, 1929-1939. London: University of California
Press.
Mishkin, F.S. (1990). Asymmetric Information and Financial Crises: An Historical Perspective.
NBER Working Paper Nr. 3400. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Mishkin, F.S. (2010). The Economics of Money, Banking and Financial Markets. Ninth Edition.
Pearson Education.
Mitchener, K.J. (2004). Bank Supervision, Regulation, and Instability during the Great Depression.
NBER Working Paper Nr. 10475. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Taylor, J.B. (2007). Housing and Monetary Policy. NBER Working Paper Nr. 13682. Cambridge:
National Bureau of Economic Research.
The U.S. Economy in the 1920s. (2009). In EH.Net Encyclopedia. Retrieved July 8, 2009, from
http://eh.net/node
50