* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Examining the Effects of Currency Depreciation on Trade Balance in
Development theory wikipedia , lookup
International monetary systems wikipedia , lookup
Heckscher–Ohlin model wikipedia , lookup
Currency War of 2009–11 wikipedia , lookup
Exchange rate wikipedia , lookup
Economic globalization wikipedia , lookup
Fear of floating wikipedia , lookup
Internationalization wikipedia , lookup
International factor movements wikipedia , lookup
Balance of payments wikipedia , lookup
International Journal of Global Business, 7 (1), 59-76, June 2014 59 Examining the Effects of Currency Depreciation on Trade Balance in Selected Asian Economies Alemu, Aye Mengistu Assistant Professor, SolBridge International School of Business, Daejeon, South Korea. [email protected] Jin-sang, Lee Specialist Professor, Duksung Women’s University, Seoul, South Korea. [email protected] Abstract The aim of this study is to investigate how depreciation could affect the export sector in selected Asian countries. Theoretically, depreciation will bring positive impact on trade balance. However, it is only possible when the sum of the elasticities of demand for export commodities and demand for import goods is greater than unity. Accordingly, this study found no evidence for the effect of depreciation to improve trade balance of about 14 Asian economies. This was perhaps due to the fact that exports did not respond as expected, mainly due to a decline in terms of trade for primary commodities and manufactured products or due to heavy dependence on import goods which may be more expensive in the local currency. As a second approach, we attempted to narrow down the number of countries understudy into 8 countries that are relatively bigger, industrialized and stable, and in this case we found that depreciation improved trade balance. Keywords: devaluation, trade balance, export, Marshall-Lerner condition, J-curve effect International Journal of Global Business, 7 (1), 59-76, June 2014 60 Introduction Theoretically, depreciation of a local currency is good for the export sector, ceteris paribus, it would increase competitiveness of export goods in foreign markets. On the other hand, it would cause higher level of import price. The higher import price could bring inflationary pressure especially those who import a lot of industrial needs, energy resources and consumer goods. Hence, the overall economic impact of depreciation will not be easy to conclude. Many Asian economies are heavily engaged in imported energy resources like oil and gas, natural resources, and many economies are focusing on export promotion. Therefore, it is worthwhile to look at the consequences of devaluation. The exchange rate in a given economy often plays a prominent role than the interest rate in the transmission mechanism of monetary policy (Vitale, 2003). Especially for developing countries, it has been assumed that depreciation is an appropriate macroeconomic fundamental to support the export sector.1 In these regards, higher exports and lower imports will increase the trade surplus of a country and also increases the aggregate demand (AD) and it is likely to allow higher level of the real GDP. This implies that there are two elements to be noted on devaluation and the impact of trade balance. Firstly, we suppose that a country has export potential, and depreciation has the price elastic for export goods in foreign markets. Secondly, we also assume that depreciation is supported by sound macroeconomic fundamentals and can maintain competitiveness in foreign markets i.e. the economy has capacity to produce more output for export. 1 Depreciation with the floating exchange rate system and devaluation in a fixed exchange rate system mean a fall in the value of the domestic currency against foreign hard currencies. International Journal of Global Business, 7 (1), 59-76, June 2014 61 Although economic theory suggests the above scenarios with respect to the impact of devaluation on trade balance and economic growth, the results from empirical research is inconclusive and even sometimes devaluation would bring negative impact on trade balance. Some studies show that there should be a set of necessary conditions on the size of import demand, export demand and supply elasticities of devaluation. This can be interpreted from two different aspects. Firstly, the elasticity of demand for exports and imports is price inelastic, and the reduced price of export goods abroad would lead to only a small increase in quantity sold. Hence, the total amount of exports may be reduced. Furthermore, the impact of the devaluation may require some time to adjust in the real economy. In the short run, the demand for export goods in foreign markets may be inelastic, but as time goes on, the demand for goods become price elastic in the long run, and hence bring greater impact to the export sector. Secondly, the state of the global economy could affect the export sector. When the global economy is in recession, depreciation may not bring much impact on the demand for export goods abroad and vice versa. With these uncertain consequences of devaluation, this study attempts to analyze the effects of devaluation on trade balances among 14 Asian economies between 1990 and 2012. The first group consists of 14 countries including large economies with some export driven relatively small economies.2 For the second group of countries, we excluded relatively small economies and used 8 countries.3 Figure 1 shows that the annual average trade balance of 14 Asian economies since 1990. China, Korea Republic, Indonesia, Malaysia and Singapore experienced trade surplus while countries such as Bangladesh, India, Pakistan, Philippines, Sri Lanka, Vietnam, Thailand and 2 This group of countries includes China, South Korea, Hong Kong China, Vietnam, Philippines, Indonesia, Singapore, Burnei, Malaysia, Thailand, Sri Lanka, Bangladesh, India and Pakistan 3 The second group includes China, South Korea, Hong Kong China, Vietnam, Singapore, India, Malaysia, Indonesia and Malaysia. International Journal of Global Business, 7 (1), 59-76, June 2014 62 Hong Kong China were experiencing huge trade deficits regardless of currency depreciation in their respective countries. Hong Kong China has a large share of income originated from trade brokerage which caused trade deficit in the current account whereas surplus in the capital account. This is possible with the openness of the Hong Kong economy that stimulates the free movement of portfolio investment from developed economies. Figure 1. The Average Trade Balance of Asian Economies (1990-2012) in Millions of US $ 100000 82409 80000 60000 40000 17471 20000 11021 16675 11815 3222 0 -4228 -20000 -6929 -7177 -2669 -1376 -4627 -17640 -40000 -43052 -60000 Source: UNCTAD Hand Book of Statistics, 2013 After the Chinese government started open door policy in the later part of 1970s, China was focusing on the promotion of manufacturing export goods and also encouraged foreign direct investment. The Chinese yuan has been kept relatively low relative to foreign hard currencies though there were pressures of appreciation from other countries notably the USA. Consequently, China has been experiencing trade surplus for a considerable time period. India, on the other hand, has been experiencing trade deficit for more than a couple of decades. The value of Indian rupee International Journal of Global Business, 7 (1), 59-76, June 2014 63 has been fluctuating and devaluation could not bring sufficient impact to the export sector. This is because the Indian economy is heavily dependent upon imported energy and industrial goods. Moreover, Indian export products are not competitive and the price inelastic in foreign markets. Other countries such as Indonesia, Malaysia and Burnei are largely focused on primary export and limited demand for imports. Korea is one of the most successful economies driven by the export sector. The country achieved technology progress and focused on exporting industrial products that are very competitive in external markets. The exchange rate of Korea is very sensitive in foreign markets. Though Korea imports almost all industrial raw materials and energy, the country has been experienced elastic demand for export goods abroad. Other countries are experiencing export promotion, but with limited export commodities which are rather focused on labor intensive and lower technology production. These products are less price elastic compared with more sophisticated consumer goods in foreign markets. Other than currency devaluation, this study also investigates the effects of other factors that may cause changes in trade surplus from one country to another country. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section II provides theoretical background of the impact of devaluation. Section III brings model specification, estimation methods and data sources. Section IV presents the results of empirical analysis and main findings and section V brings concluding remarks. Theoretical Background The classical approach of devaluation could remedy trade deficit that entails domestic expenditure as imported goods tend to become more expensive than domestic products, and domestic products will be cheaper in abroad. Hence, these shifts contribute to reduce the domestic absorption and International Journal of Global Business, 7 (1), 59-76, June 2014 64 hence could ease trade deficit. Accordingly, it is expected that devaluation would lead to improve in trade balance in the long-run (Agbola 2004, Rawlins and Praveen, 2000; Musila and Newark, 2003; Bahmani-Oskoee and Ratha, 2004). Another theory of devaluation states that trade balance has been also rooted in a particular solution of the BRM condition, known as the Marshall-Lerner condition (Marshall, 1923; Lerner, 1944; Bahmani-Oskooee and Niroomand, 1998). This condition states that devaluation brings a positive effect on trade when the sum of the demand elasticities for exports and imports must exceed unity. More specifically, the Marshal-Lerner Condition assumes that if εx and εm denote the elasticities of export and import respectively, then we reach to the following prepositions: a. If εx + εm > 1, the devaluation of home currency would improve trade balance. b. If εx + εm = 1, the devaluation of home currency will make no difference to the trade balance. c. If εx + εm < 1, , the devaluation of home currency will deteriorate the trade balance. Similarly, empirical studies such as Junz and Rhomberg (1973) shows that devaluation may cause a negative impact on trade balance in the short run but improve in the long run; that is, the trade balance followed a time path which looked like the letter “J”. Nguyen(1993) and BahmaniOskoeee and Xu(2013) also proved that depreciation brings adverse effect on trade balance in the short run. The main explanation for the J-curve would be exchange rate could adjust instantaneously, but there is a time lag as consumers and producers need to adjust to changes in demand for and supply of goods.4 4 However, Rose and Yellen(1989) examined that the J-curve was not statistically significant in the case of the USA. International Journal of Global Business, 7 (1), 59-76, June 2014 65 In the import sector, depreciation could raise the domestic price of imported goods. This will bring consumers substitute imported goods into domestic products. However, this substitution is relied on the availability of similar domestically produced goods as well as the time period subsequent to the depreciation (Edwards and Willcox, 2003). For that circumstance, many developing economies are tending to import intermediate goods such as oil and capital goods. These economies are lacking a wide range of substitutes for imported products implying a highly inelastic import demand function. Even if substitutes are available, “lags in recognition of the changed situation, in the decision to change real variables, in delivery time, in the replacement of inventories and materials, and in production” give rise to an inelastic demand curve in the short run (Magee, 1973). In these results, devaluation raises the price level of import goods that may persist even in the long run. In the export side, as we mentioned earlier, devaluation lowers the price of export goods abroad. The depreciation is passed on to foreign consumers in the form of lower foreign currency prices of exports (their imports) depends on the elasticities of export supply and demand. This leads to the Marshall-Lerner condition which states that devaluation is only viable when the sum of price elasticities of exports and imports (in absolute value) is greater than unity. This implies that if export goods are price elastic in foreign markets, their quantity demanded will increase proportionately more than the decrease in price, and total export revenue will increase. Similarly, if import goods are price elastic, total import expenditure will decrease. In both cases trade balance will be improved. Empirically, it has been found that trade in goods tends to be inelastic in the short term, and it takes time to change consuming patterns and trade contracts (Bahmani-Oskoee and Ratha, 2004). This condition will be fulfilled in the short run when import and export demand curves are inelastic. However, in the long run, the volume of exports may start to rise because their International Journal of Global Business, 7 (1), 59-76, June 2014 66 export goods would be competitive in foreign markets, and also domestic consumers may switch to domestic goods rather than import ones. Eventually, the trade balance will improve and bring positive impact to the real economy. If there is a currency appreciation, with the same reason it can induce an inverted J-curve. In fact, it is obvious that following devaluation, the volume of imports and exports may remain largely unchanged due in part to pre-existing trade contract that have to be honored. Moreover, in the short run, demand for expensive import goods and supply of export goods remain price inelastic. This is due to time lags in the consumer's choice for acceptable and cheaper alternatives. The notion that devaluation stimulates exports and curtails import is not always acceptable in all circumstances. For instance, Abeysinghe and Yeok (1998) empirically investigated the impact of currency appreciation on exports in the case of Singapore, and found that with the presence of high level of import and exports are not adversely affected by currency appreciation. Accordingly, Singapore is a particularly interesting case study as the country has been experiencing sustained export growth despite of appreciation. With these different consequences of devaluation, opponents of the classical view are not optimistic about the effect of currency devaluation to improve trade balance. In fact, most of the structuralists argue that nominal devaluation leads to contractionary demand for output. Thus, devaluation may bring an ambiguous effect on trade balance at least in the short-run. Consequently, policy makers in developing countries find difficulty to decide the types of exchange rate regime. Model Specification, Estimation Methods and Data Sources Apart from the exchange rate regime, there are many other factors that would affect trade balance. For instance, the degree of openness of the economy could be related to foreign trade. It is also International Journal of Global Business, 7 (1), 59-76, June 2014 67 sensitive in the flow of foreign capital and hence affect the balance of payment with capital account like what is happening in Hong Kong China. The level of industrial development of the country will also matter to the export sector. If a country has advanced industrial structure, there is a tendency of higher level of elasticity of demand for export commodities abroad. Hence, it would be closely related to the country’s level of manufacturing capacity. There are some other factors that would affect trade balance such as inflation, lending interest rate, the population size and physical infrastructure of the country as these will have paramount effect on trade. Figure 2 summarizes a theoretical model for the effects of devaluation and other control variables on trade balance. Figure 2. Theoretical Model for the Effects of “Devaluation” and Other Control Variables on Trade Balance Exchange Rate (+) Income Per Capita (+/-) Trade Balance Manufacturing Export/Total Merchandise Export (+) Inflation (-) Lending Interest Rate (-) Degree of Openness (+) Population Size (+) Physical Infrastructure (+) Model Specification and Estimation Methods Based on earlier empirical studies and theoretical explanations, the effect of currency devaluation and other control variables on trade balance (TB) in a given economy can be specified as flows: TBit=β0+β1CDit+β2 Openit +β3 IPCit+Zit +εit International Journal of Global Business, 7 (1), 59-76, June 2014 68 Where; TB refers to trade balance, CD refers to devaluation, Open refers the openness, IPC refers to income per capita which captures the level of development of the country, Zit represents the set of other control variables including physical infrastructure, etc., as mentioned in Table 2; i indexes the country under study, t denotes the year, and εit is the idiosyncratic errors. Thus, the model takes both the cross-section dimension and the time-series dimensions into consideration. In doing so, test for heteroscedasticity was conducted using the Breusch-Pagan test and the nullhypothesis of homoscedasticity was rejected at 1% significance level, implying there is strong evidence of heteroskedasticity in which the error variance is not constant and needs to be corrected using robust standard errors. Likewise, the test for serial correlation for the error terms was conducted using Wooldridge test for autocorrelation in panel data and the result yields a p-value of 0.5761, that implies there is no evidence of serial correlation (first order autocorrelation) and hence the error terms are not correlated. Apparently, a specification test has been conducted to determine which estimation methods would be more appropriate for this study. According to Gujarati (2003), there is a formal test that will help to choose between the fixed effect model (FEM) and the random effect model (REM). Accordingly, Hausman (1978) test has been conducted and the null hypothesis was not rejected. Hence, the REM is much appropriate for this study. In addition to the REM, this study also used the feasible general least square (FGLS) with corrected heteroscedasticity standard errors so as to check the consistency of the results. In fact, heteroscedastic models are usually fitted with the FGLS regression since the estimates assume that the disturbances are heteroscedastic. In line with this, the variables, their expected effects on trade balance, and data sources are shown in Table 1. International Journal of Global Business, 7 (1), 59-76, June 2014 69 Table 1. Variables, Their Expected Signs and Data Sources Variable Indicator Trade Balance Trade Balance in Million USD$ +/- Data Sources UNCTAD Hand Book of Statistics Exchange Rate Official exchange rate of each + WDI country’s currency against USD$ Income Per Capita Income Per Capita (PPP) + WDI MEX/TME Ratio of MEX/TMEX + WDI Inflation Index (Based on CPI) + WDI Lending Interest Rate Lending Interest rate + WDI Population Size (log) Number of Population + WDI Degree of Openness Trade/GDP + WDI Physical Infrastructure Telephone/100 people + WDI Empirical Results and Main Findings Results from the Whole Sample The empirical results using the REM and the FGLS estimation methods with heteroscedasticity corrected standard errors are presented in Table 2. Accordingly, the empirical results revealed that the effect of currency devaluation on trade balance in selected Asian economies was found to be statistically insignificant. In other words, no evidence was found for devaluation to boost trade balance. This was perhaps due to the fact that exports did not respond as expected, mainly due to a decline in terms of trade for primary commodities and manufactured products or due to heavy dependence on imported inputs. When trade volumes do not respond to exchange-rate changes, the trade balance moves in the “wrong” direction and as a result, devaluation makes the country’s trade deficits even worse at least in the short term. Moreover, it is obvious that most of the Asian International Journal of Global Business, 7 (1), 59-76, June 2014 70 economies import resources such as industrial raw materials and energy. In addition, most of those countries are highly dependent on exporting manufactured goods mainly intermediate and capital goods, and input materials for industrial needs. Table 2. Regression Results Using RE and FGLS for the Whole Sample Dependent Variable: Trade Balance Explanatory Variables Exchange Rate Income Per Capita MEX/TME Inflation Lending Interest Rate Population Size (log) Degree of Openness Physical Infrastructure Constant Number of Observations Number of Groups Time periods RE .0903 (.1589) . 1376*** (.0437) .7932*** (.2116) -.4031* (.2169) -.9986* (.5735) .2945 (11.986) .3312*** (.0788) .2039*** (.0353) -.7252.22 (916.1) 322 14 23 FGLS .0371 (.1102) .7194*** (.0494) .9242*** (.1796) -.3624*** (.1354) -.2763*** (.0425) .9807*** (.0992) .5591*** (.0664) .1901*** (.0430) -8246.7 (776.8) 322 14 23 Apart from China and India, most of emerging Asian economies countries are small in size, and there is no guarantee that trade balance can be improved via devaluation. This empirical study using both the REM and the FGLS estimation methods have found other control variables such as the country’s level of development captured by the real GDP/capita of each country, the extent how that country is dependent on manufacturing exports, degree of openness, and physical infrastructure to positively and significantly influence trade balance in a given country. For International Journal of Global Business, 7 (1), 59-76, June 2014 71 instance, the positive and significant effect of openness on trade balance is highly expected since openness to trade can enhance productivity by enabling more efficient allocation of resources. It also provide greater opportunities to achieve economies of scale. In other words, as Dobre (2008) noted, openness to trade can play an important role in raising the long-run sustainable rate of productivity growth in the economy. Likewise, better infrastructure is expected to decrease the cost of doing business in the country and consequently boosts exports as well as reducing cost of imported goods. The significant effect of the ratio of manufacturing export to total merchandise trade implies that manufactured products still have price elasticity of demand and if it is accompanied by devaluation, it can enhance trade surplus, whereas agricultural and primary exporting countries experienced price inelastic. In addition, this study reveals inflation and high lending interest rates might have negative impact on trade balance. This is due to the fact that a high rate of inflation is generally harmful to economic growth and trade balance in particular. This is due to the cost of borrowing which lowers the rate of capital investment. Furthermore, a high lending interest rate may discourage potential entrepreneurs from undertaking production and export activities as it increases the cost of capital. Results from the Sub-Sample The next attempt is excluding relatively small and non-stable economies from the first group. We excluded Bangladesh, Sri Lanka, Pakistan, Brunei, Philippines, and Vietnam and reexamined the effects of devaluation on trade balance for the remaining 8 Asian economies including China, Hong Kong, India, Indonesia, Malaysia, Korea and Singapore between 1990 and 2012. We found that devaluation has a strong positive effect to improve trade balance (Table 3). This is due to the fact that those relatively bigger and stable economies and they produce competitive export goods International Journal of Global Business, 7 (1), 59-76, June 2014 72 countries like Korea, Singapore, India and China who are producing high-tech products like computer and software, pharmaceutical and medical equipment, advanced ICT products and scientific equipment. These products are price elastic and demand will increase more than the decrease in price, and export revenue will increase. Similarly, these countries are also in a better position to produce substitute goods for domestic consumption if imported goods become expensive as a result of devaluation. Accordingly, devaluation improved trade balance in selected emerging 8 Asian economies. The empirical evidence of the sub-sample analysis in Table 3 confirms those variables such as the level of development measured in GDP/capita, the ratio of manufactured products, population size which captures the size of the domestic market, and found that devaluation enhances trade balance. The study found that there is a strong evidence that inflation and high lending interest rate may negatively affect trade balance, as they increase the cost of capital. Table 3. Regression Results Using RE and FGLS for the Sub-Sample Dependent Variable: Trade Balance Explanatory Variables RE FGLS Exchange Rate .8532*** (.2282) . 7118** (.3728) .1401*** (.0529) -.1155 (.0864) -.1853* (.1047) .2213*** (.0830) .3115* (.1897) .1907* (.1058) -.4426*** (.1724) -.8194 (3.7535) ..1893* (.0986) .3459*** (.1516) .4353* (.2377) .2082*** (.0375) .5439** (.2429) .3431** (.1501) Income Per Capita MEX/TME Inflation Lending Interest Rate Population Size (log) Degree of Openness Physical Infrastructure International Journal of Global Business, 7 (1), 59-76, June 2014 73 Constant Number of observations Number of groups Time Periods -.2324.6 (893.4) 184 8 23 -1847.4 (328.6) 184 8 23 Concluding Remarks Devaluation works through its “expenditure switching and expenditure reducing effect”. Expenditure switching works through changes in relative price of exportable and non-exportable. Devaluation is expected to increase the price of exportable relative to that of non-tradable there by shifting aggregate supply to the tradable and aggregate demand to non-tradable. Therefore, export earnings would increase and improve current account and the balance of payment. In addition to the shift in production from domestic goods (non-tradable) to tradable, the shift also occurs from import to import substitution (Guitian, 1982). Although the classical economic theory prescribes that devaluation improves trade balance, empirical evidences show that the outcome can be ambiguous or inclusive. Accordingly, the Marshal-Lerner condition proposes that the ultimate outcome of currency devaluation depends on the nation’s price elasticities of demand for exports and imports. This study attempted to analyze the effects of devaluation among 14 emerging Asian economies between 1990 and 2012. There was no strong evidence showing devaluation brings positive impacts on trade balance. From Table 1, it was evident that most Asian countries were experiencing trade deficit from time to time. Imports continued to grow more than exports after devaluation. This is because of the very strong demand for imported necessities and inelastic foreign demand for most of the exports mainly from those relatively small Asian economies. This implies that with relatively inelastic demand for exports and imports, devaluation has little or no effect in changing trade balance. International Journal of Global Business, 7 (1), 59-76, June 2014 74 To further discussion, we attempted to exclude those relatively small and unstable Asian economies such as Pakistan, Bangladesh, Sri Lanka, Brunei, Vietnam and Philippines from the sample, and we analyzed the effects of devaluation on trade balance for 8 relatively bigger and stable economies. This group includes Korea, China, India, Hong Kong, Singapore, Malaysia, Indonesia and Thailand. With this group of countries, it was confirmed that devaluation significantly contributed to trade balance. The rationale behind the positive impact of devlauation might have been because of their relatively large and stable Asian economies with strong competitive manufacturing sector. This is very difference from those who are focusing on exporting agricultural and primary products, and imports intermediate and capital goods. In addition to devaluation, this study also found strong evidence for other variables such as the level of development measured in GDP/capita, the ratio of manufactured products, population for the market size, that influence trade balance. Likewise, the study found a strong evidence for inflation and high lending interest rate to negative affect on trade balance. References Abeysinghe, Tilak and Yeok, Tan Lin. (1998). “Exchange Rate Appreciation and Export Competitiveness: The Case of Singapore.” Applied Economics, 30(1), 51-55. Agbola, F.W. (2004) “Does devaluation improve Ghana’s trade balance? Contributed paper presented at the International Conference on Ghana’s Economy, MPlaza Hotel, Accra, Ghana, 18-20 July. Bahmani-Oskooee, M. and Niroomand, F. (1998). “Long-run price elecsticities and the Marshall- International Journal of Global Business, 7 (1), 59-76, June 2014 75 Lerner condition revisited”. Economic Letters, 61, 101-109. Bahmani-Oskooee, M. and Artatrana, R. (2004). The J-Curve: A Literature Review. Applied Economics, 36, 1377-1398. Bahmani-Oskooee, M. and Xu, J. (2013). “The J-Curve and Japan-China commodity trade”. Journal of Chinese Economic and Business Studies, 11, 13-28. Dobre, Claudia. (2008). “The Relation between Openness to trade and Economic Growth.” Central and Eastern European Online Library: http://wwww.ceeol.com. Edwards, L. and Willcox, O. (2003). “Exchange Rate Depreciation and the Trade Balance in South Africa,” Paper prepared for the National Treasury. Guitian, Manuel. (1982). “Economic Management and International Monetary Fund Conditionality,” in Adjustment and Financing in the Developing World: The Role of the International Monetary Fund, ed, by Tony Killick, Washington DC., 73-104. Gujarati, Damodar. (2003). Basic Econometrics. Singapore: McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. Hausman, Jerry. (1978). “Specification Tests in Econometrics.” Econometrica, 46, 1251-71. Junz, H. and Rhomberg, R. (1973). “Price Competitiveness in Export Trade among Industrial Countries,” American Economic Review, 63, 412 – 418. Lerner, A. (1944). The Economics of Control. New York, Macmillan. Magee, S. (1973). “Currency Contracts, Pass-Through and Devaluation.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No. 1, 303 – 325. Marshall, A. (1923). Money, Credit and Commerce. London, Macmillan and Co. Mattoo, Aaditya and Subramanian, Arrind.(2009). Currency Undervaluation and Sovereign International Journal of Global Business, 7 (1), 59-76, June 2014 76 Wealth Funds: A New Role for the World Trade Organization. The World Economy, Blackwell Publish, U.K. Musila, J.W. and Newark, J. (2003). Does Currency Devaluation Improve the Trade Balance in the Long-run? Evidence from Malawi. African Development Review, 15(2), 339-352. Nguyen, D.T.(1993). “The Dynamic Effect of Devaluation on the Balance of Payments of a Small Debt-Ridden Open Economy”. The Economic Record, 69, 285-94. Rawlins, G. and Praveen, J. (2000). Devaluation and the Trade Balance: The Recent Experiences of Selected African Countries, Centre for Economic Research on Africa, School of Business, Montclair State University, New Jersey, USA. Rose, A.K. and Yellen J.L. (1989). “Is there a J-curve”. Journal of Monetary Economics, 24, 53-68. Vitale, Paolo. (2003). "Foreign Exchange Intervention: How to Signal Policy Objectives and Stabilize the Economy", Journal of Monetary Economics, 50, 841-870.