* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Core, periphery, and the collapse of the interwar gold standard Peter
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Core, periphery, and the collapse of the interwar gold standard Peter Kugler, University of Basle Tobias Straumann, University of Zurich1 10 February, 2010 Abstract Building on recent research the paper reviews the collapse of the interwar gold standard. It introduces two new elements: it focuses on the difference between core and periphery and applies an ordered probit model instead of duration analysis. The results suggest that the coreperiphery difference was highly relevant and that papers neglecting this difference overstate the vulnerability of the core countries. In particular, core countries were capable of maintaining the gold standard in the face of negative GDP growth, banking crises and government instability, while countries of the periphery showed a high vulnerability in these instances. 1 Corresponding author: Tobias Straumann, University of Zurich, Institute for Research in Empirical Economics, Winterthurerstrasse 30, CH–8006 Zurich, +41 44 634 35 69, [email protected] 1 1. Introduction There is a broad consensus among economic historians that the suspension of the gold standard was a precondition for the recovery from the world economic crisis of the 1930s (Choudhri and Kochin 1980, Eichengreen and Sachs 1985, Bernanke and James 1991). Recently, this insight has led a number of scholars to study the factors explaining why some countries went off gold earlier than others (Wolf and Yousef 2007, Wandschneider 2008, Wolf 2008). Following the seminal paper of Meissner (2005) who studied the emergence of the classical gold standard in the late 19th century they have used duration analysis in order to identify the crucial factors driving the collapse of the interwar gold standard. As this kind of research is still in its infancy, there is much room for different perspectives. In this paper we introduce two new elements. First, we study the collapse of the interwar gold standard from a core-periphery perspective. Several narrative accounts have suggested that many countries of the periphery had no choice but to follow the exchange-rate policy of their main trading partners (Brown 1940, Eichengreen 1992, James 2001). Yet, nobody has tested this proposition in a systematic way. Another reason for introducing the core-periphery dimension is methodological. If core and periphery react differently, statistical analysis which does not account for the core-periphery distinction is likely to generate distorted results. In particular, the lack of differentiation may be the reason why the recent papers mentioned above come up with a rather broad set of significant variables, making it hard to see the basic mechanism behind the collapse of the interwar gold standard. It may well be that there was no such thing as a basic mechanism, but it is also clear that economic historians have not explored all statistical possibilities yet. The second new element of this paper is that we apply a different econometric method than the scholars cited above. This methodological change involves five issues. First, while 2 duration analysis relates a “change” variable (leaving the gold standard) to its potential economic and political determinants, we use a specification in which the “state” variable “being on or off the gold standard” is related to economic and political indicators. Thus, in contrast to duration analysis we use not only the data before leaving the gold standard but take into account the data after this decision. Second, we allow for a richer menu of exchange rate regimes than “being on or off the gold standard” by considering the option of capital controls with an unchanged parity as an intermediate state before leaving the gold standard and an additional restriction after going off gold. This possibility was used for instance by Eastern European countries like Czechoslovakia and Romania. These choices were probably not accidental, but were linked to basic economic factors. Therefore instead of a binary probit model we apply an ordered probit model with the four possible states “being on gold with old parity”, “imposing capital controls with old parity”, “being off gold with an official suspension or a depreciation relative to gold” and “being off gold and imposing capital controls”. Third, we introduce two new variables, namely the level of foreign debt and the denomination of the foreign debt. Bordo and Flandreau (2003) have shown that financial maturity mattered for the choice of the exchange rate regime during the era of the classical gold standard and since the demise of Bretton Woods. There are strong reasons to assume that they were equally important for the demise of the interwar gold standard. Fourth, all authors cited above pool the data for a couple of countries over time without fully taking into account the panel structure of such a macroeconomic dataset. In particular unobserved cultural and political country characteristics may strongly bias the estimates if the indicators included in the model are correlated with these unobserved characteristics. As most of the country characteristics are more or less time invariant we can represent them by a country fixed effect as a “catch all” variable. Fifth, we explicitly test for the significance of the core-periphery dimension by allowing different coefficients for these two groups of countries in our model. 3 Our results seem to confirm that it is worthwhile to introduce a distinction between core and periphery and a different methodology render. Predictably, countries of the periphery were much more vulnerable than core countries. The former responded to a decline in GDP and negative growth, diminishing gold reserves and banking crises, while core countries devalued only because gold reserves diminished and major trading partners had depreciated their currencies. In other words, peripheral countries showed little resistence to external shocks, whereas core countries were willing and able to deal with external shocks of all sorts. The devaluation of their currencies was mainly motivated by network externalities: as everybody else devalued, it became more and more costly to maintain an overvalued currency. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides a survey of the literature. Section 3 defines the core-periphery divide. Section 4 discusses the model, the choice of variables and the data. Section 5 presents the results. The paper ends with a short conclusion. 2. Survey of the literature In contrast to the classical gold standard before World War I the gold exchange standard of the interwar years had a rather short life. The system began to operate in the mid-1920s when the British government decided to restore the old monetary order by bringing sterling back to its prewar parity against the US dollar, and it ended in the first half of the 1930s when one country after another went off gold or introduced exchange controls. Yet, despite of its short duration, the interwar gold standard proved to have devastating effects. It contributed to the propagation of the great depression and prevented governments and central banks to pursue expansionary policies (Temin 1989, Eichengreen 1992, Ahamed 2009). Instead of creating a 4 stable monetary order which was supposed to foster trade and investment it acted as a major force crippling the world economy. For the sake of simplicity, we can divide this dramatic episode into four stages (table 1). In the first period (1929-30), the group of countries abandoning the gold standard was confined to countries in Oceania (Australia and New Zealand) and South America (Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay, Uruguay). In the second period (1931-32), a series of banking, debt and currency crises hit Central and Eastern Europe. Austria, Germany, Hungary, and a number of other countries in the region responded with the introduction of exchange controls. The next victim was sterling which the British government took off gold in September 1931. This shock led a series of countries to take the same step, namely India, Portugal, the Northern European countries, Japan and Canada. The major event of the third phase was the devaluation of the US dollar in April 1933. In the final phase, the so-called gold bloc, formed by Belgium, France, Italy, the Netherlands, Poland, and Switzerland at the London Economic Conference in July 1933, broke apart. Italy introduced capital controls in May 1934, Belgium devalued its currency in March 1935, Poland went off gold in April 1936, and the remaining three gold bloc countries decided to finish their experiment in September 1936. [Table 1 about here] Ever since it happened, the causes of the dramatic collapse have been intensely debated. Only recently, however, economic historians have started to use quantitative methods in order to understand why some countries abandoned the gold standard earlier than others. Simmons (1994) pioneered this kind of research. Her goal was to demonstrate that not only economic, but also institutional and political factors influenced a country’s decision to abandon the gold standard. As she was primarily interested in the political side of the gold standard, she used only a limited number of economic factors, however. Wolf and Yousef (2007), 5 Wandschneider (2008) and Wolf (2008) were the first to come with a comprehensive set of variables as well as a large country sample and to use a more dynamic model (duration analysis) instead of the rather static regression analysis. The factors tested by these authors can be divided along three types or “generations” of currency crisis models (Krugman 2000, Wolf 2008). The first type emphasizes macroeconomic imbalances, typically caused by an expansionary monetary policy. As a result, the real exchange rate appreciates to an unsustainable level, the current account balance turns negative, and central banks reserves begin to shrink. Investors, sensing the unsustainable path, precipitate the crisis by selling large amounts of domestic assets. Under the gold exchange standard of the interwar years, macroeconomic imbalances emerged because the gold standard had been restored at too high a parity, trading partners devalued or agricultural world prices declined at a faster rate than industrial ones during the crisis. Denmark, Norway and the United Kingdom restored the gold standard at the old parity at all costs, while Belgium and France deliberately fixed their exchange rate at an undervalued level. Deteriorating terms of trade due to a devaluation of a major economic power was a problem for any small open economy depending on a few export markets. Again, Denmark is a typical case as it shipped roughly two thirds of its total exports to the British market. When sterling fell in September 1931, Copenhagen had little choice (Hoffmeyer and Olsen 1968). As for the relative decline of agricultural prices, the early exit of some Latin American countries as well as Australia and New Zealand can be cited as examples. The second type of models emphasizes the self-fulfilling character of speculative attacks. Even when the exchange rate reflects the underlying economic fundamentals, investors can 6 find it attractive to attack a currency. By selling domestic assets, they force the authorities to adopt more restrictive policies, hoping that the resulting acceleration of the economic downturn will lead to a devaluation. Second-generation models also highlight contagion. When investors sense that a government began to show signs of weakness, they turn to countries that are in a similar position or have close economic relations. As for the interwar years, Eichengreen and Jeanne (2000) have shown how the British authorities were reluctant to increase interest rates to avert speculative attacks because of their concern about the growing social costs of their orthodox monetary policy. In September 1931 they threw in the towel. Contagion played a role when after the outbreak of the German crisis in the summer of 1931 investors not only began to mistrust the British pound, but also the currencies of all small countries entertaining trade relations with Germany (Straumann 2010). Third-generation models, developed after the Asian crisis, focus on the banking sector of emerging markets. Large banking conglomerates, entertaining strong ties with the government and enjoying implicit state guarantees, attract large funds of foreign short-term capital and invest them in long-term projects to further economic development. Negative new information can trigger a panic among foreign investors. Short-term funds flow out, central bank reserves dwindle, and the currency comes under strong pressure. A typical example of the 1930s is the devaluation of the Swedish krona. A commercial bank having strong ties with the liberal government used foreign short-term capital to finance the long-term plans of Ivar Kreuger, notably his credits to countries ceding him the match monopoly. When the German crisis broke out, investors withdrew their funds from Sweden causing a dramatic reduction of central bank reserves and ultimately the suspension of the gold standard in late September 1931. Testing all these possible channels and effects requires a broad range of variables. The group of real variables includes the level of GDP per capita, the growth rate of GDP, industrial 7 production, unemployment, and trade networks. The group of financial and monetary factors comprise price and interest rate differentials, central bank reserves, the creditor/debtor status and the occurrence of banking crises, and the last group assembles political and institutional factors, namely central bank independence, the inflation history, the political regime, cabinet changes, strength of parliament, and social unrest. Roughly speaking, all authors find that a whole set of factors determined the time when a country abandoned the gold standard. Wolf and Yousef find that most of the variables they tested were significant: the economic shock, the national commitment to the gold standard, the exits of major trading partners, the global adherence to gold, the perceived costs and benefits of adhering to the gold standard and political instability. Wandschneider reports that high per capita income, international creditor status, and prior hyperinflation increased the probability that the gold standard was maintained. By contrast, democratic regimes had the tendency to leave earlier than dictatorships. Furthermore, unemployment, membership in the sterling group, higher inflation, and the experience of banking crises reduced the duration of the gold standard in a particular country. Wolf’s results show that the time of exit was dependent on the extent of deflationary pressure, the existence of a banking crisis, the cover ratio, the character of the political regime (authoritarian or democratic), the independence of the central bank, the history of prior devaluations, and the patterns of trade integration. Of the three papers, only Wolf and Yousef discuss the core-periphery dimension. Their methodological approach is not convincing, however. They only estimated their model separately for core and periphery countries including only economic, credibility, network/mentality and political factors, respectively. In addition, there is no formal statistical test of the difference between core and periphery coefficients reported. Of course, this approach will provide strongly bias results, as all these four groups of factors are correlated. The full model including all these factors jointly was not estimated taking into account the 8 core/periphery dimension. Furthermore, their definition of the core is debatable as it is mainly based on GDP per capita without any further qualification.3 In other words, the core-periphery dimension still needs to be explored. Summarizing, recent empirical research on the basis of duration analysis has greatly advanced a more systematic understanding of the collapse of the interwar gold standard. However, the results are somewhat inconclusive as almost any factor has been found to be relevant. Furthermore, in some cases the findings in some cases can differ considerably. While for example Wandschneider finds that central bank independence is irrelevant, Wolf comes to the counter-intuitive conclusion that countries with a weak central bank were likely to remain longer on the gold standard than countries with a highly independent central bank. For these reasons, we have chosen a different path by applying an ordered probit model and by focussing on the difference between core and periphery. 3. Defining core and periphery There is a huge literature on the economic relevance of core and periphery, notably in the tradition of world-systems analysis. But in the field of monetary history only Flandreau and Jobst (2005) have come up with a rigorous definition. We adopt their framework developed for the period of the classical gold standard and adjust it to the new realities of the world after World War I. We also experiment with two other definitions of core and periphery, one based on international financial relations and one linked to the international political landscape. 3 The 12 core/center countries include Australia, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, France, Germany, Netherlands, New Zealand, Sweden, Switzerland, the UK and the US. The rest are coded as periphery countries. 9 The starting point of Flandreau and Jobst is the assumption that the range of circulation of a particular currency reflects the international economic position of the currency’s country. Accordingly, they draw a map of how frequently a currency was quoted in foreign markets. Their results show that the international monetary geography is best described by a three-tier system. The core consists of the three great European powers United Kingdom, Germany and France, the second intermediary group covers most of developed Europe, Russia and the United States, and the periphery regroups all the rest (Table 2). For our purpose, however, the three-tier system is too difficult to handle from a methodological standpoint. We therefore rely on a dual view which is also provided by Flandreau and Jobst. It is essentially a mix of the first and second group of the three-tier system, with only Denmark, Norway and Portugal being relegated to the periphery. On the eve of World War I, the new core is made up of eleven instead of three countries: the great European powers United Kingdom, Germany and France as well as Austria-Hungary, Belgium, Switzerland, Spain, Italy, Netherlands, Russia, and the United States (Table 2). [Table 2 about here] Unfortunately, the analysis stops in 1910 so that we lack a well defined list for the interwar years. But we think that it is possible to adapt it to the new realities by making only minor revisions on the basis of two well-informed contemporaries, namely the Swiss banker Felix Somary and the British financial journalist Paul Einzig. Both described the changes of the international monetary order after World War I (Somary 1929, Einzig 1931). There is no doubt that the two empires which collapsed towards the end of World War I, Austria-Hungary and Russia, were not part of the core any more during the interwar years. It is equally clear that Germany, although suffering from severe economic and political setbacks, remained part of the core since it continued to be the major power of Central and Eastern Europe. The same kind of judgement applies to Belgium and Italy. They payed a high price for their war 10 involvement, although they were part of the winning coalition, but they were also capable of maintaining their prewar position as secondary international financial centers (Brussels, Milan). Belgium also continued to be one of the few European countries being able to export capital in the 1920s. As for the small neutral countries, their role was rather enhanced than hampered by World War I (Straumann 2010). The Dutch guilder and the Swiss franc improved their relative position in the international monetary geography. Spain, another neutral, was able to maintain its status as major economic and monetary power in Southern Europe and Latin America. World War I did not only induce a shrinking of the core, but also added a new member. In a similar vein as the Netherlands and Switzerland, Sweden began to play a more important regional role in the 1920s than before the war. While being a typical late industrializing country importing great amounts of capital before the war, it belonged to the small and privileged group of European capital exporters in the 1920s, and the Swedish krona therefore established itself as a currency of some international importance. Sweden, however, seems to be the only country that experienced an upward grading. Its Scandinavian neighbors Denmark and Norway, though profiting from the war as small neutrals, did not undergo a comparable improvement of their international position. Denmark continued to send two thirds of total exports to the British market, mostly for the English breakfast table, and Norway remained highly dependent on shipping and fisheries. Accordingly, their currencies were still irrelevant in international finance. The same is true for Portugal, another small neutral which survived the war without major damage. Clearly, World War I reduced the number of countries belonging to the core (Table 2). Because the definition of the core countries may be crucial for the results, we also test two alternatives (Table 2). The first one deletes Germany from the list because it can be argued that its defeat in World War I relegated the country, similary as Austria-Hungary and Russia, 11 to an emerging market. Perhaps the most negative consequence of the lost war was that the change of the reparations regime due to the Young Plan dramatically weakened the resilience of the economy and the political room of manoeuvre. After 1929, Germany was not allowed any more to borrow foreign capital to pay parts of the reparations bill (Ritschl 2003). This interpretation, though disputed by Temin (2008), needs to be considered by our definitions of core and periphery. It also has the advantage that the omission of Germany fulfills a clear criterion: the core countries are all either winners of World War I or major neutrals. It is therefore essentially a political definition of the core. The second alternative to the monetary definition highlights the central role played by international capital movements. Creditor countries had more possibilities to defend the gold standard than debtor countries. Especially those countries which imported large amounts of US capital in the second half of the 1920s were severely suffering from the reversal of the US funds following the steep increase in the discount rate of the Fed towards the end of the decade. It therefore seems legitimate to use this divide as the defining criterion for core and periphery. Another advantage of this definition is that the list of core countries becomes considerably smaller which provides a useful contrast to the monetary or political definition. 4. Model, variables and data So far, economic historians have applied duration analysis in order to identify the crucial factors leading to the exit of individual countries. For two reasons, we prefer an ordered probit model. First, while duration analysis relates a “change” variable (leaving the gold standard) to its potential economic and political determinants, we use a specification in which the “state” 12 variable “being on or off the gold standard” is related to economic and political indicators. Thus, in contrast to duration analysis we use not only the data before leaving the gold standard but take into account the data after this decision. Second, an ordered probit model allows for a richer menu of exchange rate regimes than “being on or off the gold standard” by considering the option of capital controls before or after leaving the gold standard. This possibility was used for instance by Eastern European countries like Czechoslovakia and Romania. These choices were probably not accidental, but were linked to basic economic factors. Therefore instead of a binary probit model we apply an ordered probit model with the four possible states “being on gold with old parity”, “imposing capital controls with old parity” , “being off gold with an official suspension or a depreciation relative to gold” and “being off gold with imposing capital controls”. Furthermore, we are sceptical of how all authors working with duration analysis pool the data for a couple of countries over time without fully taking into account the panel structure of such a macroeconomic dataset. In particular unobserved cultural and political country characteristics may strongly bias the estimates if the indicators included in the model are correlated with these unobserved characteristics. As most of the country characteristics are more or less time invariant we can represent them by a country fixed effect as a “catch all” variable. And finally, we explicitly test for the significance of the core-periphery dimension by allowing different coefficients for these two groups of countries in our model. In our model the ordinal observable variable to be explained is the variable y taking the value 0 for “being on gold”, 1 for “imposing capital controls”, 2 for “being off gold” and 3 for “being off gold with capital controls”, respectively. The ordered probit model is based on a regression model for one underlying non-observable variable y* depending on observed xvariables with a normally identically and independently distributed error term. The latent variable y* represents the willingness of countries to remove the gold standard restrictions. If 13 this unobservable dependent variable gets larger than a first bound we observe that the ordinal variable y takes the value 1 (imposition of capital controls). If it increases further and crosses a second bound we observe y to take the value 2 “being off gold” and so on. These bounds are unknown and have to be estimated jointly with the regression coefficients by maximum likelihood. A positive (negative) value of such a regression coefficient means that an increase in the corresponding variable makes the country more (less) willing to remove the gold standard restrictions. Formally the model with N countries and T periods panel data set with fixed effects can be written as follows: k k j =1 j =1 yit* = ∑ β j x jit + ∑ δ j x jit dci + α i + ε it I = 1,2,...N ; t = 1,2....T yi = s, if γ s−1 < yi* ≤ γ s , s = 0,1,2,3 γ −1 = −∞, γ 3 = ∞ α i : country fixed effect dci : core dummy (1 for core countries, 0 otherwise) ε it : normal error term The second set of regressors, the interaction terms x-variables with the core dummy, allows for core-peripheries difference: if some of the δ j are different from zero we have a different reaction of the core countries to the corresponding x-variable and the respective core coefficient is the sum of β j and δ j , whereas the periphery value is, of course, β j . As we prefer to represent some country characteristics by a country fixed effect, the number of our x-variables is considerably reduced. We have omitted the degree of independence of the central bank, the inflation history, the degree of democratization, and the extent of social unrest. In addition, we exclude the variable creditor/debtor status because, as explained in the third section, it can be used as an alternative criterion to divide the world into core and 14 periphery. And finally, for the sake of simplicity, we do not test interest rate and inflation rate differentials as their effects can be caught by other variables, in particular by GDP growth and change of gold reserves. Consider a country with a high inflation rate. Under the gold standard its real exchange rate will appreciate, slowing down GDP growth and reducing gold reserves as the external balance deteriorates. A high interest rate also leads to weaker or negative GDP growth, but can have very different effects on the gold reserves. In the ideal world of the price-specie-flow mechanism, the gold cover ratio is supposed to increase as foreign capital flows in. Within the framework of the second generation currency crises in which a high interest rate can lead to a self-fulfilling prophecy as investors interpret the high yield as a sign of weakness the gold cover ratio is likely to decrease dramatically (Obstfeld 1994). Apart from these omissions, our set of variables is quite similar to the ones used by the papers which are based on duration analysis. Our list starts with GDP per capita (GDPPC). The choice of this variable is motivated by the assumption that rich countries were more resilient to the negative effects of the economic downturn than poor ones. It is, however, important to note that the level of GDP per capita is not related to our selection of core countries. Australia, Canada, Denmark and New Zealand had a higher level of GDP per capita than France, Germany and Sweden, but are not part of the core according to our definition. In other words, the periphery is a very heterogeneous group with respect to GDP per capita. It is therefore likely to see a significant effect of this variable. The second variable is the growth of GDP per capita (GGDPPC). The assumption is that countries with a particularly severe contraction are more likely to devalue or to introduce capital controls. The economic downturn can exert a negative effect on the stability of a currency through several channels. A high rate of unemployment can make the central bank hesitate to increase the discount rate in the face of capital flight as second-generation models 15 suggest. It can also lead to a banking crisis or a dramatic decrease of central bank reserves triggering a run on the currency. Whether or not this variable plays a different role for core and periphery countries is hard to predict. As for the monetary side, we focus on the growth of gold reserves (GGRLA). This variable reflects all kinds of shocks, for example a deterioration of the terms of trade, a drop in foreign demand relative to domestic demand or a reversal of capital movements. It is also of vital importance because it was one of the most important indicators guiding the discussions and actions of central bankers. In particular, a steep decline of gold reserves often led the authorities to abandon the gold standard, for example in Great Britain and Sweden in late September 1931. The fourth and fifth variables reflect international linkages. When major trading partners devalue, it becomes more likely that a country abandons the gold standard. We therefore calculated the share of exports affected by a devaluation of trading partners (EXDVL: Export Share Devaluing countries). Likewise, the currency in which the foreign debt is denominated matters. If the currency remains on the gold standard, the debtor country may not leave the gold standard because it would be too costly to allow an increase of the foreign debt. The variable DDVL (Debts Share Devaluing currencies) represents the share of foreign debt affected by the devaluation of the creditor country. Both variables are expected to be more important for countries of the periphery than for core countries. The share of foreign debt (FDSLA) accounts for the amount of foreign debt in relation to total debts. Countries with high a share are more likely to be more vulnerable to economic shocks. It is a way to integrate the insight by Bordo and Flandreau (2003) concerning the importance of financial maturity for the exchange rate regime during the classical gold standard and since 16 the demise of Bretton Woods. Core countries are able to issue international securities denominated in domestic currency while countries of the periphery are not. A banking crisis, expressed by a dummy variable (DBC), can force the government and the central bank to lower interest rates and to expand the money supply which may contradict the rules of the gold standard and subsequently lead to a weakening of the currency. This is one of the central aspects of the third-generation model. As noted, the change of cabinet (CCH) is the only political variable we are explicitly testing as it is time-variant.5 It is an indicator for political instability and we expect a positive influence on our latent endogenous variable. We would expect that it is more relevant to the periphery than to the core. As explained in section 3, we test three different definitions of the core, expressed by a dummy variable (DC). We also let the core dummy interact with all variables listed above. The country dummy variable (D*) takes account of the problem that unobserved cultural and political country characteristics may strongly bias the estimates if the indicators included in the model are correlated with these unobserved characteristics. We use only lagged explanatory variables in order to avoid simultaneity and reverse causation problems. Most of the variables are defined three years moving average in order to smooth out transitory fluctuations. Our sample includes the following countries: - Europe: Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Italy, Norway, Romania, Portugal, Poland, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, UK 5 Recall that all time-invariant cultural and political characteristics are represented by the country fixed effect 17 - North America: Canada and the US - South America: Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Peru, Uruguay and Venezuela - Asia/Oceania: Japan, Australia and New Zealand GDP data are taken from Maddison (2001), gold reserves from the League of Nations (statistical yearbook), trade data from Mitchell (2003),currency denomination of foreign debt from United Nations (1948), share of foreign debt from the League of Nations, banking crisis data from Bernanke and James (1991), change of government from Banks (1971). 5. Results Table 3 reports our results generated by an ordered probit model for the indicator variable with four values as described above. We use annual data from 1926-1938 if available. As for some countries not all x-variables are available for the full sample we have an unbalanced panel consisting of 288 observations consisting of time series with variable length for 29 countries. We report the results for the adjusted Flandreau/Jobst core periphery classification. However, the results for the two alternative classifications discussed in section 3 provide results which only differ marginally from those given in Table 3. These results are available on request from the authors. Before turning to the result for the non-core countries let us mention that the pseudo Rsquared of 0.469 indicates a good model fit. Six x-variables are statistically significant at the 5% level (one-sided) for the periphery, namely GDP level and GDP growth, growth rate of gold reserves, the share of exports going to devaluing countries, the banking crisis dummy as well as the number of cabinet changes. Most of them have the expected sign: higher growth decreases the propensity to relax the gold standard restrictions, whereas all other indicators 18 representing banking crises and export difficulties as well as political turmoil have a positive influence on the disposition to go off gold. The growth rate of gold reserves has the expected negative sign. The only surprising result is the positive sign of the level of per capita GDP indicating that rich countries in the periphery were more willing to go off gold than poorer ones. Thus countries in the periphery show a common pattern of the disposition to leave the gold standard in response to a decline in GDP and negative growth, diminishing gold reserves, banking crises and political instability. The coefficient estimate for the foreign debt share is clearly statistically insignificant. For the core countries things are different: we see that four of the interaction terms are individually different from zero. In addition, the F-value for hypothesis that all core dummy interaction coefficients are jointly zero is 5.962 and the null hypothesis is rejected at any reasonable significance level (third panel in Table 3). In the fourth panel the coefficient estimates for the core countries (the sum of the periphery and interaction term estimates) and their standard errors are displayed. The coefficients of per capita GDP, the growth of gold reserves and the export share with devaluing countries is highly statistical significant at the 0.1% level. Note that all coefficients have the “right” sign. All other x-variables are jointly statistically insignificant and individually relatively small compared to their standard errors. Thus there are only three common factors determining the disposition to go off gold among core countries, namely a low level of per capita GDP, shrinking gold reserves and, statistically most significant, the fact that others went off gold previously. Thus the early devaluation of the pound in 1931 appears as a country specific phenomenon captured in our modelling framework by the country fixed effect. All other core countries were initially willing to withstand all the difficulties and absorb the shocks within the system of the gold standard. For instance core countries were more able and willing to absorb negative GDP growth, a banking crisis and political instability than countries of the periphery. Notably the US suffered from 19 four banking crises until a new administration under President F. D. Roosevelt changed course in spring 1933. Similarly, Belgium, France and Switzerland managed to contain their banking crises in 1931. These results ultimately stem from the fact that the core countries on average remained longer on the gold standard than the peripheral countries. The gold bloc consisted almost entirely of core countries, with the exception of the Polish speaking countries (Danzig, Lithuania, Poland). Taken together, our results suggest that the core-periphery divide was central to how the interwar gold standard was collapsing from 1929 to 1936. Finally we should mention that the results are robust with the respect to our choice of a four values indicator probit model instead of a simple binary probit model with only two different states “being on gold” (0) and “being off gold” (1): Table for reports qualitatively strongly similar results for this model. However, it can be seen the ordered probit model provides a higher degree of statistical significance of the estimates. 6. Conclusion Ever since it occurred, many scholars have highlighted the core-periphery dimension of the collapse of the interwar gold standard from 1929 to 1936. However, hardly any economic historian has tried to catch this story by the means of econometrics. In this paper, we present some evidence on the basis of an ordered probit model. The results suggest that the coreperiphery divide was essential for the chronology of the collapse. In fact, the story is not only gradually, but completely different, depending on the position of a country in the international economy. The crucial difference was that only countries of the periphery abandoned the gold standard in reaction to negative GDP growth, banking crises and government instability. Put differently, core countries were resilient enough to absorb the domestic consequences of the 20 depression, be they economic, financial or political. Only with respect to their external relations, namely trade and capital, did they share the same vulnerabilities as the countries of the periphery. In addition, the level of GDP per capita mattered in both country groups: rich countries were more resilient than poor ones. References Ahamed, Liaquat (2009), Lords of Finance: The Bankers Who Broke the World, New York: Penguin Press. Banks, Arthur S. (1971), Cross-Polity Time-Series Data, Cambridge (Mass.) and London: The MIT Press. Bernanke, Ben S., and Harold James (1991), «The Gold Standard, Deflation, and Financial Crisis in the Great Depression: An International Comparison», in R. Glenn Hubbard (ed.), Financial Markets and Financial Crises, Chicago and London: The University of Chicago Press, pp. 33-68. Bordo, Michael, and Marc Flandreau (2003), “Core, Periphery, Exchange Rate Regime and Globalization”, in Michael Bordo, Alan Taylor and Jeffrey Williamson (eds.), Globalization in Historical Perspective, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 417-468. Brown, William Adams (1940), The International Gold Standard Reinterpreted, 1914-1934, New York: National Bureau of Economic Research. 21 Choudri, Ehsan U., and Levis A. Kochin. “The Exchange Rate and the International Transmission of Business Cycle Disturbances: Some Evidence from the Great Depression.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 12, no. 4 (1980): 565-74. Eichengreen, Barry (1992), Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919 1939, New York: Oxford University Press. Eichengreen, Barry and Olivier Jeanne (2000), “Currency Crisis and Unemployment: Sterling in 1931,” in Paul Krugman (ed.), Currency Crises, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Eichengreen, Barry, and Jeffrey Sachs (1985), “Exchange Rates and Economic Recovery in the 1930s”, Journal of Economic History 45 (4), December, pp. 925-946. Einzig, Paul (1931), The fight for financial supremacy, London: Macmillan. Flandreau, Marc, and Clemens Jobst (2005), “The Ties that Divide: a Network Analysis of the International Monetary System, 1890-1910, The Journal of Economic History 65, pp. 9771007. James, Harold, The End of Globalization: Lessons from the Great Depression. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2001. Krugman, Paul (2000), “Introduction,” in Paul Krugman (ed.), Currency Crises, Chicago and London: The University of Chicago Press, pp. 1-7. League of Nations, Statistical Yearbook, various issues. Maddison, Angus (2001), The world economy: a millennial perspective, Paris: OECD. Meissner, Christopher M. (2005), “A new world order: explaining the international diffusion of the gold standard, 1870.1913”, Journal of International Economics 66, pp. 385-406. 22 Mitchell, Brian R. (2003), International historical statistics, 1750-2000, 3 vols., New York: Palgrave Macmillan. Simmons, Beth (1994), Who adjusts? Domestic sources of foreign economic policy during the interwar years, Princeton: Princeton University Press. Somary, Felix (1929), Wandlungen der Weltwirtschaft seit dem Kriege, Tübingen: Mohr/Siebeck. Straumann, Tobias (2010), Fixed ideas of money: small states and exchange rate regimes in 20th century Europe, Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press. Temin, Peter (1989), Lessons from the great depression, Cambridge (Mass.): The MIT Press. United Nations (1949), International Capital Movements during the Inter-War Period, Lake Success (NY): United Nations. United Nations (1948), Public Debt 1914–1946, Lake Success (NY): United Nations. Wandschneider, Kirsten (2008) “The Stability of the Interwar Gold Exchange Standard: Did Politics Matter?”, Journal of Economic History 68 (1), pp. 151-181. Wolf, Holger C., and Tarik M. Yousef (2007), “Breaking the Fetters: Why did Countries Exit the Interwar Gold Standard?”, in Timothy J. Hatton, Kevin H. O’Rourke and Alan M. Taylor (eds.), The New Comparative Economic History: Essays in Honor of Jeffrey G. Williamson, Cambridge (Mass.): The MIT Press, pp. 241-266. Wolf, Nikolaus (2008), “Scylla and Charybdis: Explaining Europe’s exit from gold, January 1928-December 1936”, Explorations in Economic History 45 (4), pp. 383-401. 23 Table 1: Year of end of interwar gold standard (selected countries) * Continent First phase Second phase Third phase Fourth phase (1929-30) (1931-32) (1933) (1934-36) Northern Europe Denmark Estonia Finland Norway Sweden Western Europe UK Belgium France Netherlands Central Europe Austria Switzerland Czechoslovakia Germany Eastern Europe Mediterranean Bulgaria Danzig Hungary Lithuania Roumania Poland Greece Italy Portugal Yougoslavia North America Canada USA Central America South America Argentina Brazil Paraguay Uruguay Asia India Neth. East Indies (Indonesia) Japan Oceania Australia New Zealand Sources: League of Nations (1939), Aldcroft and Oliver (1998), Officer (2001), Obstfeld and Taylor (2004). Note: * We consider either a depreciation or the introduction of foreign exchange controls as the break with the gold standard, even in these cases in which the government suspends the gold standard later. 24 Table 2: Definitions of core countries Monetarydefinition Monetarydefinition Political definition Financialdefinition 1900 1930 1930 1930 Flandreau and Jobst 2005 Flandreau and Jobst Winners of WW I and Creditor countries adjusted major neutrals Belgium Belgium Belgium Belgium France France France France Germany Germany Italy Italy Italy Netherlands Netherlands Netherlands Spain Spain Sweden Sweden Sweden Switzerland Switzerland Switzerland Switzerland UK UK UK UK USA USA USA USA Austria-Hungary Netherlands Russia Spain 25 Table 3: Ordered Probit Model 0: GS, 1: Exchange Controls with GS, 2: Devaluation, Exit GS , 3: Devaluation, Exit GS and Exchange EXRN Controls GDPPCLA Per Capita GDP (ma lagged 3 years) GGDPPCLA Growth Per Capita GDP (ma lagged 3 years) GGRLA Growth Gold Reserves(ma lagged 3 years) EXDVL Export Share Devaluing countries( lagged 1 year) DDVL Debt Share Devaluing currencies( lagged 1 year) FDSLA Share Foreign Debt (ma lagged 3 years) DBC Banking Crisis Dummy CCH Change of Government DC Core Dummy (BE,FR,CH,NL,UK,US) D* Country Dummy Dependent Variable: EXRN Method: ML - Ordered Probit (Quadratic hill climbing) Included observations: 288 after adjustments Number of ordered indicator values: 4 26 Convergence achieved after 8 iterations QML (Huber/White) standard errors & covariance Coefficient Std. Error z-Statistic Prob. GDPPCLA 0.029855 2.952626 0.0032 GGDPPCLA -0.103190 0.020474 -5.039981 0.0000 GGRLA -2.61E-05 7.75E-06 -3.360061 0.0008 EXDVL 0.023087 0.008413 2.744130 0.0061 DCDL 0.004836 0.005289 0.914363 0.3605 DBC 0.802895 0.445121 1.803767 0.0713 CCH 0.300163 0.142651 2.104177 0.0354 FDSLA 0.233093 0.706891 0.329744 0.7416 DC 5.960094 1.581709 3.768135 0.0002 GDPPCLA*DC -0.068971 0.013403 -5.145790 0.0000 GGDPPCLA*DC 0.122899 2.765484 0.0057 GGRLA*DC -0.026697 0.005525 -4.832279 0.0000 EXDVL*DC 0.037971 0.014398 2.637212 0.0084 DCDL*DC 0.008299 0.010752 0.771872 0.4402 DBC*DC -0.835821 0.621115 -1.345680 0.1784 CCH*DC -0.285386 0.224102 -1.273464 0.2029 FDSLA*DC 0.172228 0.049299 0.9607 DAU -1.785704 0.683557 -2.612370 0.0090 DBE -0.699084 1.473210 -0.474531 0.6351 DCH 0.207638 0.350892 0.7257 DDK -2.546091 0.889558 -2.862197 0.0042 DFI -2.069742 0.485654 -4.261760 0.0000 DGE 0.172926 0.055498 0.9557 DIT -2.009256 0.810581 -2.478784 0.0132 DNL -1.883756 0.684381 -2.752496 0.0059 DNO -1.819362 0.464798 -3.914304 0.0001 0.010111 0.044440 3.493525 0.591743 3.115899 27 DPT 1.203903 DSW 0.676593 1.779360 0.0752 -2.141604 0.858774 -2.493793 0.0126 DAR 0.035912 0.055664 0.9556 DAS -3.675287 0.820958 -4.476825 0.0000 DBR 1.590854 2.214117 0.0268 DBU -2.238768 0.782403 -2.861401 0.0042 DCA -3.322924 0.546540 -6.079926 0.0000 DCL -0.906749 0.464685 -1.951320 0.0510 DHU -1.301073 0.357921 -3.635090 0.0003 DNZ -3.428446 0.855857 -4.005861 0.0001 DPE -0.373169 0.519288 -0.718617 0.4724 DRO -1.244013 0.842749 -1.476138 0.1399 DUS 1.094894 0.724485 1.511272 0.1307 0.645163 0.718505 Limit Points LIMIT_1:C(40) 1.441085 1.034910 1.392473 0.1638 LIMIT_2:C(41) 1.502153 1.033381 1.453629 0.1460 LIMIT_3:C(42) 3.790398 1.043814 3.631296 0.0003 Akaike info criterion 1.481142 Schwarz criterion 2.015324 Log likelihood -171.2844 Hannan-Quinn criter. 1.695210 Restr. log likelihood -323.1666 Avg. log likelihood -0.594738 LR statistic (39 df) 303.7644 LR index (Pseudo-R2) 0.469981 Probability(LR stat) 0.000000 28 Joint and Single Test of Core Periphery Difference Wald Test: Test Statistic Value df Probability F-statistic 5.962324 (9, 246) 0.0000 Chi-square 53.66092 9 0.0000 Core Coefficient Estimates and Joint Test Wald Test: Test Statistic Value df Probability F-statistic 9.106582 (8, 246) 0.0000 Chi-square 72.85265 8 0.0000 Normalized Restriction (= 0) Value Std. Err. GDPPCLA -0.039116 0.008555 GDPPCLA 0.019709 0.039136 GGRLA -0.026723 0.005525 EXDVL 0.061058 0.012092 DCDL 0.013135 0.009367 DBC -0.032927 0.430946 CCH 0.014777 0.171803 FDSLA 0.405320 3.420966 Null Hypothesis Summary: 29 Table 4 Binary Probit Model Dependent Variable: EXRB (0: “on gold”, 1: “off gold” Method: ML - Binary Probit (BHHH) Included observations: 288 after adjustments Convergence achieved after 2589 iterations QML (Huber/White) standard errors & covariance Variable Coefficient Std. Error z-Statistic Prob. C -3.109188 1.821980 -1.706488 0.0879 GDPPCLA 0.043982 2.426645 0.0152 GGDPPCLA -0.098729 0.041287 -2.391292 0.0168 GGRLA -1.55E-05 5.71E-06 -2.709213 0.0067 EXDVL 0.025341 0.012349 2.052079 0.0402 DCDL 0.013061 0.007243 1.803181 0.0714 DBC 0.979974 0.505867 1.937218 0.0527 CCH 0.538394 0.295217 1.823726 0.0682 FDSLA 2.785173 1.838917 1.514573 0.1299 DC 3.371443 2.284026 1.476097 0.1399 GDPPCLA*DC -0.061983 0.020628 -3.004847 0.0027 GGDPPCLA*DC 0.271896 3.048865 0.0023 GGRLA*DC -0.026967 0.011570 -2.330734 0.0198 EXDVL*DC 0.082821 0.031539 2.626007 0.0086 DCDL*DC 0.072600 0.074555 0.973779 0.3302 DBC*DC -0.669621 0.750756 -0.891929 0.3724 CCH*DC -0.359253 0.369136 -0.973227 0.3304 FDSLA*DC -5.465537 4.123237 -1.325545 0.1850 DAU -5.203589 1.645541 -3.162236 0.0016 0.018125 0.089180 30 DBE -7.416042 6.553801 -1.131563 0.2578 DCH -1.471311 1.019147 -1.443669 0.1488 DDK -5.289646 1.467751 -3.603911 0.0003 DFI -3.634721 1.389436 -2.615968 0.0089 DGE 2.883643 0.863463 0.3879 DIT -2.770277 0.928498 -2.983612 0.0028 DNL -3.378303 1.629056 -2.073780 0.0381 DNO -2.178102 1.020011 -2.135371 0.0327 DSW 0.298096 0.358573 0.7199 DAS -4.810625 1.860203 -2.586075 0.0097 DBR 0.777147 0.589899 0.5553 DBU -3.639534 1.509473 -2.411129 0.0159 DCA -4.119451 1.303329 -3.160714 0.0016 DCL -3.047501 1.500149 -2.031466 0.0422 DHU -1.791626 0.899699 -1.991361 0.0464 DNZ -4.741750 1.875148 -2.528733 0.0114 DPE -1.283821 1.644889 -0.780491 0.4351 DRO -2.483250 1.478493 -1.679582 0.0930 DUS -0.689533 1.676500 -0.411293 0.6809 Mean dependent var 0.649306 S.D. dependent var 0.478018 S.E. of regression 0.294104 Akaike info criterion 0.754651 Sum squared resid 21.62429 Schwarz criterion 1.237959 Log likelihood -70.66981 Hannan-Quinn criter. 0.948332 Restr. log likelihood -186.5881 Avg. log likelihood -0.245381 LR statistic (37 df) 231.8367 McFadden R-squared 0.621252 Probability(LR stat) 0.000000 Obs with Dep=0 101 Total obs 288 Obs with Dep=1 187 3.339626 0.831339 1.317425 31 Joint and Single Test of Core Periphery Difference Wald Test: Test Statistic Value df Probability F-statistic 5.122697 (9, 250) 0.0000 Chi-square 46.10427 9 0.0000 Core Coefficient Estimates and Joint Test Wald Test: Test Statistic Value df Probability F-statistic 6.737437 (8, 250) 0.0000 Chi-square 53.89950 8 0.0000 Normalized Restriction (= 0) Value Std. Err. GDPPCLA -0.018001 0.009848 GGDPPCLA 0.173168 0.099047 Null Hypothesis Summary: 32 GGRLA -0.026983 0.011570 EXDVL 0.108162 0.029021 DCDE 0.085661 0.074202 DBC 0.310353 0.554738 CCH 0.179141 0.221604 FDSLA -2.680364 3.690456 33