
1. Expand (a b)n Using Pascal`s Triangle Section 15.4 The Binomial
... 1. Expand (a ⴙ b)n Using Pascal’s Triangle Here are the expansions of (a b) n for several values of n: (a b) 0 1 (a b) 1 a b (a b) 2 a2 2ab b2 (a b) 3 a3 3a2b 3ab2 b3 (a b) 4 a4 4a3b 6a2b2 4ab3 b4 (a b) 5 a5 5a4b 10a3b2 10a2b3 5ab4 b5 Notice th ...
... 1. Expand (a ⴙ b)n Using Pascal’s Triangle Here are the expansions of (a b) n for several values of n: (a b) 0 1 (a b) 1 a b (a b) 2 a2 2ab b2 (a b) 3 a3 3a2b 3ab2 b3 (a b) 4 a4 4a3b 6a2b2 4ab3 b4 (a b) 5 a5 5a4b 10a3b2 10a2b3 5ab4 b5 Notice th ...
Name:_________________________________________________________ Period:________ Unit 1 Helpful Tools for Proofs
... If two parallel lines are cut by a transversal, then the two pairs of same-side interior angles are supplementary. If two coplanar lines are cut by a transversal so that a pair of alternate interior angles are congruent, then the two lines are parallel. If two coplanar lines are cut by a transversal ...
... If two parallel lines are cut by a transversal, then the two pairs of same-side interior angles are supplementary. If two coplanar lines are cut by a transversal so that a pair of alternate interior angles are congruent, then the two lines are parallel. If two coplanar lines are cut by a transversal ...
Measures and functions in locally convex spaces Rudolf Gerrit Venter
... results comparable to the status quo. Such properties are thoroughly considered. Then we investigate certain locally convex spaces for which some of the summability conditions can be relaxed. In the second part of this dissertation, in Chapter 3, we consider the existence of weak integrals in locall ...
... results comparable to the status quo. Such properties are thoroughly considered. Then we investigate certain locally convex spaces for which some of the summability conditions can be relaxed. In the second part of this dissertation, in Chapter 3, we consider the existence of weak integrals in locall ...
Brouwer fixed-point theorem

Brouwer's fixed-point theorem is a fixed-point theorem in topology, named after Luitzen Brouwer. It states that for any continuous function f mapping a compact convex set into itself there is a point x0 such that f(x0) = x0. The simplest forms of Brouwer's theorem are for continuous functions f from a closed interval I in the real numbers to itself or from a closed disk D to itself. A more general form than the latter is for continuous functions from a convex compact subset K of Euclidean space to itself.Among hundreds of fixed-point theorems, Brouwer's is particularly well known, due in part to its use across numerous fields of mathematics.In its original field, this result is one of the key theorems characterizing the topology of Euclidean spaces, along with the Jordan curve theorem, the hairy ball theorem and the Borsuk–Ulam theorem.This gives it a place among the fundamental theorems of topology. The theorem is also used for proving deep results about differential equations and is covered in most introductory courses on differential geometry.It appears in unlikely fields such as game theory. In economics, Brouwer's fixed-point theorem and its extension, the Kakutani fixed-point theorem, play a central role in the proof of existence of general equilibrium in market economies as developed in the 1950s by economics Nobel prize winners Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu.The theorem was first studied in view of work on differential equations by the French mathematicians around Poincaré and Picard.Proving results such as the Poincaré–Bendixson theorem requires the use of topological methods.This work at the end of the 19th century opened into several successive versions of the theorem. The general case was first proved in 1910 by Jacques Hadamard and by Luitzen Egbertus Jan Brouwer.