
Two-Column Proofs
... columns- statements and reasons. The best way to understand two-column proofs is to read through examples. When writing your own two-column proof, keep these things in mind: Number each step. Start with the given information. Statements with the same reason can be combined into one step. It is up to ...
... columns- statements and reasons. The best way to understand two-column proofs is to read through examples. When writing your own two-column proof, keep these things in mind: Number each step. Start with the given information. Statements with the same reason can be combined into one step. It is up to ...
Section 1.2-1.3
... conditions hold: (a) P (1) is true, and (b) for all n 1, if P (n) holds then P (n + 1) also holds. Use the well-ordering principle to prove that P (n) must be true for all natural numbers n 1. Exercise Notes: For Exercise 1, use the well-ordering proof strategy 1.2.1 where P (n) is the statement “n ...
... conditions hold: (a) P (1) is true, and (b) for all n 1, if P (n) holds then P (n + 1) also holds. Use the well-ordering principle to prove that P (n) must be true for all natural numbers n 1. Exercise Notes: For Exercise 1, use the well-ordering proof strategy 1.2.1 where P (n) is the statement “n ...
SOME RESULTS ABOUT BANACH COMPACT ALGEBRAS B. M.
... Abstract. In this paper, we prove that (i) if A is a quasi-complete locally m−convex algebra on which the operator x 7−→ yxy(x ∈ A) is Banach compact for all elements y in a sequentially dense subset of A, then A is a Banach compact locally m−convex algebra and (ii) that every Montel algebra is Bana ...
... Abstract. In this paper, we prove that (i) if A is a quasi-complete locally m−convex algebra on which the operator x 7−→ yxy(x ∈ A) is Banach compact for all elements y in a sequentially dense subset of A, then A is a Banach compact locally m−convex algebra and (ii) that every Montel algebra is Bana ...
Quotient spaces
... bijective correspondence between functions f : Y → Z and functions fˆ : X → Z, the latter of which need to be constant on π −1 (y) for all y ∈ Y . The next theorem shows that this correspondence remains bijective after restricting to the subset of continuous functions in each of these sets. Theorem ...
... bijective correspondence between functions f : Y → Z and functions fˆ : X → Z, the latter of which need to be constant on π −1 (y) for all y ∈ Y . The next theorem shows that this correspondence remains bijective after restricting to the subset of continuous functions in each of these sets. Theorem ...
on the relation between completeness and h
... $\uparrow 0-=\{0_{-}\},$ disjoint union with the extended order as follows: $X$ $and\uparrow 0+=\{0_{+}\}\sqcup B$ . is not directed complete and has ...
... $\uparrow 0-=\{0_{-}\},$ disjoint union with the extended order as follows: $X$ $and\uparrow 0+=\{0_{+}\}\sqcup B$ . is not directed complete and has ...
Brouwer fixed-point theorem

Brouwer's fixed-point theorem is a fixed-point theorem in topology, named after Luitzen Brouwer. It states that for any continuous function f mapping a compact convex set into itself there is a point x0 such that f(x0) = x0. The simplest forms of Brouwer's theorem are for continuous functions f from a closed interval I in the real numbers to itself or from a closed disk D to itself. A more general form than the latter is for continuous functions from a convex compact subset K of Euclidean space to itself.Among hundreds of fixed-point theorems, Brouwer's is particularly well known, due in part to its use across numerous fields of mathematics.In its original field, this result is one of the key theorems characterizing the topology of Euclidean spaces, along with the Jordan curve theorem, the hairy ball theorem and the Borsuk–Ulam theorem.This gives it a place among the fundamental theorems of topology. The theorem is also used for proving deep results about differential equations and is covered in most introductory courses on differential geometry.It appears in unlikely fields such as game theory. In economics, Brouwer's fixed-point theorem and its extension, the Kakutani fixed-point theorem, play a central role in the proof of existence of general equilibrium in market economies as developed in the 1950s by economics Nobel prize winners Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu.The theorem was first studied in view of work on differential equations by the French mathematicians around Poincaré and Picard.Proving results such as the Poincaré–Bendixson theorem requires the use of topological methods.This work at the end of the 19th century opened into several successive versions of the theorem. The general case was first proved in 1910 by Jacques Hadamard and by Luitzen Egbertus Jan Brouwer.