* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download ETUC Econ 11-10 - European Economic Governance is
Transformation in economics wikipedia , lookup
Currency War of 2009–11 wikipedia , lookup
Currency war wikipedia , lookup
Development theory wikipedia , lookup
Financialization wikipedia , lookup
Exchange rate wikipedia , lookup
Economic globalization wikipedia , lookup
Development economics wikipedia , lookup
Fear of floating wikipedia , lookup
Balance of payments wikipedia , lookup
Economic discussion paper 2011/10 EUROPEAN ECONOMIC GOVERNANCE: THE COMMISSION IS LETTING SURPLUS COUNTRIES « OFF THE HOOK” The Commission is currently preparing the start up of the policy process that is supposed to detect and correct excessive macro economic imbalances, a new European procedure which was recently approved by an agreement concluded between the Parliament, the Council and the Commission at the end of September. These preparations do not bode well. They testify to the fact that the Commission continues to hold a biased view on the causes of Euro Area macroeconomic imbalances. The consequence of this is that policies which have actually caused the unbalancing of the Euro Area and the ongoing debt crisis will go undetected and uncorrected. The Commissioner’s letter: Blaming countries that have ‘lived beyond their means” A recent letter written by Commissioner Olli Rehn to the Polish Presidency makes the Commission’s view on Euro Area imbalances perfectly clear. The thrust of this letter is to shift the entire focus onto countries with current account deficits while completely ignoring the role of member states running huge and rising huge current account surpluses. Commissioner Rehn’s letter argues that: “…large and persistent current account deficits raise concerns about the sustainability of external debt of a country and can pose solvency risks”. In other words, if a country is continuously running an external deficit, this deficit needs to be financed by economic actors (be it households, companies or governments) taking up more debts, year, after year, after year. Such a process is unlikely to continue indefinitely. Sooner or later, financial markets will go on ‘strike’, refusing to roll over existing debts and stop financing the economy altogether, with economic collapse as a result. This is indeed the scenario the Euro Area has become all too familiar with. Whereas the Commissioner’s letter clearly identifies the problem that may be caused by caused by external deficits, large and persistent current account surpluses are not seen as a threat for the coherence of the single currency. The letter states: “However, unlike current account deficits, large and sustained current account surpluses do not raise concerns about the sustainability of external debt or financing capacity that affect the smooth functioning of the euro area”. All of this boils down to the fact that the Commission, when using this new process of excessive imbalances, will zoom in on those countries which are “living beyond their means” while countries living “below” their means are per definition considered not to endanger the single currency. Instead, the Commission even considers them to be good pupils that have simply improved their ‘competitive position in the global economy’ and should not be lectured, let alone sanctioned, for doing so. The real story behind the “unbalancing” of the European single currency The Commission’s approach is clouded by its traditional view that ‘wage competitiveness’ is of the upmost importance. However, a radically different story can be told if one widens the perspective to include other dimensions of how economies under a single currency regime function. This story starts when one member state, representing almost 25% of the total economic weight of the entire Euro Area, opted to pursue an encompassing program of labour market deregulation from the moment the single currency was introduced. All standard recipes from the standard economic textbook on labour market flexibility were introduced. Unemployment benefits were cut in duration and the unemployed were forced to accept any kind of jobs, even jobs paying substantially less than collectively bargained wages. Interim agency work was ‘liberalised’ with the effect that workers on regular contracts were replaced by precarious workers paid up to 50% lower wages. ‘Mini-jobs’ and ‘one euro’ jobs were promoted or introduced, again with the effect of turning what were otherwise full time jobs with regular contracts and wages into precarious ones. This type of employer behaviour of switching to precarious work practices was actually rewarded by topping up poverty wages with ‘in work’ benefits. Meanwhile, no overall wage floor existed in the form of a statutory minimum wage to prevent workers on low wages from getting even lower wages. Finally, the principle of the autonomy of collective bargaining, free from political interference that is enshrined in the German constitution was thrown overboard by blackmailing trade unions into ‘employment pacts at company level’. If trade unions did not agree with clauses to open sector conventions and accept lower wages and/or longer unpaid working hours at company level, the government threatened to intervene in sector wage bargaining. The results of ‘anglo-saxonising’ the German labour market have been disastrous. From 2000 onwards, the number of precarious and low wage jobs, profits and dividends, simply exploded in Germany along with inequalities. In terms of averages, overall wage dynamics simply stagnated, while real wages for low wage workers substantially fell. However, even if a substantial part of the rents created by this policy of systematic wage repression ended up on the side of profits and dividend payments, another direct effect was stagnating domestic demand and inflation in Germany started to fall and move towards a minimum of only 1%. The next step in this process concerns the reaction of the ECB. If German inflation kept falling, it would eventually push the Euro Area average rate of inflation below the ECB’s price stability target of 2%. (Recall that Germany accounts for a quarter of the Euro Area). Moreover, the ECB could not stand by and let the core member state upon which the entire construction of the single currency had been built slide into a domestic demand led depression with the possibility of extremely low inflation turning into outright deflation. The ECB, even if it was reluctant to do so, finally cut interest rates to a historic low of 2% in 2002 and kept rates at this level over a period of several years. The following graphs illustrate how developments in Germany dominated the ECB’s interest rate policy. In the first graph, the Euro Area’s short term interest rate is set out against German inflation and economic growth. With the benefit of hindsight, a clear picture emerges: There’s a remarkable parallel between the interest rate policy of the ECB on the one hand and disinflation and economic slowdown in Germany on the other. Note that while the policy of wage stagnation made the German economy continue to struggle to recover from the 2002 economic stagnation, the Spanish economy for example maintained growth rates of 3, even almost 4% over the same period. Graph I: Germany’s depression pulling down ECB interest rates Source: OECD Unfortunately, the ECB’s low interest rate policy of the mid-2000’s turned out to be a poisonous gift for what has now become known the group of the ‘deficit’ countries. In several of these countries, the economy was already doing well and growing at rather robust growth rates (Spain, Ireland). The ECB’s low interest rate policy was simply too loose for them. With households and banks expecting their nominal revenues to grow at 5 to 6% a year, whilst the interest rate on loans is down to only 2%, the incentive to take out more loans and debts becomes strong. Graph II shows how the gap between nominal growths rates in the Southern part of the Euro Area (Spain, Italy, Portugal, Greece, France) on the one hand and the ECB’s interest rate on the other hand opened up from 2002 until 2007. Graph II Source: Natixis. Flash 2011/857 Moreover, the financial sector of these countries is characterised by the extensive use of mortgages with ‘variable’ interest rates. The ECB’s cuts in official interest rates was therefore almost immediately reflected in the interest rates to be paid by Spanish, Irish, Italian households on their mortgages (see table below). Source: Natxis. Flash 2011/857 The inevitable followed: huge debt and housing booms were triggered, these economies started to ‘overheat’ with domestic demand and inflation accelerating (which actually intensified the perverse monetary stimulus even further), and their external deficits took on gigantic proportions. Graph III illustrates how private sector (not public sector!) debt loads in Spain, Ireland and Greece (Italy, France and Portugal to a lesser extent), exploded in this first decade of European monetary union. Graph III: Private debt as a % of GDP Source: European Commission, Note from ECFIN to the EPC on the scoreboard for the surveillance of Macroeconomic Imbalances. The Euro Area economy now finds itself in the final stage of this process: The debt booms resulting from the combination of loose monetary policy with financial market flexibility have blown up and countries with high debt loads are no longer able to find sufficient and affordable access in the European or global marketplace to finance their economies. This situation is threatening the European single currency project itself, with markets increasingly counting on a chaotic breakup of the Euro Area. Implications for European Economic Governance The narrative on what actually happened during the first ten years of European monetary union shows that the story that is usually told is overly simplistic and misguiding. It is not just about countries that have been ‘living beyond their means’, it should also be about countries which have been ‘living below their means’. In particular, the systematic policy of wage dumping and repressing decent jobs pursued by German policy makers carries a heavy responsibility. It is this type of policy which has seriously distorted the single currency’s monetary policy regime, thereby providing other Euro Area members with perverse financial impulses and saddling them up with the debt booms which are now no longer sustained by financial markets. By openly and formally stating that ‘external surpluses’ do not pose any risk for the proper functioning of the Euro, the Commissioner’s letter turns a blind eye to what is a fundamental issue of the single currency. The fact that a policy of wage repression in some countries, combined with a single interest rate regime, creates substantial negative spill over effects towards the rest of the Euro Area. Moreover, the Commission follows this up by proposing a scoreboard of indicators on imbalances which defines an upper threshold for (unit) wage costs without also installing at a lower threshold. This actually means that policies of wage dumping will simply go undetected in this brand new European policy process! As previously indicated this does not bode well for the way economic governance will be implemented in practice. One actually fears that the Commission and the Council will uphold the labour market deregulation policies that unbalanced the single currency in the previous decade as the example to be followed by the whole of the Euro Area, in particular the ‘deficit’ countries’. This type of ‘unbalanced’ and unfair European economic governance will lead us into an Euro Area wide economic depression. Rjanssen/Brussels/ 12th December 2011