* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Risk Perceptions, Directional Goals and the Link between Risk and
Syndicated loan wikipedia , lookup
Investment management wikipedia , lookup
Beta (finance) wikipedia , lookup
Land banking wikipedia , lookup
Present value wikipedia , lookup
Securitization wikipedia , lookup
Financialization wikipedia , lookup
Stock trader wikipedia , lookup
Investment fund wikipedia , lookup
Moral hazard wikipedia , lookup
Stock selection criterion wikipedia , lookup
Mark-to-market accounting wikipedia , lookup
Corporate finance wikipedia , lookup
Systemic risk wikipedia , lookup
Risk Perceptions, Directional Goals and the Link between Risk and Value W. Brooke Elliott University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign Kristina M. Rennekamp Cornell University Brian J. White* The University of Texas at Austin April 2015 * Corresponding author’s contact information: Department of Accounting The University of Texas at Austin McCombs School of Business Department of Accounting 2110 Speedway, B6400 Austin, TX 78712-1281 Phone: (512) 471-5619 E-mail: [email protected] We appreciate helpful feedback from Tim Bauer, Tim Brown, Shuping Chen, Willie Choi, Paul Demeré, Peter Demerjian, Cassandra Estep, Harry Evans, Steph Grant, Frank Hodge, Jane Jollineau, Lisa Koonce, Russ Lundholm, Dawn Matsumoto, Adam Presslee, Nick Seybert, Jane Thayer, Michael Williamson and seminar participants at the University of British Columbia, University of Oregon and University of Washington (UBCOW) Conference, the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, the University of Pittsburgh and the University of Texas at Austin. Risk Perceptions, Directional Goals and the Link between Risk and Value ABSTRACT A fundamental premise in accounting and finance research is that risk affects firm value, and a key purpose of financial disclosures is to communicate risk to market participants. In this paper, we test how investors perceive risk in response to financial disclosures and how these risk perceptions affect their judgments of firm value. We also test directional goals for positive firm performance as a potential boundary condition on investors’ incorporation of risk perceptions into their judgments of firm value. Consistent with the adage that “losses loom larger than gains,” we find that prospective investors (those without directional goals) focus on downside risk. Further, prospective investors’ risk perceptions significantly influence their valuation judgments. In contrast, long investors perceive risk as more symmetric, and largely disregard risk in forming their valuation judgments. Taken together, these results suggest an unintended consequence of communicating risk in financial reports, in that not all investors interpret risk in a similar way, and some disregard risk in judging value. Finally, our results have implications for others who assess risk – including preparers, auditors and analysts – given that each of these groups may have directional goals for firm performance. Keywords: financial disclosures, risk perceptions, directional goals, valuation Data availability: Contact the authors. I. Introduction A longstanding and fundamental premise in accounting and finance research is that risk affects firm value: given a level of expected return, increased risk reduces value. Because of the link between risk and value, a key purpose of financial disclosures is to communicate risk to market participants. In this paper, we test two important links in the assumed risk-value relation, plus a boundary condition for this relation. First, we test how investors perceive risk in response to financial disclosures that convey some uncertainty. Second, we test how risk perceptions are incorporated into investors’ judgments of firm value. In addition, we test directional goals for positive firm performance as a potential boundary condition for these links. Testing the effect of disclosures on risk perceptions, and the link between risk perceptions and value, is important for several reasons. First, the psychology literature on risk perceptions indicates that people’s risk perceptions do not always match the way in which risk is defined in formal models (e.g., Slovic 1987; Koonce, McAnally and Mercer 2005). Thus, the links between disclosures and risk perceptions, and between risk perceptions and value, are not a foregone conclusion. Second, standard setters and regulators are clearly interested in conveying information about risk to investors, since many mandatory disclosures are intended to communicate risk information (Linsmeier and Pearson 1997; SEC 1997; ASC 715, 820 and 860 [FASB 2014]). Thus, they are likely interested in how investors evaluate such disclosures, particularly if all users do not evaluate risk in the same way. Third, it is important to test how directional goals moderate risk perceptions and the link between risk and value, because many financial statement users hold long or, more rarely, short positions in the firms they analyze, and thus have a directional goal for positive or negative firm performance. While prior research in accounting has shown earnings forecasts and bid prices in asset markets move in line with 1 investors’ directional goals (e.g., Hales 2007; Seybert and Bloomfield 2009; Han and Tan 2010), we investigate how directional goals not only affect a different type of measure – risk perceptions – but also the influence of risk perceptions in assessing firm value. That is, we propose that differences in risk perceptions and the extent to which they are considered in subsequent judgments may be important underlying factors that help to explain the effects of motivated reasoning documented by prior research. Drawing on theory and previous research on risk perceptions and directional goals, we develop two hypotheses. The first hypothesis focuses on perceptions of risk and how directional goals moderate these perceptions. Building on prior research that suggests individuals focus on negative aspects of risk, we predict that prospective investors (i.e., those without directional goals) will perceive the potential for loss as greater than the potential for gain. In contrast, because of their directional goals for positive firm performance, long investors will assess the potential for future loss (gain) as smaller (greater) than prospective investors; that is, their risk perceptions will be more symmetric. The second hypothesis focuses on how investors incorporate these risk perceptions in their valuation judgments. We predict that long investors will be less likely than prospective investors to incorporate their perceptions of risk into their estimates of firm value. That is, if motivated reasoning allows investors with directional goals to interpret risk more favorably, it may also allow these same investors to disregard risk when making related valuation judgments. This hypothesis challenges the common assumption that investors link risk and value. To test our hypotheses, we conduct an experiment in the context of fair value estimates. We first instantiate a directional goal for positive firm performance by assigning one group of participants to a long position in the stock of a real estate firm, while the other group of 2 participants is assigned to consider a prospective investment in the firm’s stock (and thus do not have a directional goal). We also vary the observability of the inputs to a fair value estimate (i.e., Level 2 and Level 3 in the fair value hierarchy in ASC 820 [FASB 2014]). Level 3 estimates are the most powerful setting in which to test our predictions because the high level of uncertainty in Level 3 estimates allows for the most flexibility in interpreting risk. However, it is important to examine whether our predictions also hold with Level 2 estimates. Although Level 2 estimates include less uncertainty than Level 3 estimates, they represent the majority of fair value estimates (Laux and Leuz 2010) and allow us to test whether directional goals can affect risk perceptions and valuation judgments even when there is relatively less flexibility for investors to exploit in order to reach their desired conclusions. Following these manipulations, participants evaluate the risk and valuation effects of an accounting estimate related to the impaired value of land the firm is holding for development. Results of the experiment support our predictions. First, whereas prospective investors assess the probability and likely amount of a future economic loss as much higher than a future economic gain, long investors assess these probabilities and amounts as being more symmetric. That is, long investors judge the likelihood of a gain to be insignificantly different from the likelihood of a loss. This result is remarkable given that previous studies across multiple domains suggest people tend to focus on downside risk (Vlek and Stallen 1981; Fischoff, Slovic and Lichtenstein 1982; Loewenstein, Weber, Hsee and Welch 2001). Our results thus support the adage that “losses loom larger than gains” (Kahneman and Tversky 1981, 456) for prospective investors’ risk perceptions, but directional goals appear to substantially reduce long investors’ emphasis on the potential for loss. Further, we find that these results hold for both Level 2 and Level 3 estimates, suggesting that investors perceive sufficient subjectivity in Level 2 estimates 3 that they can reach their desired conclusions with respect to risk. Second, in judging the effect of risk on firm value, we find that long investors’ risk perceptions (i.e., the potential for loss and gain) are not significantly associated with their valuation judgments; by contrast, the potential for loss and gain are both significant determinants of value for prospective investors. Further, risk is generally less important in explaining the valuation effects of accounting estimates for long compared to prospective investors (as measured by adjusted R2 values from regressions of risk variables on valuation judgments). These results suggest that the fundamental link between risk perceptions and firm value essentially breaks down for long investors.1 An additional out-of-sample survey provides convergent evidence that long investors are biased when they fail to incorporate their risk assessments into their valuation judgments. In this survey, we present unbiased investors (i.e., those with no directional goals) with the assessments of potential for gain and loss made by long investors in our primary experiment. We find that these assessments of the potential for gain and loss are significant determinants of unbiased investors’ valuation judgments (whereas they did not affect long investors’ valuation judgments in our experiment). Finally, additional analyses confirm that our results are robust to alternative measures of risk perceptions suggested by prior research. Our study has implications for both theory and practice. We extend prior research on directional goals by showing that these goals affect both investors’ risk perceptions and the way in which risk perceptions are incorporated into valuation judgments. Moreover, our results identify directional goals as a boundary condition on the idea that “losses loom larger than gains” in judging risk, thus extending research on the conditions under which people are more sensitive 1 As discussed in more detail in Section IV, we confirm that (1) our manipulations affect risk perceptions but not participants’ risk preferences, and (2) results are robust to controlling for participants’ underlying risk preferences. 4 to losses than gains (e.g., Novemsky and Kahneman 2005; Ariely, Huber and Wertenbroch 2005) Further, our results suggest that previously documented effects of directional goals (for example, on investors’ earnings forecasts and bids in asset markets) may be explained in part by directional goals causing differences in perceptions of risk and the extent to which these perceptions affect subsequent judgments. Our study also has implications for other users of accounting estimates – including preparers, auditors, and analysts – each of whom may have directional goals (Hackenbrack and Nelson 1996; Lin and McNichols 1998; Michaely and Womack 1999; Kadous, Kennedy and Peecher 2003). As one example, prior to the financial crisis of 2008, ratings agencies were paid by the firms issuing the instruments they were rating, so their analysts’ interpretation of risk may have been influenced by a goal to generate more ratings business (e.g., Silver 2012, 29-30; Jollineau, Tanlu and Winn 2014). Given the catastrophic losses that subsequently occurred, analysts appear to have underestimated downside risk, which may have contributed to the broader crisis. For accounting practitioners and regulators, our results are directly informative about the effect of financial statement estimates on users’ judgments. Given the risk inherent in relying on accounting estimates, it is important to understand how financial statement users interpret risk and incorporate risk perceptions into subsequent judgments. Our results are informative on this issue because we document effects of accounting estimates that are likely unanticipated by regulators relying on standard economic theory, which assumes that risk information will be incorporated into valuation judgments. Of course, our results do not suggest that regulators should abandon the use of estimates, but that the effects we document should be weighed against the potential benefits of mandating the extensive incorporation of estimates in financial disclosures. 5 The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. We provide background and develop hypotheses in Section 2. We discuss the experimental method we employ in Section 3, and discuss results of the experiment in Section 4. We summarize and conclude in Section 5. II. Previous Literature, Theory, and Hypotheses Risk perceptions and financial disclosures Investors face a variety of risks when deciding whether, and how much, to invest in a given firm (e.g., market risk, liquidity risk, business risk, exchange rate risk, etc.). Since many of these sources of risk are directly or indirectly discussed in firms’ financial reports, investors also face the risk associated with interpreting the information provided in these disclosures. That is, investors face risk both with respect to the underlying assets and liabilities themselves in a firm, but also in interpreting related disclosures that can never fully convey all relevant information. The standard assumption in accounting research is based on economic theory, and suggests that investors will use financial disclosures to form expectations about risk associated with the future potential for gain or loss. Further, the expectation is that investors will incorporate these risk assessments into decisions about how much capital to provide to the firm (see Beyer et al. 2010). This expectation is consistent with formal valuation models in accounting and finance, to which risk, defined as variance, is a key input (e.g., Merton 1973; Jorgensen and Kirschenheiter 2003). While formal models define risk as variance, research across a variety of domains suggests that individual perceptions of risk are largely focused on the potential for negative outcomes, with much less emphasis on the potential for positive outcomes (Vlek and Stallen 1981, Fischoff, Slovic and Lichtenstein 1982; Loewenstein, Weber, Hsee and Welch 2001).2 Relatedly, people 2 Slovic (1987) summarizes previous work on risk perceptions and identifies two dimensions (“dread” and the “unknown”) to explain how people perceive risk. In an accounting context, Koonce et al. (2005) show that these 6 tend to be loss averse, in that they prefer avoiding potential losses to pursuing potential gains, even when such choices are riskless (e.g., Kahneman and Tversky 1981, Tversky and Kahneman 1991). Taken together, previous research finds substantial evidence that people tend to focus the potential for loss over the potential for gain in assessing risk, and tend to be more sensitive to losses than to gains. The effect of directional goals on beliefs and behavior The theory of motivated reasoning predicts that goals and motivation influence the process by which people form judgments, with the result that judgments tend to be biased in favor of people’s preferred conclusions, at least within reason (Kunda 1990, Ditto and Lopez 1992, Boiney et al. 1997). The theory divides judgments into two types: those in which an individual has a goal to arrive at the most accurate conclusion (an “accuracy goal”), and those in which the individual has a goal to arrive at a conclusion consistent with a particular preference or goal (a “directional goal”). For our purposes in this study, a key distinction is that long investors have a directional goal for positive firm performance, while prospective investors do not have directional goals (although they may have an accuracy goal in that they would like to make an accurate assessment of a firm’s investment potential). The type of goal associated with a particular judgment influences how information is processed (Kunda 1990). Accuracy goals typically lead people to adopt strategies considered most appropriate to arrive at an accurate judgment, for example attending to more, and more relevant, information, and by expending more effort processing the information considered. Directional goals, in contrast, typically lead people to non-consciously adopt strategies that dimensions have additional explanatory power over more traditional risk measures for explaining the risk associated with financial instruments. We measure these dimensions in our study and use them as alternative measures of risk perception as robustness tests in our analyses. 7 support their desired conclusions. Thus, directional goals lead people to selectively search their memory for supportive knowledge and beliefs. Supporting this theory, a number of accounting studies have demonstrated that the beliefs and behavior of auditors and investors are biased by directional goals. For example, Hackenbrack and Nelson (1996) find that auditors’ preference for accepting client-preferred accounting treatments leads them to interpret accounting standards in ways that allow them to accept such treatments. Building on this result, Kadous, Kennedy and Peecher (2003) find that adding an accuracy goal, in the form of a quality assessment, to a directional preference for accepting a client-preferred treatment, amplifies the effect of the directional preference. Among investors, Hales (2007) finds that long investors forecast higher earnings than short investors, even when firm fundamentals are held constant. Han and Tan (2010) show that these effects are especially apparent when management earnings guidance is presented in range form and conveys positive news. Thayer (2011) finds that directional goals influence the information sought out by investors, with some investors choosing to access preference-consistent information even when it is of low credibility. Seybert and Bloomfield (2009) show that traders in asset markets make bids biased by their preferences about future outcomes, and that these bids provoke even more optimistic beliefs among other traders. Finally, Fanning, Agoglia and Piercey (2014) provide evidence that investors’ risk perceptions are influenced by the quantity of risk disclosures, and that this relation varies with directional goals. To summarize, motivated reasoning predicts that people process and interpret information in ways that allow them to support directional goals while maintaining an “illusion of objectivity” by selectively engaging and/or combining memories and beliefs to justify their preferred conclusion (Kunda 1990, 482-3). When faced with an accounting estimate, the reliance on which 8 entails risk, financial statement users may justify their preferred conclusion (e.g., that the firm will perform well in the future) by interpreting risk in a way that bolsters the evidence for that conclusion. As such, financial statement users with directional goals are likely to interpret the risk associated with accounting estimates in ways that allow them to support their preference for positive firm performance. We extend the literature in this area in two ways. First, while prior research has focused on how investors use motivated reasoning to arrive at desired conclusions related to firm value (for example, in their earnings forecasts and market bid prices), we are one of the first studies to examine how motivated reasoning might influence risk perceptions, which standard economic theory indicates should influence conclusions about firm value.3 Thus, our study seeks to shed light on the process underlying previous results. Second, we explicitly test how a directional goal affects the link between risk perceptions and value, and whether a directional goal leads to biased judgments. Hypotheses Our hypotheses focus on the risk associated with an accounting estimate. As noted, motivated reasoning requires a certain degree of flexibility or ambiguity for individuals with directional goals to gather evidence in support of their preferred conclusions while maintaining an illusion of objectivity (Kunda 1990, Kadous et al. 2003). Thus, it is important that flexibility exists that financial statement users with directional goals can exploit to reach their desired conclusion. The uncertainty associated with accounting estimates provides that flexibility. When faced with an accounting estimate, there are at least two opportunities for investors to 3 One exception is Fanning et al. (2014) which provides evidence that overall risk perceptions are influenced by the quantity of risk disclosures, and that this relation varies with directional goals. In contrast, we hold disclosure quantity constant and test the effect of directional goals on the gain and loss components of risk, and on how these components of risk influence perceptions of firm value. 9 engage in motivated reasoning. The first is in assessing the risk associated with the estimate. Based on previous research showing that people focus on the potential for loss over the potential for gain in assessing risk, we expect prospective investors (those without directional goals) to assess the potential for loss to be greater than the potential for gain. However, we expect investors with directional goals to exploit the flexibility in accounting estimates to support their preferred conclusions. We therefore predict that long investors will interpret the risk associated with accounting estimates more favorably than prospective investors, such that they judge downside risk less negatively and the upside more favorably. Hypothesis 1: Prospective investors will judge the potential for loss associated with an accounting estimate to be greater than the potential for gain, but this difference will be smaller for long investors. While assessing the risk of an accounting estimate provides one opportunity for investors to support their preferred conclusions via motivated reasoning, assessing the effect of the estimate on firm value provides another. Although much of the research on motivated reasoning focuses on how directional goals bias individuals’ processing of information, there is also evidence to suggest that directional goals will affect whether certain information is considered at all. In arriving at their desired conclusions, individuals often fail to search for, or tend to dismiss, evidence that does not support their preferred conclusion (Ditto and Lopez 1992). Related research in the literature on message persuasiveness suggests that, even when facing information that is relatively difficult to refute, individuals with a goal to reach a desired conclusion appear to be able to isolate negative information and minimize its impact on subsequent judgments (Ahluwalia 2000). Thus, in our setting, even though investors provide risk and valuation judgments in tandem, we predict that long investors are more likely to minimize the relation between risk information and related valuation judgments. In other words, we predict that long 10 investors will be less likely than prospective investors to incorporate their risk judgments into their estimates of firm value.4 Hypothesis 2: Perceptions of risk are more likely to affect the valuation judgments of prospective investors than long investors. III. Method Design overview and participants To test our predictions, we conducted an experiment with a 2 × 2 between-subjects design with investor type (prospective vs. long) and fair value input level (Level 2 vs. Level 3) as manipulated independent factors. The investor type manipulation allows us to compare the risk perceptions of investors with directional goals for positive firm performance (long investors) to those without directional goals (prospective investors). The fair value input manipulation plays two roles in our design. From a theory perspective, it allows us to test whether investors’ propensity to engage in motivated reasoning is moderated by level of uncertainty. From a practical perspective, it allows us to test whether the effects of directional goals generalize to multiple types of estimates. Experimental materials were randomly distributed to 198 masters of accounting students at a large public university. Sixty-one students completed and returned the materials. They participated in this and another experiment in return for a cash payment (calculated as described below) and a chance to win one of five $100 participation prizes in a random draw. The experimental conditions in this experiment were counterbalanced with conditions in the other experiment, and we detect no carryover effects in our analyses. At the time of the experiment, 4 Alternatively, it is possible that long investors would use motivated reasoning to incorporate the potential for gains into their valuation judgments while ignoring the potential for losses. However, motivated reasoning theory suggests this is unlikely due to reasonableness constraints. If long investors recognize that risk assessments should influence valuation judgments (i.e., by incorporating gains), it is likely to be psychologically unjustifiable to simultaneously ignore losses. Because of this, we instead predict that long investors will instead prefer to limit the influence of both gain and loss risk assessments on their valuation judgments. 11 participants had completed an average of 14 accounting courses and three finance courses. All participants had some full-time work experience in accounting or finance, averaging eight months at the time of the experiment. Forty-eight percent (29 of 61) had previously invested in debt or equity securities and ninety-seven percent (59 of 61) planned to do so in the future, suggesting that these participants were reasonable proxies for investors. Case materials and procedures The experiment consisted of three parts, divided into numbered envelopes to ensure that participants worked through materials in order. Figure 1 describes the tasks participants completed in each of these three parts. <INSERT FIGURE 1 HERE> Part one & investor type manipulation In the first envelope, participants received information about two hypothetical real estate firms, Lanark Residential and Moray Residential. We manipulated investor type at two levels— long and prospective—using an approach adapted from previous research on directional goals (e.g., Hales 2007). First, long investors chose to take a long position in one of the two firms. Prior to making this choice, long investors were informed that their task was to select the firm that they believed would be the better performer as the firm that they would invest in, and that their compensation would depend on whether the firm they chose was actually the better performer of the two firms. Specifically, they would be paid $15 if the firm they chose to invest in was the better performer and $5 otherwise. In contrast, prospective investors were informed that their task was to evaluate the companies as a potential investment and that they would be paid $10 for providing their judgments on one of the firms to be chosen at random (Han & Tan 2010, Fanning et al. 2014). 12 Next, all participants viewed summary information for each firm, including three financial statement ratios and four qualitative statements about the firms’ operations (see Figure 2). Importantly, this information holds constant the underlying economics of the two firms by deriving all six ratios (three for each firm) from the same underlying financial statements. Consistent with the two firms having the same underlying economics, the choice of firm did not affect the information provided about the accounting estimate in the second part of the experiment; that is, the information in part two was identical regardless of which firm was selected. After responding to a comprehension check question to ensure they understood how their compensation would be determined, participants moved on to part two. <INSERT FIGURE 2 HERE> Part two & fair value input level manipulation In part two, long investors were provided with two sealed envelopes (one for each firm), but opened only the one corresponding to the firm they chose in part one.5 Prospective investors opened the envelope provided to them, which contained materials for one of the two firms chosen at random. These envelopes contained summary information from the firm’s financial statements, including two line items from the firm’s most recent quarterly financial statements related to land held for development. The first line item came from the income statement and listed a loss of $21.152 million on land held for development. The second line item came from the balance sheet and listed land held for development at a net carrying value of $267.095 million. To ensure participants recognized that these values were material for the firm, they were also told that the impairment loss was equal to approximately 30% of the firm’s net income in the previous year, 5 One of the experimenters confirmed that the seal on the other envelope had not been broken prior to authorizing each participant’s payment. 13 and that the impaired value of the land represented approximately 20% of the firm’s total assets. Participants then viewed a note containing further information about the land’s fair value. The note disclosed the reason for the impairment, the designation of the fair value as either Level 2 or Level 3 within the fair value hierarchy, and a description of the valuation technique used in accordance with fair value disclosure requirements in ASC 820 (FASB 2014). In Level 2 conditions, the fair value of the land parcels was estimated based on recent sales of several comparable parcels. In Level 3 conditions, the fair value of the land parcels was generated using an expected present value technique. All disclosures were adapted from actual disclosures and examples provided in accounting standards. The appendix contains further details of the fair value disclosure manipulation for Moray; all information was identical for Lanark except the name of the firm. After reviewing this information, participants responded to dependent measures. Part three and payment In part three, participants responded to several post-task questions and received a payment summary page. The payment summary page informed long investors whether their chosen firm performed better; the better-performing firm was randomized to avoid participants learning which firm was the better performer from their peers. Prospective investors were reminded that they would be paid a fixed amount. All participants were provided instructions on how to collect their payment. Specifically, they brought the payment summary page and completed materials to the office of one of the experimenters to receive payment and register for the prize drawing. Dependent measures In part two of the experiment, participants responded to questions designed to measure the risk and valuation effects of the impaired land. We use four questions to capture perceptions 14 associated with the risk of gain and/or loss: (1) the probability of a further economic loss to the company from the land, (2) the amount of a further economic loss to the company from the land, (3) the probability of a further economic gain to the company from the land, (4) the amount of a further economic gain to the company from the land. A fifth question asked about the probability of the status quo (i.e., neither an economic loss nor an economic gain from the land). In addition, because prior research has also identified additional, “behavioral”, dimensions of risk, called “dread” and the “unknown” (Slovic 1987; Koonce et al. 2005), we asked a further seven questions related to these behavioral risk dimensions as a robustness check on the more traditional measures of risk as the potential for loss and gain. We conduct supplemental analyses using these behavioral risk measures discussed in Section IV. Finally, two questions asked about the overall level of risk associated with the land held for development and about how the land affected the value of the company. IV. Results Manipulation checks To assess the effectiveness of the investor type manipulation, we asked participants how their pay would be determined. The two possible responses were: “I will be paid $15 if the firm I chose is the better performer, or $5 otherwise” and “I will be paid a fixed amount of $10”.6 Eighty-seven percent of participants correctly indicated their condition and responses are significantly associated with experimental condition (χ2 = 33.87, p < 0.01), indicating a successful manipulation of investor type. To verify the effectiveness of the fair value input level manipulation, we asked participants what level of the fair value hierarchy the value of the land held for development was considered to be: “Level 2” or “Level 3”. Ninety-seven percent of 6 For all results, long investors’ responses do not differ depending on which of the two hypothetical firms they chose. 15 participants correctly indicated their condition and these responses are also significantly associated with condition (χ2 = 53.21, p < 0.01), indicating a successful manipulation of fair value input level.7 Tests of H1 H1 predicts that prospective investors will perceive greater potential for loss than potential for gain, and that this difference will be smaller for long investors. To test this, we measured both the probability and the likely amount of a future gain or loss on the land held for development. To create a single measure of potential for loss or gain, we multiply the probability of a loss or gain (as a percentage) by the amount of a gain or loss. Table 1, Panel A presents cell sizes, means, and standard deviations for both the individual and combined measures.8 Since results are inferentially identical whether we use the individual measures or the combined measure, we focus on the combined measure for the sake of brevity. Figure 3 also depicts the pattern of cell means for the combined potential for loss or gain measure by experimental condition. <INSERT TABLE 1 & FIGURE 3 HERE> Table 1, Panel B presents an analysis of variance (ANOVA) model of the potential for loss or gain. The significant within-subjects effect of the gain/loss variable indicates a significant onaverage difference between the potential for gain and the potential for loss (F = 20.77, p < 0.01). Of interest in testing H1, however, is the gain/loss × investor type interaction (F = 11.08, p < 0.01). This indicates that the two-way interactions depicted in Panels A and B of Figure 3 are significant, in support of H1. We do not observe a significant interaction of gain/loss with fair 7 Excluding the manipulation failures yields inferentially identical results. An additional risk question asked about the probability of the status quo (i.e., neither a loss nor a gain related to the land held for development). We detect no main or interactive effects of our manipulated variables on this measure (all p-values > 0.29). 8 16 value level, or a significant three-way interaction. This indicates that neither the relative potential for gain versus loss nor the significant two-way interaction of gain/loss with investor type differ significantly between Level 2 and Level 3 fair value conditions. Planned contrasts in Table 1, Panel C provide additional support for H1. Specifically, prospective investors assess the potential for a future loss on the land as greater than the potential for a future gain (t = 5.17, p < 0.01, one-tailed). By contrast, long investors view the potential for loss as not significantly different from the potential for gain (t = 1.13, p = 0.27, two-tailed). In other words, while prospective investors’ perceptions are heavily weighted toward downside risk, long investors’ perceptions of upside and downside risk are statistically symmetric. For completeness, we also confirm that long investors’ assessments of the potential for loss are lower than those of prospective investors (t = 2.30, p = 0.01, one-tailed), whereas long investors’ assessment of the potential for gain are higher than those of prospective investors (t = 2.49, p < 0.01, one-tailed).9 Taken together, these results provide strong support for H1. Specifically, prospective investors judge the potential for loss to be significantly greater than the potential for gain, long investors view the upside and downside potential as more symmetric. Tests of H2 Table 2, Panel A presents cell sizes, means, and standard deviations by experimental condition for participants’ valuation judgments (i.e., the effect of the land held for development on firm value). Before testing the effect of investors’ risk perceptions on their valuation 9 We confirm that our manipulations affect risk perceptions but not participants’ risk preferences. Specifically, we measure risk preferences by eliciting participants’ level of agreement with the statement, “I believe protecting the principal of my investment is more important than the potential for achieving high returns.” Participants responded on a 101-point scale (0 = “Strongly Disagree”, 100 = “Strongly Agree”). Results of an ANOVA with risk preferences as the dependent variable indicate no significant main or interactive effects of investor type or fair value level (all p-values > 0.10). Further, including risk preferences as a covariate in our test of H1 does not affect our inferences. Specifically, the gain/loss × investor type interaction remains highly significant (F = 10.34, p < 0.01). 17 judgments predicted in H2, we first consider the effect of our manipulated variables, investor type and fair value input level, on valuation judgments. The ANOVA presented in Panel B of Table 2 indicates a main effect of both of these variables on valuation judgments. First, consistent with motivated reasoning theory, the main effect of investor type indicates that the land has a significantly more negative effect on the valuation judgments of prospective investors than long investors (F = 5.30, p = 0.03). Second, the main effect of fair value input level indicates that the Level 2 estimate has a significantly less negative effect than the Level 3 estimate on investors’ valuation judgments (F = 4.73, p = 0.03). These two main effects are also apparent in the pattern of cell means depicted in Figure 4. The interaction of investor type and fair value level is not significant (F = 0.03, p = 0.86) <INSERT TABLE 2 & FIGURE 4 HERE> We next turn to formal tests of H2. H2 predicts that perceptions of risk are more likely to affect the valuation judgments of prospective investors than long investors. Panel C of Table 2 presents regressions of valuation judgments on participants’ perceptions of the potential for gain and loss. In support of H2, we observe that the coefficient on potential for loss is negative and significant (t = -2.55, p < 0.01, one-tailed) for prospective investors, but does not differ significantly from zero for long investors (t = 1.19, p > 0.10). Similarly, the potential for gain significantly affects prospective investors’ valuation judgments (t = 3.66, p < 0.01), but does not significantly affect long investors’ valuation judgments (t =1.18, p > 0.10). These results support H2, indicating that long investors appear to ignore risk (both upside and downside) in assessing the effect of a fair value estimate on firm value. Panel C of Table 2 also includes adjusted R2 values for the regressions of prospective and long investors’ risk perceptions on valuation judgments. In least squares regressions like these, 18 R2 captures the strength of the association between the predictor variables (here, investors’ risk perceptions) and the dependent variable (here, investors’ valuation judgments) (Hays 1994). Adjusted R2 makes a downward adjustment for the number of predictor variables in the model, since unadjusted R2 can be artificially inflated by adding additional predictors. The adjusted R2 values for the regression of risk perceptions on valuation judgments are considerably higher for prospective investors than for long investors. Specifically, the adjusted R2 for prospective investors is 0.37, compared to only 0.04 for long investors. Thus, consistent with the importance of risk as an input in formal valuation models, risk is an important determinant of prospective investors’ valuation judgments. By contrast, risk perceptions explain very little of the variation in long investors’ valuation judgments.10,11 In the analyses reported above, we estimate separate regressions for long and prospective investors so that we can assess the explanatory power of risk perceptions on value separately for each group via R2 and adjusted R2 values. To provide corroborating evidence, we also estimate a single regression (untabulated) with interaction terms for the incremental effect of the gain and loss risk dimensions on prospective investors’ valuation judgments. These results are again consistent with H2. Specifically, the coefficients on potential for loss and potential for gain are insignificant (loss: t = 1.21, p = 0.23; gain: t = 1.20, p = 0.24; both two-tailed), while the interaction of prospective investor status and potential for loss is negative and significant (t = 2.37, p = 0.01, one-tailed) and the interaction of prospective investor status and potential for gain 10 A comparison of variances confirms that these differences in adjusted R2 values are not caused by greater dispersion in long investors’ risk perceptions (Levene’s test, all p-values > 0.10). 11 We confirm that these results are robust to controlling for participants’ underlying risk preferences. Specifically, including risk preferences as a covariate in the regressions in Panel C of Table 2 does not affect our inferences. Controlling for risk preferences, prospective investors’ valuation judgments are significantly affected by both potential for loss and potential for gain (both p-values < 0.01, one tailed), but long investors’ valuation judgments are not significantly affected by potential for loss or potential for gain (both p-values > 0.10, one-tailed). 19 is positive and marginally significant (t = 1.50, p = 0.07, one-tailed), indicating that risk significantly affects prospective investors’ valuation judgments, but not those of long investors. Supplemental Study: Long Investors and the Link between Risk Perceptions and Value We conduct a supplemental study to provide convergent evidence that long investors are biased when they neglect to incorporate risk assessments into their valuation judgments. On its face, it may seem reasonable that a symmetric risk of gain and loss would lead to no change in valuation judgments. For example, if an investor learns that an asset currently priced at $100 has a 10% chance of a $50 gain and a 10% chance of a $50 loss, then it may seem reasonable to conclude that the expected value of the asset has not changed and the asset is still worth $100. However, it is unreasonable to assume that the aforementioned asset should have the same value as one currently priced at $100 that has a 50% chance of a $50 loss and a 50% chance of a $50 gain. That is, investors should be willing to pay more for an asset with less variance in the distribution of future outcomes. To provide evidence of this particular to our setting, we conduct an out-of-sample survey using 94 participants from Amazon’s Mechanical Turk (MTurk) platform. We provide all participants with background information on Lanark Residential, one of the hypothetical firms from our primary experiment. We include information related to the impairment loss on land held for development. Participants are randomly assigned to either the condition using Level 2 or Level 3 inputs. We then present all participants with scenarios showing potential distributions for gain or loss associated with the land. These scenarios are drawn from actual responses made by long investors in our primary experiment. For example, if a given participant indicated probability of a loss (gain) was 44% (47%) with an estimated magnitude on our 101-point scale (0 = zero gain, 100 = very large gain) of 22 (27), we converted the magnitude to dollar amounts 20 of $8,800,000 ($10,800,000) and told them to imagine that there was a 44% chance that the company would suffer a loss of $8,800,000, and a 47% chance that the company would experience a future gain of $10,800,000, on the land held for development.12 In total, participants assigned to the Level 2 (Level 3) group saw 11 (15) separate scenarios.13 For each scenario, participants then respond to a valuation judgment question that is identical to the one used in our primary between-subjects experiment. We present all scenarios on the same page in order to increase the chance that participants attend to and process differences in the scenarios, and consider how each scenario should affect valuation. Importantly, we do not give participants in this supplemental study any directional goals. Thus their valuation judgments in response to the different scenarios serve as a benchmark to determine whether, and how, unbiased observers perceive that the long investors’ perceptions of the potential for loss and gains should affect valuation judgments. As shown in Table 3, we find that both the gain potential and loss potential are significant in explaining participants’ valuation judgments. Greater loss (gain) potential is significantly associated with decreased (increased) valuation judgments (p<0.01, two-tailed for both loss and gain).14 Recall that these same perceptions did not significantly influence long investors’ valuation judgments in our primary experiment. These results therefore further support that long investors in our primary experiment are biased by their directional goals to ignore the fundamental relationship between risk perceptions and firm valuation. 12 In all cases we made the conversion by dividing responses on the 101-point scale by 100 and then multiplying by $40,000,000. For ease of interpretation, Table 3 further scales the calculated gain and loss potentials by dividing each by $1,000,000. 13 The difference in the number of scenarios presented is driven by two things. First, the actual number of participants in each cell of our primary experiment differs to due random assignment (12 in Level 2 and 15 in Level 3 for long investors). Second, one of the responses from the Level 2 condition indicated a 70% chance of gain and 70% chance of loss. Because this adds to greater than 100%, we exclude this response from our adapted scenarios. 14 Our inferences are unchanged if we instead use rank regressions for each gain or loss potential. Both gain and loss are still significant in explaining valuation judgments (p<0.01, one-tailed, untabulated, for both). 21 <INSERT TABLE 3 HERE> Robustness: Behavioral Risk Measures As discussed in Section III, we also asked participants seven questions designed to measure risk perceptions from the behavioral perspective identified in prior literature (Slovic 1987; Koonce et al. 2005). These questions capture aspects of both “dread” and the “unknown”, and include: (1) the extent to which the land causes worry, (2) the likelihood that the risks from the land are likely to be catastrophic, (3) whether participants would invest voluntarily in a firm that they were aware held the land, (4) management’s ability to control the risk of the land, (5) whether the risks are new, novel ones or old, familiar ones, (6) the extent to which the risks from the land are known precisely by investors, and (7) the extent to which the risks from the land are known precisely by company management.15 Responses to the first four (last three) of these questions capture the “dread” (“unknown”) dimension of risk. Slovic (1987) finds that the “dread” dimension is particularly associated with risk judgments, whereas the “unknown” dimension reflects the extent to which a particular phenomenon provides information about risks in related areas. Thus we would expect directional goals to primarily affect the “dread” dimension. Descriptive statistics for these measures and comparisons between long and prospective investors’ judgments are shown in Table 4. Of the four measures associated with dread, two differ significantly between long and prospective investors. Specifically, the potential for the 15 We measured the same decision theory and behavioral risk variables as Koonce et al. (2005) with one exception. The results reported in Koonce et al (2005) suggest that the effects of the immediacy variable are weak and inconsistent in a financial statement context. Specifically, immediacy does not significantly affect risk judgments in either experiment reported in that paper. In addition, although immediacy is classified as an “unknown” risk variable in Slovic (1987), it loads—albeit weakly—on the factor associated with “dread” in the Koonce et al. (2005) data. As a result, and because we did not specify a particular timeframe for the investment being considered in our study, we did not ask a question about immediacy. 22 land to lead to catastrophe is rated as higher by prospective investors than by long investors (t = 1.69, p = 0.05, one-tailed), and prospective investors indicate that they would be less likely than long investors to take on the risks associated with the land voluntarily (t = 2.01, p = 0.02, onetailed). These results indicate that prospective investors assess these dimensions of risk more negatively than long investors, providing additional support for H1. The other two variables associated with dread—worry and control—do not differ significantly between long and prospective investors (both p-values > 0.10). We also do not observe significant differences between prospective and long investors’ judgments for the variables associated with the unknown (all p-values > 0.10).16 <INSERT TABLE 4 HERE> Consistent with prior research on risk perceptions (e.g., Slovic 1987, Koonce et al. 2005), we next conduct a factor analysis on all of the risk perception measures, including both the potential for gain and loss variables and the seven behavioral variables. This analysis serves two functions. First, it confirms that our measures capture the dimensions of risk suggested by theory and previous research (e.g., Slovic 1987, Koonce et al. 2005). Second, reducing the data to fewer dimensions reduces collinearity and improves interpretability for the regressions we will use to provide additional evidence for H2 (Dunteman 1989). Results of this factor analysis are shown in Panel A of Table 5. The analysis reveals five factors: one each for the potential for loss and potential for gain, as well as one “dread” factor and two “unknown” factors.17 These factors thus appear consistent with both theory and prior research. 16 We observe no significant effect of fair value input level on the behavioral variables, with one exception. A main effect of fair value level on worry indicates that Level 3 estimates cause more worry than Level 2 estimates (F = 5.14, p = 0.03). Further, we observe no significant interaction between investor type and fair value input level for any of the behavioral variables. 17 We follow Koonce et al. (2005) in using principal components extraction with varimax rotation to identify factors corresponding to risk dimensions. However, our results are robust to various alternative specifications, including least squares and maximum likelihood extraction methods and oblique (nonorthogonal) rotation. 23 Finally, as in our main test of H2, Panel B of Table 5 presents regressions of valuation judgments on the five risk factors identified in our factor analysis for prospective and long investors. In further support of H2, we observe that the coefficient on the potential for loss, potential for gain, and “dread” risk factors have the expected sign and differ significantly from zero (all p-values < 0.05, one-tailed) for prospective investors. For long investors, only the factor associated with potential for gain has a marginally significant effect on valuation judgments (t = 1.65, p = 0.06, one-tailed); none of the other risk factors have a significant effect on long investors’ valuation judgments. Further, the adjusted R2 is much higher for prospective investors (0.46) than for long investors (0.04). <INSERT TABLE 5 HERE> Combined, these supplemental analyses using measures from the behavioral perspective on risk indicate that our results are robust to alternative methods of measuring risk perceptions. They therefore provide additional support for the idea that prospective investors perceive more downside risk than long investors, and that long investors largely ignore risk in assessing the effect of a fair value estimate on firm value. V. Conclusion This study presents theory and experimental evidence that directional goals affect investors’ risk assessments and their incorporation of risk assessments into valuation judgments. Most notable are two new insights. First, long investors in our study view risk as symmetric, assessing the potential for future gain and loss as statistically equivalent. By contrast, and consistent with previous research on risk perceptions, prospective investors emphasize downside risk, assessing the potential for loss as higher than the potential for gain. Second, in judging the effect of an estimate on firm value, long investors in our study disregard risk. That is, despite risk being a 24 key input into formal models of firm value, and despite the fact that we ask participants to make valuation judgments immediately following their risk judgments, risk perceptions explain very little of the variation in long investors’ valuation judgments. Further, using an out-of-sample survey we provide convergent evidence that long investors are biased when they fail to incorporate risk assessments into their valuation judgments by showing that investors without directional goals do incorporate these very same risk assessments into their valuation judgments. These results challenge the link between risk perceptions and firm value that is often assumed in the accounting literature, in that directional goals can lead to a breakdown in this fundamental relationship. Our study of course has certain limitations, which in turn raise interesting questions for future research. First, we investigate the effect of directional goals for positive firm performance on investors’ perceptions of risk and their use of risk perceptions in valuation. We focus on directional goals for positive firm performance because this reflects the preferences of a majority of investors (e.g., Odean 1999) as well as financial statement preparers, auditors and analysts. However, certain participants in the financial reporting process have directional goals for negative firm performance, including recent examples of prominent activist investors taking short positions in firms (see, e.g., Schmidt et al. 2014 on Bill Ackman’s billion dollar short of Herbalife). Future research might investigate how such directional goals for negative performance influence perceptions of risk and the emphasis placed on risk in valuation. Second, we find that risk perceptions play very little role in determining long investors’ valuation judgments. However, because we focus on risk perceptions, we do not investigate other inputs to investors’ valuation judgments. Formal models suggest book value, expected future cash flows or earnings, and estimates of long-term growth as additional determinants of value. We leave it 25 to future research to determine how directional goals affect the weights placed on these or other determinants of value. Despite these limitations, our study contributes to the literatures on risk perceptions and the effects of directional goals on judgment. Our study also speaks directly to regulators and standard setters interested in how the increase in the use of estimates and, in turn, the increase in disclosures on estimate-related risks in financial reports affects users’ judgments. Our results suggest that one of the costs associated with mandating estimated-related risk disclosures is that the information may be interpreted differently depending on the investor’s directional goal, particularly given the inherent subjectivity in estimates that gives investors the flexibility to reach their desired conclusions. While explicit analysis of the costs and benefits of the mandatory disclosure regime has been rare historically, political pressure for cost-benefit analysis is high, and regulators have indicated some willingness to conduct such analyses as part of their rule-making process in the future (Committee on Oversight and Government Reform 2012, Kraus and Raso 2013). 26 References Ahluwalia, R. (2000). Examination of psychological processes underlying resistance to persuasion. Journal of Consumer Research, 27, 217-232. Ariely, D., J. Huber, & K. Wertenbroch. (2005). When do losses loom larger than gains? Journal of Marketing Research, 42, 134-138. Barth, M. (2006). Including estimates of the future in today’s financial statements. Accounting Horizons, 20, 271-285. Beyer, A., Cohen, D., Lys, T., & Walther, B. (2010). The financial reporting environment: Review of the recent literature. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 50, 296-343. Boiney, L., Kennedy, J., & Nye, P. (1997). Instrumental bias in motivated reasoning: More when more is needed. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 72,1-24. Committee on Oversight and Government Reform. (2012). The SEC’s aversion to cost-benefit analysis. Retrieved from http://oversight.house.gov/hearing/the-secs-aversion-to-cost-benefitanalysis/. Ditto, P., & Lopez, D. (1992). Motivated skepticism: Use of differential decision criteria for preferred and nonpreferred conclusions. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 63, 568-584. Dunteman, G. H. (1989). Principal Components Analysis. Newbury Park, CA: Sage. Fanning, K., Agoglia, C., & Piercey, M. D. (2014). Unintended consequences of lowering disclosure thresholds. Working Paper, University of Massachusetts Amherst and Villanova University. Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB). (2014). Accounting standards codification TM. Retrieved from http://asc.fasb.org/. Fischhoff, B., Slovic, P. & Lichtenstein, S. (1982). Lay foibles and expert fables in judgments about risk. American Statistician, 36, 240-255. Glover, J., Ijiri, Y., Levine, C. & Liang, P. (2005). Separating facts from forecasts in financial statements. Accounting Horizons, 19(4), 267-282. Hackenbrack, K., & Nelson, M. (1996). Auditors’ incentives and their application of financial accounting standards. The Accounting Review, 71, 43-59. Hales, J. (2007). Directional preferences, information processing, and investors’ forecasts of earnings. Journal of Accounting Research, 45, 607-628. Han, J., & Tan, H-T. (2010). Investors’ reactions to management earnings guidance: The joint effect of investment position, news valence, and guidance form. Journal of Accounting Research, 48, 81-104. Hays, W. L. (1994). Statistics. 5th edition. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth. 27 Jollineau, J., Tanlu, L., & Winn, A. (2014). Evaluating proposed remedies for credit rating agency failures. The Accounting Review, Forthcoming. Jorgensen, B., & Kirschenheiter, M. (2003). Discretionary risk disclosures. The Accounting Review, 78, 449-469. Kadous, K., Kennedy, S. J., & Peecher, M. E. (2003). The effect of quality assessment and directional goal commitment on auditors’ acceptance of client-preferred methods. The Accounting Review, 78, 759-778. Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1981). The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Science, 211(30), 453-458. Koonce, L., McAnally, M., & Mercer, M. (2005). How do investors judge the risk of financial items? The Accounting Review, 80, 221-241. Kraus, B. & Raso, C. (2013). Rational boundaries for SEC cost-benefit analysis. Yale Journal on Regulation, 30, 289-342. Kunda, Z. (1990). The case for motivated reasoning. Psychological Bulletin, 108, 480-98. Lambert, R., Leuz, C, & Verrecchia, R. (2007). Accounting information, disclosure, and the cost of capital. Journal of Accounting Research, 45, 385-420. Laux,C. & Leuz, C. (2010). Did fair-value accounting contribute to the financial crisis? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24, 93-118. Lin, H., & McNichols, M. (1998). Underwriting relationships, analysts’ earnings forecasts and investment recommendations. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 25, 101-127. Linsmeier, T., & Pearson, N. (1997). Quantitative disclosures of market risk in the SEC release. Accounting Horizons, 11, 107-135. Loewenstein, G., Weber, E., Hsee, C., & Welch, N. (2001). Risk as feelings. Psychological Bulletin, 127(2), 267-286 Merton, R. (1973). Theory of rational option pricing. Bell Journal of Economics, 4, 141-183. Michaely, R., & Womack, K. (1999). Conflict of interest and the credibility of underwriter analyst recommendations. The Review of Financial Studies, 12, 653-686. Novemsky, N. & D. Kahneman. (2005). The boundaries of loss aversion. Journal of Marketing Research, 42, 119-128. Odean, T. (1999). Do investors trade too much? The American Economic Review, 89, 12791298. Paredes, T. (2003). Blinded by the light: Information overload and its consequences for securities regulation. Washington University Law Quarterly, 81, 417-485. 28 Paredes, T. (2013). Remarks at the SEC speaks in 2013. Retrieved from www.sec.gov/News/Speech/Detail/Speech/1365171492408 Schmidt, M., Lipton, E., and Stevenson, A. (2014). After big bet, hedge fund pulls the levers of power. The New York Times. Retrieved from http://nyti.ms/1lmClDs Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC). (1997). Disclosure of Accounting Policies for Derivative Financial Instruments, and Derivative Commodity Instruments and Disclosure of Quantitative and Qualitative Information About Market Risk Inherent in Derivative Financial Instruments, Other Financial Instruments, and Derivative Commodity Instruments. Release Nos. 33-7386; 34-38223; IC-22487; F R No. 48; International Series No. 1047; File No. 27-35-95. Washington, D.C.: SEC. Seybert, N. & Bloomfield, R. (2009). Contagion of wishful thinking in markets. Management Science, 55, 738-751. Silver, N. (2012). The signal and the noise: Why so many predictions fail—but some don’t. New York: The Penguin Press. Slovic, P. (1987). Perception of risk. Science, 236, 280-285. Thayer, J. (2011). Determinants of investors' information acquisition: Credibility and confirmation. The Accounting Review, 86(1), 1-22. Tversky, A. & D. Kahneman. (1991). Loss aversion in riskless choice: A referent-dependent model. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 1039-1061. Vlek, C. & Stallen, P-J. (1981). Judging risks and benefits in the small and in the large. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 28, 235 271. Weber, E. (1988). A descriptive measure of risk. Acta Psychologica, 69, 185-203. 29 Appendix Fair value disclosures Part 1: Level 2 disclosures The following information is related to an impairment loss on land held for development by Moray, announced in the first quarter of 2014. The impairment loss is equal to approximately 30% of net income in the previous year (2013), and the impaired value of the land represents approximately 20% of Moray’s total assets. Income Statement ($ in thousands) Q1 2014 Expenses: Impairment loss – land held for development (see note 1) 21,152 Balance Sheet ($ in thousands) Assets: Land held for development (fair value net of impairment loss; see note 1) 267,095 Note 1 Assets measured at Fair Value on a Nonrecurring Basis ($ in thousands) Description Land held for development Fair Value at End of Period Fair Value Measurements Using Quoted Prices Significant in Active Other Significant Markets for Observable Unobservable Identical Assets Inputs Inputs (Level 1) (Level 2) (Level 3) Total Gains (Losses) $267,095 $267,095 $(21,152) Impairment Loss During the period, the Company concluded that market conditions did not support the development and construction of certain new apartment communities that were previously in planning. Accordingly, two land parcels held for development with a carrying value of $288,247 were written down to their fair value of $267,095, resulting in an impairment charge of $21,152, which was included in earnings for the period. Because the valuation of the land parcels incorporated significant other observable inputs, these values are considered to be Level 2 prices in the fair value hierarchy. Valuation Technique The fair value of the land parcels was estimated based on recent sales of several comparable land parcels. The sales prices of the comparable parcels were adjusted for differences including size, location, and zoning restrictions. 30 Part 2: Level 3 disclosures The following information is related to an impairment loss on land held for development by Moray, announced in the first quarter of 2014. The impairment loss is equal to approximately 30% of net income in the previous year (2013), and the impaired value of the land represents approximately 20% of Moray’s total assets. Income Statement ($ in thousands) Q1 2014 Expenses: Impairment loss – land held for development (see note 1) 21,152 Balance Sheet ($ in thousands) Assets: Land held for development (fair value net of impairment loss; see note 1) 267,095 Note 1 Assets measured at Fair Value on a Nonrecurring Basis ($ in thousands) Description Land held for development Fair Value at End of Period $267,095 Fair Value Measurements Using Quoted Prices Significant in Active Other Significant Markets for Observable Unobservable Identical Assets Inputs Inputs (Level 1) (Level 2) (Level 3) $267,095 Total Gains (Losses) $(21,152) Impairment Loss During the period, the Company concluded that market conditions did not support the development and construction of certain new apartment communities that were previously in planning. Accordingly, two land parcels held for development with a carrying value of $288,247 were written down to their fair value of $267,095, resulting in an impairment charge of $21,152, which was included in earnings for the period. Because the valuation of the land parcels incorporated significant unobservable inputs, these values are considered to be Level 3 prices in the fair value hierarchy. Valuation Technique The internal model used to estimate the fair value of the land parcels employed an expected present value technique. The model used a set of probability-weighted future cash flows to generate a single stream of expected cash flows. These expected cash flows were then adjusted using a risk-adjusted discount rate. The discount rate used in generating the fair value of the impaired land parcels was the Company’s estimated weighted average cost of capital (WACC) at the balance sheet date. The WACC is a weighted average of the Company’s cost of equity capital, estimated using the capital asset pricing model (CAPM), and the Company’s after-tax incremental borrowing rate for long-term debt. This valuation technique is the same as techniques used to measure similar assets in prior periods. 31 Figure 1 Summary of the three parts of the experiment Part One Part Two • All participants receive • Long (prospective) investors open information about two a sealed envelope related to the hypothetical real estate firms. firm they chose (were assigned to) in Part One. • Long (prospective) investors learn they will receive $15 if they • All participants view summary choose the better performer of the performance information from the two firms, and $5 otherwise (flat firm’s financial statements pay of $10). (identical regardless of which firm they chose or were assigned • Long (prospective) investors to). choose (are assigned to) one of the two firms. • Participants view a footnote containing additional information about an impairment related to the fair value of land held for development. The land represents a large portion of the firm’s total assets (20%) and its impairment loss represents a large proportion of the prior year’s net income (30%) to ensure participants view the values related to the land as material. • In the Level 2 (Level 3) condition of our experiment, the footnote discloses that the fair value of the land is estimated based on recent sales of comparable parcels (an expected present value technique). • Participants respond to dependent measures related to risk perceptions and valuation judgments. Part Three • Participants respond to post-task questions and receive a page summarizing their payment. • Long investors learn whether their chosen firm performed better (this was randomized), and prospective investors are reminded that they will be paid a fixed fee. • All participants are given instructions on how to collect their payment. This figure describes the tasks participants complete in each of the three parts of our experiment. Participants complete all tasks in a given part before moving on to the next part. 32 Figure 2 Summary firm information provided to all participants This figure presents the information provided to all participants in part one of the experiment. After reviewing this information, long investors chose to invest in one of the firms, while prospective investors were randomly assigned to one of the two firms. To hold underlying economics constant, the three ratios presented for each firm were derived from the same set of financial statements. 33 Figure 3 Effect of investor type on the potential for future gain or loss Panel A: Potential for gain/loss (Fair Value Level 2) 35.00 Potential for gain/loss 30.00 25.00 Prospective 20.00 Long 15.00 10.00 5.00 Loss Gain Panel B: Potential for gain/loss (Fair Value Level 3) 35.00 30.00 25.00 Prospective 20.00 Long 15.00 10.00 5.00 Loss Gain This figure depicts the observed pattern of cell means for assessments of the potential (probability × amount) for a future gain and loss based on whether (1) the participant is a long or prospective investor, and (2) whether the fair value estimate is based on Level 2 or Level 3 inputs. 34 Figure 4 Effect of investor type on valuation judgments Valuation Judgment 10 0 -10 Prospective -20 Long -30 -40 Level 2 Level 3 Fair Value Disclosures This figure depicts the observed pattern of cell means for the effect of impaired land held for development on firm value based on whether (1) the participant is a long or prospective investor, and (2) whether the fair value estimate is based on Level 2 or Level 3 inputs. 35 Table 1 Descriptive statistics and tests of H1 – Effect of investor type on potential for future gain or loss Panel A: Descriptive statistics – Means (std deviations) for judgments of probability and amount of future loss and gain Long Level 2 n = 12 Long Level 3 n = 16 Prospective Level 2 n = 16 Prospective Level 3 n = 17 Loss probability 46.25 (18.81) 45.25 (17.51) 58.31 (13.01) 61.18 (19.42) Loss amount 41.42 (19.41) 39.44 (18.18) 43.31 (17.72) 47.41 (26.74) Potential for loss (probability × amount) 20.28 (14.00) 19.03 (13.67) 26.54 (14.43) 32.62 (23.52) Gain probability 47.00 (11.18) 41.00 (13.69) 31.63 (17.35) 23.12 (17.76) Gain amount 42.50 (22.28) 30.25 (22.22) 27.94 (20.59) 19.53 (17.04) Potential for gain (probability × amount) 19.34 (9.22) 13.57 (11.58) 11.71 (13.18) 6.43 (11.71) Panel B: Potential for loss or gain – ANOVA SS df MS F-stat p-value 48.37 72.46 114.49 12125.93 1 1 1 57 48.37 72.46 114.49 212.74 0.23 0.34 0.54 0.64 0.56 0.47 4207.93 2243.54 471.92 1 1 1 4207.93 2243.54 471.92 20.77 11.08 2.33 <0.01 <0.01 0.13 87.70 1 87.70 0.43 0.51 11545.79 57 202.56 Prospective investors: Loss (26.54+32.62) > Gain (11.71+6.43) t-Stat 5.17 p-value <0.01† Long investors: Loss (20.28+19.03) < Gain (19.34+13.57) 1.13 0.27 Potential for loss: Long (20.28+19.03) < Prospective (26.54+32.62) 2.30 0.01† Potential for gain: Long (19.34+13.57) > Prospective (11.71+6.43) 2.49 <0.01† Between subjects: Investor type Fair value level Investor type × FV level Error Within subjects: Gain/loss Gain/loss × investor type Gain/loss × FV level Gain/loss × investor type × FV level Error Panel C: Planned contrasts Participants responded to the following questions (scale endpoints in parentheses): 36 Loss probability: What do you think is the probability of a further economic loss to the company from the land held for development? (0 = zero probability; 100 = absolute certainty) Loss amount: If there were a further economic loss to the company from the land held for development, how big a loss would you expect? (0 = zero loss; 100 = very large loss) Gain probability: What do you think is the probability of a future economic gain to the company from the land held for development? (0 = zero probability; 100 = absolute certainty) Gain amount: If there were a future economic gain to the company from the land held for development, how big a gain would you expect? (0 = zero gain; 100 = very large gain) The combined measure potential for loss (gain) is calculated as loss (gain) probability (as a percentage) multiplied by loss (gain) amount. This combined measure is the dependent variable in the analyses in Panels B and C. † one-tailed p-value 37 Table 2 Descriptive statistics and tests of H2 – Valuation judgments Panel A: Descriptive statistics – Means (std deviations) for effect of land held for development on firm value Valuation judgment Long Level 2 n = 12 Long Level 3 n = 16 Prospective Level 2 n = 16 Prospective Level 3 n = 17 1.08 (23.27) -13.50 (26.96) -14.44 (28.64) -31.59 (31.93) Panel B: Valuation judgments – ANOVA SS df MS F-Stat p-value Investor type 4228.11 1 4228.11 5.30 0.03 Fair value level 3769.51 1 3769.51 4.73 0.03 24.67 1 24.67 0.03 0.86 45468.97 57 797.70 Investor type × FV level Error Panel C: Regression model for incorporation of risk perceptions into valuation judgments Long Investors Risk Variable Prediction Intercept Coefficient -24.33 ** Prospective Investors t-stat Prediction -2.25 Coefficient -19.26 *** t-stat -2.20 Potential for loss – 0.43 1.19 – -0.57*** -2.55 Potential for gain + 0.54 1.18 + 1.43*** 3.66 Adjusted R2 0.04 0.37 Valuation judgments are responses to the following question (endpoints in parentheses): “Overall, how does the land held for development affect the value you place on the company?” (-100 = greatly decreases how much I value the company; 0 = neither increases nor decreases how much I value the company; 100 = greatly increases how much I value the company) *,**,*** indicate significance at p < 0.10, 0.05 and 0.01, respectively (one-tailed for directional predictions, two-tailed otherwise). 38 Table 3 Regression Analysis for Out-of-Sample Valuation Judgments Panel A: Regression model for incorporation of risk perceptions into valuation judgments Risk Variable Prediction Intercept Coefficient 4.35 * t-stat 1.70 Potential for loss – -4.78*** -14.14 Potential for gain + 1.79*** 4.20 Adjusted R2 0.14 Valuation judgments are responses to the following question (endpoints in parentheses): “Overall, how does the land held for development affect the value you place on the company?” (-100 = greatly decreases how much I value the company; 0 = neither increases nor decreases how much I value the company; 100 = greatly increases how much I value the company). Participants respond to either 11 (Level 2 condition) or 15 (Level 3 condition) scenarios with different combinations of potential for gain or loss. *,**,*** indicate significance at p < 0.10, 0.05 and 0.01, respectively (one-tailed for directional predictions, two-tailed otherwise). 39 Table 4 Robustness test – Effect of investor type on behavioral risk variables Panel A: Descriptive statistics – Means (std deviations) for behavioral risk variables Worry Catastrophic Voluntary Control Newness Known by investor Known by management Long Level 2 n = 12 47.50 (20.95) 32.92 (18.08) 52.75 (16.87) 33.75 (23.52) 25.75 (22.05) 36.75 (17.89) 66.42 (19.90) Long Level 3 n = 16 62.75 (16.26) 33.00 (19.55) 47.94 (20.89) 35.88 (17.27) 38.56 (28.29) 31.87 (20.61) 67.31 (21.51) Prospective Level 2 n = 16 52.63 (18.67) 41.63 (18.78) 41.00 (18.58) 44.13 (21.99) 29.50 (15.33) 31.50 (17.70) 68.19 (12.21) Prospective Level 3 n = 17 61.88 (26.12) 41.88 (24.52) 37.12 (27.08) 42.47 (20.97) 37.18 (27.85) 29.88 (18.53) 68.24 (23.37) Panel B: Contrasts p-value Worry: Long (47.50+62.75) < Prospective (52.63+61.88) t-stat 0.21 Catastrophic: Long (32.92+33.00) < Prospective (41.63+41.88) 1.69 0.05† Voluntary: Long (52.75+47.94) > Prospective (41.00+37.12) 2.01 0.02† Control: Long (33.75+35.88) > Prospective (44.13+42.47) 1.57 0.12 Newness: Long (25.75+38.56) ≟ Prospective (29.50+37.18) 0.06 0.95 Known by investor: Long (36.75+31.87) ≟ Prospective (31.50+29.88) 0.70 0.49 Known by management: Long (66.42+67.31) ≟ Prospective (68.19+68.24) 0.26 0.80 0.42† Participants responded to the following questions (scale endpoints in parentheses): Worry: Are the risks to the company from the land held for development ones that cause you to worry or do they cause you no worry? (0 = no worry; 100 = high worry) Catastrophic: To what extent are the risks to the company from the land held for development likely to be catastrophic? (0 = not likely to be catastrophic; 100 = very likely to be catastrophic) Voluntary: Would you voluntarily invest in a company that had this land held for development or would such an investment only occur if you were unaware of the land held for development (i.e., you would only invest involuntarily)? (0 = involuntarily, 100 = voluntarily) Control: How difficult is it for the company’s management to use their skill and diligence to control (limit) the risks of the land held for development? (0 = very difficult to control; 100 = very easy to control) Newness: Are the risks to the company from the land held for development new, novel ones or old, familiar ones? (0 = old; 100 = new) Known by investor: To what extent are the risks to the company from the land held for development known precisely by you, as an investor? (0 = not known; 100 = known precisely) Known by management: To what extent are the risks to the company from the land held for development known precisely by management? (0 = not known; 100 = known precisely) †one-tailed 40 Table 5 Robustness test – Effect of all risk variables (potential for loss and gain plus behavioral variables) on valuation judgments Panel A: Factor analysis Factor 1 (Dread) 0.117 Factor 2 (Gain) -0.142 Factor 3 (Loss) 0.872 Factor 4 (Unknown 1) -0.065 Factor 5 (Unknown 2) 0.001 Loss amount 0.349 0.176 0.766 0.034 0.142 Gain probability -0.287 0.810 -0.164 0.082 0.048 Gain amount -0.041 0.851 0.123 0.002 -0.183 Status quo probability -0.271 -0.213 -0.189 0.451 0.452 Worry 0.787 -0.080 0.178 -0.006 0.088 Catastrophic 0.745 -0.096 0.203 -0.029 0.049 Voluntary -0.662 0.344 -0.151 -0.042 0.153 Control -0.542 -0.097 0.311 0.089 -0.495 Newness 0.086 -0.088 0.211 -0.032 0.775 Known by investor -0.085 0.298 0.043 0.715 0.202 Known by mgmt 0.121 -0.101 -0.027 0.781 -0.241 Loss probability Panel B: Regression model for incorporation of risk perceptions into valuation judgments Prospective Investors Long Investors Risk Variable Prediction Intercept Coefficient -12.60 * t-stat Prediction -1.73 Coefficient -14.02 *** t-stat -3.11 Loss – 2.57 0.41 – -8.12** -1.85 Gain + 12.42* 1.65 + 16.54*** 4.01 Dread – -5.23 -0.91 – -12.22*** 3.84 Unknown 1 ? 5.25 1.06 ? 3.31 0.75 Unknown 2 ? 2.79 0.52 ? -0.10 -0.02 Adjusted R2 0.04 0.46 Valuation judgments are responses to the following question (endpoints in parentheses): “Overall, how does the land held for development affect the value you place on the company?” (-100 = greatly decreases how much I value the company; 0 = neither increases nor decreases how much I value the company; 100 = greatly increases how much I value the company) *,**,*** indicate significance at p < 0.10, 0.05 and 0.01, respectively (one-tailed for directional predictions, two-tailed otherwise). 41