* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Benchmarking and Comparing Entrepreneurs with Incomplete
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Finnish Economic Papers – Volume 20 – Number 2 – Autumn 2007 Benchmarking and Comparing Entrepreneurs with Incomplete Information* Juha-Pekka Niinimäki Department of Economics, Helsinki School of Economics, PB 1210, FIN-00101 Helsinki, Finland; e-mail: [email protected] and Tuomas Takalo Monetary Policy and Research Department, Bank of Finland, PO Box 160, FI-00101 Helsinki, Finland; e-mail: [email protected] This paper studies how the creation of (ex ante) benchmarks and rankings can be used to provide information in financial markets. Although an investor cannot precisely estimate the future returns of an entrepreneur’s projects, the investor can mitigate the incomplete information problem by comparing different entrepreneurs and financing only the very best ones. Incomplete information can be eliminated with certainty if the number of compared projects is sufficiently large. Because the possibility to make benchmarks and comparisons favours centralised information gathering, it creates a novel rationale for the establishment of a financial intermediary. (JEL: G21, G24) 1. Introduction It is widely felt that incomplete information can explain the existence of financial intermediaries (Diamond, 1984 and Boyd and Prescott, 1986). There are several means by which specialised * We thank Andreas Wagener (the co-editor) and the two referees for extensive comments. A previous version had a third coauthor, Klaus Kultti, who dropped out due to time constraints. We thank him for useful discussions. We also thank Bengt Holmström, Ari Hyytinen, Marco Pagano and audience in numerous seminars for helpful comments. The paper was partly written while Takalo was visiting IDEI, Toulouse. Financial support from Jenny and Antti Wihuri Foundation, Säästöpankkien tutkimussäätiö and Yrjö Jahnsson Foundation is gratefully acknowledged. outside investors can ease information frictions: ex ante monitoring (Broecker, 1990), interim and ex post monitoring (Holmström & Tirole, 1997; Diamond, 1984), collateral requirements (Bester, 1985) and long-term lending relationships (von Thadden, 1995).1 The analysis is extended in this paper, which explores how making benchmarks and comparisons of potential investment projects can help to mitigate – even eliminate – the incomplete information problem 1 Freixas & Rochet (1997) and Gorton & Winton (2003) provide thorough surveys of this literature. 91 Finnish Economic Papers 2/2007 – Juha-Pekka Niinimäki and Tuomas Takalo in financial markets, and how this benefit of benchmarking is conducive to centralised financial intermediation. To conduct ex ante monitoring properly, outside investors ought to gather comprehensive information on each entrepreneur or firm applying for funding and on their projects. For example, the skills and experience of the entrepreneur or firm’s management, the quality of the business plan, the tangible and intangible assets, the market potential of the products, and the cost efficiency should all be examined in detail. Based on this information, investors can evaluate the expected returns of the proposed project and provide finance at appropriate (risk-based) pricing. It is, however, not easy to assess expected returns precisely or to price risks correctly. In particular, in new markets where investors have little, or no, prior experience and entrepreneurs’ assets are intangible, it is virtually impossible to make precise evaluations. In more familiar sectors, finance for new entrepreneurs with no track record is difficult to price. Even if entrepreneurs or firms seeking outside finance are well known to the investors, changes in the economic environment may hamper the rating of applicants and hence their funding. In this paper we argue that investors can overcome the difficulties in ex ante monitoring by making benchmarks and comparisons. Although incomplete information problems in funding entrepreneurs and their projects relate to individual characteristics, learning from other entrepreneurs’ projects can help to uncover the true distribution of project characteristics in the economy. As a result, investors can compare and rank the projects and choose the very best. These projects will succeed with above-average probability. Hence by making benchmarks and comparisons, investors gather valuable information and thereby boost their investment yields. Moreover, if an investor compares sufficiently many entrepreneurs, the incomplete information problem will be eliminated with certainty. As an example, consider 10 de novo entrepreneurs from the same narrow high-tech sector. Such entrepreneurs typically have fresh prototype products, their primary assets consist of human capital and intellectual property rights, 92 and they lack funds for the investments required to commercialise the prototypes. Any outside investor will certainly find it a demanding task to assess the value of a prototype, its expected sales revenues, marketing strategy and ability of entrepreneur, and so on. However, if the investor would contact each of the 10 firms and investigate their prototypes, intellectual property portfolios, and entrepreneurial talent and then compare these, she may discover crucial differences between entrepreneurs’ business plans. The investor can rank the entrepreneurs and finance only the best ones. As a result, the investor can be quite confident that the best entrepreneurs’ products and plans are of sufficiently high quality that the entrepreneurs will be able to repay the funding. To benefit from the creation of benchmarks and rankings, however, an outside investor needs to evaluate numerous entrepreneurs, even if she can finance only one. With multiple investors operating in isolation, each entrepreneur is evaluated and compared several times. This duplicates the costs of information gathering. Wasteful duplication could be avoided if the investors joined together to establish a financial intermediary, which would evaluate each loan applicant, compare and rank them, and finance only the best ones. Each applicant is evaluated only once, and inefficient duplication is eliminated. Consequently, the possibility to make benchmarks and comparisons creates a novel rationale for centralised financial intermediation and delegated information gathering. In this respect our paper is related to the literature on the role of information provision in explaining financial intermediaries. Beyond the seminal contribution by Leland and Pyle (1977), our argument is closely related those of Diamond (1984), Ramakrishnan & Thakor (1984), and Boyd & Prescott (1986). As in these papers, a major advantage of forming a financial intermediary in our model is to reduce monitoring costs. Finally, our intermediary engages in asset transformation as in Diamond (1984) and Boyd & Prescott (1986). Our work thus adds to the long string of literature that extends the basic insights on financial intermediaries as delegated monitors and information gatherers into various dimensions (see e.g. Krasa & Villamil, 1992, Finnish Economic Papers 2/2007 – Juha-Pekka Niinimäki and Tuomas Takalo Winton, 1995, Cerasi & Daltung, 2000, Hellwig, 2000, and Niinimäki, 2001). Although the intermediary emerging from our analysis is bank-like and we treat entrepreneurs seeking outside finance as loan applicants, most of the analysis deals with a single investor and needs not specify the form of the financial contract. Moreover, the benefits of benchmarking are most evident in the finance of new ideas in new markets, where debt contracts are less predominant. Our paper therefore touches the literature on entities that finance innovation such as private equity and venture capitalists (for an authoritative survey of venture capital finance, see Gompers & Lerner, 2004). In particular, our study sheds light on the question of why and how venture capitalists benchmark their projects as in Bergemann & Hege (2002). In contrast to Bergemann & Hege (2002), which emphasises the value of ex post benchmarking in alleviating moral hazard, project comparison in our model provides ex ante benchmarks that mitigate the incomplete information problem.2 Another connection with the works of Bergeman & Hege (1998, 2002) is that making benchmarks and comparisons can be seen as a special form of costly learning or experimentation in financial markets. Although benchmarks and comparisons provide information, they are costly to make, since an investor must monitor numerous entrepreneurs to gather information. Thus the investor has to weigh the opportunity cost of monitoring yet one entrepreneur against the future informational benefits, as in the theory of experimentation. The key difference versus the learning and experimentation literature is that information derived from making benchmarks and comparisons exploits the differences between entrepreneurs and does not require observations on the same entrepreneur over time. 2 Our model and some of the motivating examples have also many similarities with Tirole (2006, Section 3.2.6). Like Bergemann & Hege (2002) Tirole shows how ex post benchmarking can be used to reduce moral hazard in entrepreneurial finance. We thank a referee for pointing out this link to Tirole (2006). Our focus on ex ante benchmarking also marks a difference to the related literature on relative performance measurement stemming from Holmström (1979). On performance benchmarking in practice, see e.g. Siems & Barr (1998), Balk (2003) and Courty & Marschke (2004). Indeed, in our model no additional information is gained by observing the same entrepreneur more than once. In contrast, the experimentation and relationship lending literature (see e.g. Sharpe, 1990, Boot, 2000, and von Thadden, 2004) emphasises that a bank can gather information trough multiple contacts with the same borrower over time. As a result, the bank achieves comparative information advantage in lending against competitive investors. It has also been shown in the literature (e.g. Pagano & Jappelli, 1993) that banks can sometimes optimally share borrower specific information among themselves.3 Since the problem of asymmetric information and alternative suggestions to eliminate it play important roles in the theory of finance, we have mostly considered our analysis from this point of view: a loan applicant knows the type of his project, but the type is unobservable to investors. Alternatively, since there is no adverse selection in our model, it is possible to assume that neither the loan applicant nor the investors know the quality of the project. Each entrepreneur will always search finance for his project since the project incurs no costs to him. Whether or not a loan applicant knows the quality of his project, he will always search for finance and investors aim to evaluate the project quality.4 3 In practice, learning by lending is combined with benchmarking in credit scoring programs (see Thomas, 2000; Berger & Frame & Miller, 2005, and Blochlinger & Leippold, 2006). Using a statistical program, a bank compares the information of a loan applicant to the credit performance of former borrowers with similar profiles. A credit scoring program awards points for each factor that helps predict who is likely to pay back a loan. A total number of points – a credit score – helps evaluate how creditworthy a loan applicant is. Hence, credit scoring programs offer an important instrument to handle information within banks. Since the quality of the credit scoring system is increasing in the number of former borrowers, the programs may generate information-releted economics of scale in banking. Additionally, established banks with credit scoring programs may have an information advantage against de novo banks. Benchmarks and comparisons complete information that can be achieved using credit scoring and longterm lending relationships. 4 We thank an anonymous referee for pointing out the possibility of recasting the model in terms of incomplete but symmetric information. 93 Finnish Economic Papers 2/2007 – Juha-Pekka Niinimäki and Tuomas Takalo The paper is organised as follows. In sections 2–3 we develop the main ideas and present the costs and benefits of comparing using a simple model with one investor and at most two entrepreneurs. In section 4 we consider a more general environment where the number of potential entrepreneurs can increase without a bound. In section 5 we allow for multiple investors and show how comparing can explain the existence of financial intermediaries. Section 6 concludes. 2. The economy 2.1 Financial market participants In the basic model there are, N ∈Z +, risk-neutral entrepreneurs (= loan applicants) and one riskneutral investor. In section 5 we allow for multiple investors. The entrepreneurs lack funds, but each has a project that requires a fixed startup investment of unit size. The funding can be obtained from the investor (she), who has a unit of capital but no project of her own. The project of an entrepreneur (he) is good with probability g and bad with probability 1 – g. Project quality is unobservable to outsiders and, without risk of confusion, we refer to good and bad entrepreneurs. A good project yields a transferable income Y with certainty, and a bad project only generates a non-transferable private benefit B to the entrepreneur. We assume that contacting an entrepreneur is costly. This cost, denoted by c, includes, e.g., the costs of waiting or searching for an entrepreneur, evaluating and monitoring his project, making the funding decision, and writing the funding contract or informing of the rejection of funding application. The cost occurs when the investor contacts and monitors an entrepreneur, and it cannot be avoided. A contact provides an informative signal about the entrepreneur’s type, which will be specified in the next subsection.5 5 Although we believe that unavoidable contacting and monitoring costs are empirically relevant, the assumption is essentially a short-cut. We could have regarded c as a signal extraction expense and assumed that it can be avoided but only at the cost of not receiving the signal. This 94 Since there is only one investor we assume that the investor has full bargaining power. Besides simplifying the analysis, the assumption is convenient when we look more closely at the benefits of centralised financial intermediation with multiple investors in section 5, since the assumption implies that investors have no incentive to form a financial intermediary to gain market power. The assumption also means that the form of financial contract is indeterminate: the investor can seize the entire output of a good project, Y, by driving the entrepreneur to the zero profit level. It is assumed that Y – r – c > 0 where r ≥ 1 denotes the economy’s risk-free interest rate (investor’s opportunity cost). Hence a good project has a positive net present value. In contrast, a bad entrepreneur is assumed to have a project with negative net present value, i.e., B – r < 0.6 2.2 Signals Upon contacting an entrepreneur, the investor receives a signal on the entrepreneur’s type. Each signal is informative in itself but, more importantly, they can be used as a benchmark with which subsequent signals will be compared. The signal can originate from any information reflecting profitability of the entrepreneur’s project. For brevity, we assume the signal can take only three values: s1, s2, and s3 where s1 > s2 > s3. Besides entrepreneur’s type, the value of a signal depends on the state of the world: • With probability h, the state of the world is high, in which case a good entrepreneur’s signal is invariably s1 and a bad entrepreneur’s signal is invariably s2. • With probability 1– h, the state of the world is low, in which case a good entrepreneur’s signal is invariably s2 and a bad entrepreneur’s signal s3. Then, on average, the value of a signal is larger in a high state of the world than in a low state would have complicated the analysis by adding one layer to the decision problem of the investor. 6 Strictly speaking we do not need the assumption that B < r, but it is more appropriate to label entrepreneurs bad if their projects have negative net present value. Finnish Economic Papers 2/2007 – Juha-Pekka Niinimäki and Tuomas Takalo of the world. For simplicity, we do not allow the state of the world to affect the project return but only the value of the signal. Because the investor cannot receive the signal s3 from a good entrepreneur and the signal s1 from a bad entrepreneur, the signals s1 and s3 are perfectly informative in that they fully reveal both the state of the world and type of loan applicant. Signal s1 tells the investor that the state of the world is high and the entrepreneur is good. Similarly, signal s3 says that the state of the world is low and the entrepreneur is bad. After observing either s1 or s3, the investor operates under perfect information. Signal s2 is more interesting. It indicates a bad entrepreneur in a high state of the world or a good one in a low state. Although the investor can use the signal s2 to update her prior beliefs about the state of the world and entrepreneur’s type, incomplete information remains after observing such a signal. After observing s2 from the first loan applicant, the investor must accept or reject the application without knowing the entrepreneur’s type, or she can use the first signal as a benchmark and gather more information by contacting another entrepreneur and comparing him with the benchmark. If the second signal is s1, the comparison of s1 with the benchmark s2 reveals that the state of the world is necessarily high and that the first entrepreneur is bad and the second is good. If the second signal is s3, the investor learns that the state of the world is low, the first entrepreneur is good and the second is bad. If the investor receives s2 from the second applicant, we still have incomplete information. However, even in this case, seeking a second loan applicant and comparing with the benchmark yields useful information, since the investor can update her beliefs about the state of the world and entrepreneur’s type. Thus, although the investor still must make a lending decision under incomplete information, she is better informed. Note that it is optimal to contact the loan applicants sequentially since this ensures that each contact provides some useful information and no costs of contacting are wasted. Since contacting a new loan applicant is costly, the investor encounters an optimal stopping problem each time she receives the signal s2. We nonetheless assume for brevity that the contacts take place fast enough so that the state of the world remains unchanged and that previous contacts can be recalled. As a result, if the first signal is s2 but the second is s3, the investor optimally returns to the first entrepreneur and grants him a loan. In sum, the signalling technology is simple: there are only three signals and they are informative. Two of the signals are actually very informative: good and bad signals perfectly reveal the borrower type. Despite this simple signalling technology, it is more informative to compare several entrepreneurs than just to observe the same entrepreneur over time, since the signals can vary according to the state of the world. Subsection 3.4 cites examples where signals depend on the state of the world. 2.3 The timing of events The investor’s decision problem has two stages. In the first stage, the investor who may have contacted some entrepreneurs previously faces three options. First, she can exit the credit market without lending to anyone. Second, she can grant a loan to any of entrepreneurs she has contacted previously. Finally, she can pool the previous signals with her prior to form a benchmark and invest c to acquire more information by comparing a new loan applicant with the benchmark. In the second stage, the investor will collect her payoffs from exit or lending decisions. In case the investor decides to contact a new entrepreneur, she will receive a signal on the entrepreneur’s type and updates her belief about the entrepreneur’s type and the state of the world. In this case the investor again faces the aforementioned three options. 3. Benchmarking and comparing with two loan applicants In this section, we first consider a loan market with perfect information. We then further develop concepts in the context of a simple example where there is only one loan applicant in the economy. Finally, we introduce a second loan 95 In this section, we first consider a loan market with perfect information. We then further develop concepts in the context of a simple example where there is only one loan applicant in the economy. Finnish Economic Papers 2/2007 – Juha-Pekka Niinimäki and Tuomas Takalo Finally, we to introduce a secondthe loan applicant to demonstrate the value ofinformation benchmarking. applicant demonstrate value of bench3.2 Incomplete with one loan marking. applicant If the economy consists of just one entrepreneur, the investor has to decide first whether to incur andfirms contact and then Under perfect information the investor can sepUnder perfect information the investor can separate good fromc bad and the grantentrepreneur a loan to a good arate good from bad firms and grant a loan to a whether to grant a loan to the entrepreneur givher updated belief about goodWe one. We assume that under perfect infor one. assume that under perfect information, lendingen is profitable to the investor, i.e.,the entrepreneur’s mation, lending is profitable to the investor, type. With probability hg, the signal is s1. With this signal, the investor knows that the entreprei.e., 11 neur is good and she grants him a loan. With (1) g (Y − r ) − c > 0 . probability (1–h)(1–g) the signal is(1)s3 and the entrepreneur's type,that but the incomplete information remains. In suc investor knows entrepreneur is bad 11 As explained, g in (1) is the probability of con- and she does not grant a loan. With probability 11 grant a loan in the presence of uncertainty about h (1–g) + (1–h)g the signal is s2 and the investor the type o tacting a good entrepreneur. In such case the not As explained, g in the (1) is the probability of contacting goodupdate entrepreneur. In such case the information investor type, but11 incomplete remains. In suc 10 aentrepreneur's can hertype, belief about entrepreneur’s investor can reap entire output of the project, loan to the investor with one entrepreneur in the economy is entrepreneur's type, but incomplete information remains. Ingive suc Y ; r denotes the opportunity cost of invested but incomplete information remains. In such a can reap the entire output of the project, Y ; r denotes the opportunity cost of invested capital and c not grant a loan in the presence of uncertainty about the type o case, the mayremains. or may not grant a loan capital the cost of a contact. first entrepreneur's type, buthas incomplete information In such aby case, the investor the cost and of a ccontact. Suppose first thatSuppose the economy only oneainvestor entrepreneur, who is contacted not grant loan in the presence of uncertainty about the typema o that the economy has only one entrepreneur, in the presence of uncertainty about the type of loan to the investor with one entrepreneur in the economy is give entrepreneur. Thus the whoinvestor. is contacted the investor. probabilnot a loan inlearns the presence uncertainty entrepreneur. {hgwith (Yabout ) +the } v = max −one rvalue [ha(type 1of − gaof ) +loan (1in− the hto ) geconomy ]the v R ( s 2Thus ) − cis, 0the the With by probability g, grant theWith investor that the entrepreneur represents good type. loan toVof the entrepreneur give N =1 investor ity g, the investor learns that the entrepreneur investor with one entrepreneur in the economy loaninvestor to the investor with entrepreneur in the economy is given by is by a good represents good type. The finances The investorafinances the project and makes profit Y −one r −given c , since project always succeeds. the project and makes profit Y – r – c, since a V N =1 = max{hg (Y − r ) + [h(1 − g ) + (1 − h) g ]v R ( s 2 ) − c, 0} With 1-g, succeeds. the entrepreneur proves to be bad. investor does lend good probability project always With probability where N{=1 (ofY −Vnot Vsubscript hg ris) +the [h(number 1 −toghim. ) + of (1 In −entrepreneurs h) g ]v R ( s 2 ) −in c, the 0} e (2) The N =1 = max 1–g, the entrepreneur proves to be bad. The in(Yrisk-free } bears V N =1 = max − r ) + [hinterest (1 − g ) +rate (1 − of h) gthe ]v Reconomy ( s 2 ) − c, 0and contrast, the investor hisInendowment at{hg the vestor does not lendinvests to him. contrast, the investor invests his endowment at the risk-free where subscript N=1 of V is the number of entrepreneurs in the e the cost of contacting. Thus, theand investor’s returns − c . Inv subscript sum, with N = 1 probability g− the investor of en( gVof s 2is)Vthe Yis rthe , 0}number where interest rate of the economy bears the costare where subscript N=1{pof number of entrepreneurs in the e R (s 2 ) = max of contacting. Thus, the investor’s returns are trepreneurs in the economy and probability 1-g − cnumber . The expected returns ofinthe makes profits Y − r − c and with where N=1she of loses V is the of entrepreneurs theinvestor economy and – c. In sum, with probability gsubscript the investor makes profits with isprobability 1–g to (1). (3) v R (s 2 ) = max{p ( g s 2 ) Y − r , 0} r ) − c >and positive owing amount to g (Y −Y – r – c 0 , which {punder v R (s 2 )of= amax ( g s 2 )uncertainty, Y − r , 0} given the signal s 2 . In (3 loan she loses – c. The expected returns of the inves- is the value is the value of a loan under uncertainty, tor amount to g (Y – r) – c > 0, which is positive Suppose now that the entrepreneurs until a good given {p( gcontact v R (investor s 2 ) = maxcan s 2 ) Y −numerous r , 0} the signal s2. In (3) owing to (1). Suppose now thatThe the expected investor value can contact is the valueisof ga (loan entrepreneur appears. of the each contact ) − c >uncertainty, 0 to her. Ifgiven Y − runder the the signal s 2 . In (3 (1 − huncertainty, )g the value of a loan under given the signal s 2 . In (3 numerous entrepreneurs until a good entrepre- is ( ) = p g s (4) 2 h(1 − g )to+ (1[g−(Yh)−g r ) − c ] + neur appears. expected value the each expected profits given economy has nTheentrepreneurs, theofinvestor’s amount is the value of a loan under uncertainty, the signal s 2 . In (3) contact is g (Y – r) – c > 0 to her. If the economy (1 − h) g that signal s2 indihas the conditional probability (1 − ng )[entrepreneurs, g (Y − r ) − c ] + (the 1 − ginvestor’s ) 2 [g (Y − r ) expected − c ] + .... . , is which pis( gequal s2 ) =to (g1 )−+h()1g−As profits amount to [g (Y – r) – c] + (1–g)[g (Y – r) cates pa(good entrepreneur. h ( 1 − h) g(3) shows,vR(s2) g s2 ) = indicates a good ent conditional hprobability (1 − investor g ) + (1 −that hfinances ) gsignal sa2 project – c] + (1–g)2[g (Y – r) – c] +… . , which is equal to(1 −is ish)the positive since the g p ( g s2 ) = only if its NPV is positive. Note that the posih(1 − g ) positive + (1 − h) gsince the investor finances a project only if its NPV is p tive value of vR(s2) has nothing to do with lim( − ) − g Y r c [1 − (1 − g ) n ] . s 2 context indicates a good ent is theliability, conditional probability signal ited which plays nothat role in this g of v R (conditional sthe nothing to do withher limited s 2 liability, indicates a goodplay ent is the probability that signal 2 ) has since investor uses only own funds. which positive since thevalue investor finances a project only if its NPV is p Similarly, the of a loan given by (2) is This is always positive when (1) is satisfied. s 2 investor indicates afunds. good Similarly, shows, is the conditional probability that signal investor uses her ownfinances the As value of a is loan positive the aentrepreneur. project only if its(3)NPV p positivesince sinceonly the investor contacts the entrepre(s 2 ) has of v R only nothing to doreturns with limited liability, which play neur if the expected from the con- that This is always positive when positive (1) is satisfied. since the investorof finances project only if its NPV islimited positive. Note the play posif investor contacts the entrepreneur only the expected returns (s 2 positive. ) ahas nothing to doand with liability, tactv Rare From (1) (2) it isif clear that which investor usesinformation only her own funds. the Similarly, of the value of a loan of v (s ) has nothing toincomplete do with limited liability,reduces which playsvalue no role the in this context 3.1 Perfect Perfectinformation information 3.1 (1) and (2) it is clear incomplete information va investor uses only herthat own funds. Similarly, the reduces value ofthe a loan 3.2 with one loan applicant investor contacts the entrepreneur only if the expected returns f 96 Incomplete information investor uses only her own funds.information Similarly, value of never a only loanhas by (2) is returns positive perfect investor to risk of losing her fc investor contacts thethe entrepreneur ifgiven the expected (1) and has (2) ittoisdecide clear that reduces the va If the economy consists of just one entrepreneur, the investor first incomplete whether to information incur c investor contacts the entrepreneur only the expected from thesignal contact posit information takes suchincomplete riskreturns when information the first is sare and vR (1) and (2) itshe isifclear that reduces val 2 the perfect information the investor never has to risk of losing her c and contact the entrepreneur and then whether to grant a loan to the entrepreneur given her updated (1) and (2) it is clear that perfect incomplete information reduces the value opportu information the investor never hasoftothe risklending of losing her c R 2 v(s3 ) = g (Y − r ) − c > 0 . v(s3 ) = g (Y − r ) − c > 0 . Note that the value of a loan stems entirely from 13 the possibility of c Finnish Economic Papers 2/2007 – Juha-Pekka Niinimäki and Tuomas Takalo Note that the value of a loan stems entirely theispossibility of case comparing the entrepre The firstfrom signal s . In this the investor's prob 2 lending opportunity: with perfect information Note max{g(Y – r) – c, by (1), v(s3 ) that = g (the Y −value r ) − c0}. . g (Y – r) – c > 0 of> a0As loan stems entirely from the possibility of c 13 signal is s 2 . In this case the investor's problem is more complica the investor never has the risk of losingThe herfirstwe obtain second signal is also s 2 , the investor cannot be sure about the e capital (r ) whereas with incomplete information The first signal is s 2 . In this case the investor's prob v(sinvestor − r ) − cbe > 0sure . about the entrepreneurs' type and (5) she takes such a risk when thesecond first signal s 2 , the signal is is salso 2 3 ) = g (Y cannot updatethat herthe beliefs. The value of a loan underfrom uncertainty when both Note value of a loan stems entirely possibility of ce and vR(s2) is strictly positive. cannot bethesure about the second signal is also s 2 , the investor value ofuncertainty a loan stems entirely from are s 2 is given update her beliefs. TheNote valuethat of athe loan under when both signals Theoffirst signal is the In under this case the investor's prob the possibility comparing 2 . entrepreneurs. update her beliefs. The value of as loan uncertainty when both 3.3 Incomplete information with two loan Note that the value of a loan stems entirely from the possibilit The first signal is s . In this case the inves2 applicants (s 2 , s 2 )isis= also )Y − r ,If0cannot }the second v Rsignal max{p (,g the s 2 , sinvestor 2 be sure about the e second tor’s problem morescomplicated. 2 signal cannot is s 2 . Inbethis case the investor's the first investor sure With two entrepreneurs, the investorv R must (s 2 , s 2 first ) = maxsignal {p(g s 2 ,iss 2 )also Y − r ,s02}, The update her beliefs. The value of a loan under uncertainty when both decide whether to contact either of the entrepre- aboutvthe (s 2entrepreneurs’ , s 2 ) = max{p (g stype , s 2 )Yand − r can , 0} only upR 2 , the investor cannot second signalThe is also beliefs. values 2of a loan under un- be sure about neurs. If she contacts one of them, she has to date her where, analogously to (4), decide whether to grant a loan to him or use him certainty when both signals are s2 is given by as a benchmark. By creating the benchmark the to (4), update her beliefs. The value of a loan under uncertainty when where, analogously (s 2 , s 2 ) = max p (g s 2 , s 2 )Y − r , 0} (6) vanalogously investor can contact a second entrepreneur and where, R to {(4), compare him with the benchmark. Then the in(1 − h) g 2 g s2 , s2 ) = to (4),2 vestor must decide whether to grant a loan to where,p(analogously h(1 − g ) + (1 − h) g 2 (1 − h) g 2v R (s 2 , s 2 ) = max{p (g s 2 , s 2 )Y − r , 0} either or neither of the two entrepreneurs. Since p (g s , s ) = the investor has only one unit of capital, 2he 2can h(1where, − g ) 2 analogously + (1 − h) g 2 to (4),(1 − h) g 2 (7) p(g s2 , s2 ) = not finance both projects even when both of h(1 − g ) 2 + (1 − h) g 2 them are good.7 If the first signal is either s1 or is the conditional probability that signal s indicates a good entre analogously to (4), that signal2s2 indis3, the investor’s decision problem is straight- is thewhere, conditional probability ( 1 − h)after g a2 good s 2 indicates after two ob is the conditional probability forward so we first characterise them. cates a that goodsignal entrepreneur twoentrepreneur observaAgain,pv(gR (ss22,,ss22)) =is positive since the investor finances a project onl 2 (12−) gis) 2positive (1 − hsignal ) gsince +that The first signal is s1. If the signal from the is tions. Again, vR(sprobability in- a good entre the conditional s 2 the indicates 2h, s ) is positive Again, knows v R (s 2 , sthat the investor finances a project first entrepreneur is s1, the investor vestorsince finances a project only if 2its only NPVif its is NPV is positiv 2 If the signal received the second entrepreneur is (1 −the ) ginvestor hfrom he is good. Since the investor has only one unit Again, positive. v R (s 2p, (sg2 )s2is, spositive since finances a project onl ) = 2 2 (1 − entrepreneur 1 − h) gis2 entrehfrom g )the + (second of capital, there is no need to contact the second the signal received s1 , the investor know If the signalIfreceived from the second is dealing with a good entrepreneur and grants a loan. aIfgood the secon s 2 second indicates entre the conditional probability that signal entrepreneur, and the investor grants a loan to is preneur is sIf1, the the investor knows she is entrepreneur signal received fromthat the is the first entrepreneur, which isyields Y – r with dealing with a good entrepreneur and grants a dealing with a good entrepreneur and grants a loan. If the second contact yields s 3 , th knows is low, the entrepreneur isfinances bad andathe first onl en (sthe Again, vthe , s 2state is positive since thesand investor certainty. loan. Ifthat contact yields investor R with 2second 3, the is dealing a) good entrepreneur grants a loan. Ifproject the secon s indicates a good is the conditional probability that signal 2 is The first signal is s3. If theknows signal received knows that the state isis low, the the entrepreneur that the state isthus low,grants the entrepreneur bad and first entrepreneur is good. a If loan tosignal the first entrepreneur. When the first signalTh the received from the second entrepreneur isi upon contacting the first entrepreneur is s3, the knows bad and the first entrepreneur is good. The inthat the state is low, the entrepreneur is bad and the first en ( ) Again, v s , s is positive since the investor finances a proje entrepreneur is bad with certainty. the second vestor grants loan to entrepreR 2 2a When thus If grants a loan to the firstthus entrepreneur. thethe firstfirst signal is s 2 , the value of a lo written as is dealing with a good entrepreneur and value grants a loan. If thesignal seconi contact also yields s3, the investor does not lend. thus neur. When first signal is s2, the of athe first grants a the loan to the first entrepreneur. When If the If the second signal is s2, the investor as signal received from the second entrepren written ascan elim- loan can be written inate the incomplete information problem by written knows that and the first en as the state is low, the entrepreneur is bad 14 a loan. If the with a(sgood entrepreneur and grants comparing signals. Because the first signal, s3, (8) isv(sdealing ) { ) ( ) ( ) ( = max v , t Y − r + 1 − t v s , s 2 R 2 2 2 R 2 2 ) − c, 0} . reveals that the state of the world is low, the thus grants a loan to the first entrepreneur. When the first signal i )(h+ s(12the )v[1R−(sisp2 ,(low, }g .) is the probability v(sa2 )worthy = max{v Rwhere t 2 t(Y =− rpthat second entrepreneur with s2 must be is bad and that the fi )−gt +2state (c1, −0entrepreneur hs 2s)2−)]the (s 2 ), knows 2 s 2 ) = max{v R (s 2 ), t 2 (Y − r ) + (1 − t 2 )v R (s 2 , s 2 ) − c, 0} . borrower. Since the probability that the second writtenv(as grants loan to the signal. first entrepreneur. When the first si wherethus t2 = p(h | sa2)g + [1– p(h | s 2)](1– g) entrepreneur emits s2 is g, the value of a loan eliminated by using the second Here is the when s3 is the first signal is given by v(s3) = probability that incomplete information can be writtenby as using the second signal. Here eliminated v(s 2 ) = max{v R (s 2 ), t 2 (Y − r ) + (1 − t 2 )v R (s 2 , s 2 ) − c, 0} . 7 By assuming that an investor has only a unit of capital in this section, we will emphasise that the investor’s sole reason to contact numerous entrepreneurs is to gather more information. As a result, it is possible to explore optimal stopping in information gathering. The analysis is extended in section 5, where the economy has numerous investors and entrepreneurs. (9) h(1 − g ) = 1 − p (g s 2 ) h(1 − g ) + (1 − h) g v(s 2 ) = max{v R (s 2 ), t 2 (Y − r ) + (1 − t 2 )v R (s 2 , s 2 ) − c, 0} p(h s 2 ) = is the conditional probability that the state is high when the investor observes signal s2. As it stands, (8) showsprobability the three choices the when the inve is the conditional that thefaced state by is high stands, (8) shows the three choices faced by the 97 investor after obse First, if p (g s 2 )Y − r < 0 implying v R ( s 2 ) = 0, and if t 2 (Y − r investor does not lend at all and v(s )=0. That is, the investor can a is the conditional probability that the state is high when the investor observes signal s 2 . As it stands, (8) shows the three 2/2007 choices – faced by the investor after and observing s 2 Takalo from the first contact. Finnish Economic Papers Juha-Pekka Niinimäki Tuomas investor after observing s2 from the first contact. comparing entrepreneurs and updating her beFirst, if p (g s 2 )Y − r < 0 implying v R ( s 2 ) = 0, and if t 2 (Y − r ) + (1 − t 2 )v R (s 2 , s 2 ) − c < 0 , the First, if p(g | s2) Y – r < 0 implying vR(s2) = 0, and liefs. The cost of benchmarking is on the RHS if t2(Y – r) + (1– t2)vR(s2, s2) – c < 0, the investor of (10). Besides the cost of contacting, the opinvestor at allv(s and v(s2)=0. That is, the portunity investor can achieve zero returns by omitting cost of benchmarking stems from the does not does lendnot at lend all and 2) = 0. That is, the investor 8can achieve zero returns by omitting possibility to grant a loan under uncertainty lending. Otherwise, the maximisation problem on the right-hand side of (8) reflects the investor's lending.8 Otherwise, the maximisation problem about the type of the first entrepreneur. For the g > 1/2, it isdecides easy totosee why part under i) of Propon the right-hand of (8)the reflects inves- case choice of whether side to contact secondthe entrepreneur. If the investor grant a loan tor’s choice of whether to contact the second osition 1 must be true, since then Y – r > vR(s2, ) ≥ vR(s2),payoff i.e., the payoff entrepreneur. If the investor decides to grant a hers2expected (s2 ) .benchmarking From (8) uncertainty after contacting only one entrepreneur, is given by vfrom R loan under uncertainty after contacting only one clearly exceeds the value of the loan under uncertainty. entrepreneur, her payoff the is given we observe that theexpected investor contacts secondby entrepreneur if But it turns out that the same concluvR(s2). From (8) we observe that the investor sion holds even for g < 1/2, so the benefits exceed the cost of benchmarking when the cost of contacts the second entrepreneur if contacting is sufficiently low. As part ii) suggests, the investor may (10) prefer (10) t 2 (Y − r ) + (1 − t 2 )v R (s 2 , s 2 ) ≥ c + v R (s 2 ) . to grant a loan under uncertainty about the type In Appendix we prove that the investor’s opti- of the first entrepreneur over using him as a mal lending strategy after observing s2 satisfies benchmark if the cost of contacting is suffi9 In Appendix we prove that the investor's optimal lending afterstrategy observingmay s 2 satisfies the followingAconditions: cientlystrategy high. The also be the optimal with moderate or even with low contacting cost 9 following conditions: Proposition 1 Suppose that the first loan ap- if the first entrepreneur, given signal s2, is good plicant’s type is unknown (signal s2). Then, with sufficiently high probability, that is, when g is close to one or h is close to zero. In such i) if the contacting cost (c) is sufficiently low, circumstances, incomplete information causes a the investor contactsthat a second appliProposition 1. Suppose the firstloan loan applicant's type isnuisance unknown (signal ). Then, benefits of minor and thes2 expected cant and compares him with the first one, 16 benchmarking do not cover the cost of contactii) if c is sufficiently high and if either the ing. 16 prior probability that a loan applicant has a 8 Partcontact iii) are ofPart Proposition iii) of Proposition 1sunk canbe alsoseen be seen from (10 Thegood investor can achieve zero returns, since the sunk costs of the first not included in v (1s 2 )can . Thealso project (g) is sufficiently high or if from (10). The investor prefers not to lend at all prior probability of a Part highiii) state (h) is coststhe appear in (11). of Proposition 1 can also be (10). The investor to lend after signal s2 seen ifs2 the expected return on aa loan iffrom the expected return onprefers loan not under uncera all after signal 9 sufficiently low to renderand theTakalo, net present A working paper version (Niinimäki 2007) includes extensive numerical examples showing that all result under uncertainty is not positive and the cost of value of a loan under uncertainty thepositive expected satisfying return onequation a loan under uncertainty is not positive and the cost o after signal 2 if simultaneously exist for some plausibleall parameter values swhile (1). contacting is hightotorender render a search contacting is sufficiently sufficiently high a search for a second en (vR(s2) > 0), the investor grants a loan to the for a second entrepreneur unprofitable. first applicant.contacting is sufficiently high to render a search for a second entrepreneur unprofitable. a loan. Weabove have above The value The of avalue loan.ofWe have deter-determined t iii) if c is sufficiently high and if either g is mined the conditional value of a loan for the sufficiently low or h sufficiently to We The value high of a loan. have above determined thefirst conditional value of a loan for th three possible values the signal. The initial three possible valuesof of the first signal. The value of a render vR(s2) ≤ 0, the investor does not lend initialThe value of avalue loanof– athe investor’s expected three possible values of the first signal. loan – theapplicant investor's return at all. beforebefore sheinitial hasshe contacted either loan isexpected then given by return has contacted either loan–apThe LHS of (10) shows the has benefits of bench– is– then given before she contacted either loanplicant applicant is then givenby by marking: with positive probability (t2) the second contact will probably eliminate the incom- (11) V = hg (Y − r ) + [h(1 − g ) + (1 − h )g ]v( s ) + (1 − h )(1 − g ) 2 N =2 plete information problem and, even if it does ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )( ) V = hg Y − r + [ h 1 − g + 1 − h g ] v ( s ) + 1 − h 1 − g v ( s ) − c . (11) not, the investor can gatherN =more information by 2 2 3 (5),and they giv The investor can achieve zero returns, since the sunk InIn(11) (11) v(s v( s22) )and andv(s v(3s)3 )are aregiven givenby by (8) (8) and and (5), and they give the values of a loan to the investor costs of the first contact are not included in v (s2). The sunk costs appear in (11). In (11) v ( s 2 ) and v( s 3 ) are given when by (8)the andfirst (5), signals and theyare give a loanofto the investo s the andvalues s . Theofvalue 9 the first signals are s22 and s33 . The value of a loan after A working paper version (Niinimäki and Takalo, 2007) awhen loan after the investor receives signal s1 from includes extensive numerical examples showing that all re first entrepreneur is simply Y–r. These s 2 and sthe whenparameter the first values signalswhile are simul3 . The value of a loan after the investor receives signal s1 from sult exist for some plausible the first entrepreneur is simply Y-r. These values of loan values of loans are weighted by the appropriate taneously satisfying equation (1). 8 98 the first entrepreneur is simply Y-r. These values loans are weighted the appropriat probabilities: withof probability hg the bysignal of the probabilities: with probability hg the signal of the first entrepreneur is s1 , with probability [h(1 − g ) + (1 − h )g ] the signal is s2, and with probabi probability [h(1 − g ) + (1 − h )g ] the signal is s2, and with probability (1-h)(1-g) it is s3. That the investor's optimal strategy under in Finnish Economic Papers 2/2007 – Juha-Pekka Niinimäki and Tuomas Takalo probabilities: with probability hg the signal of the first entrepreneur is s1, with probability [h(1– g) + (1– h)g] the signal is s2, and with probability (1–h)(1–g) it is s3. That the investor’s optimal strategy under incomplete information can involve benchmarking can be seen from (11). After contacting the first entrepreneur, the investor can gather more information by using the first signal as a benchmark, seeking a second entrepreneur and comparing him with the benchmark. If the signal from the first entrepreneur is ’better’ than the signal of the second, the first proves to be worthy of finance and vice versa. If the received signals are identical, the investor can update her prior beliefs on the state of the world and types of entrepreneurs, but the incomplete information problem remains. The investor will create a benchmark and search for a second entrepreneur if the benefits outweigh the opportunity costs of doing so. If the cost of contacting is sufficiently large, the investor may want to grant a loan to the first entrepreneur without benchmarking and comparing, although there is higher risk of credit loss than for a loan under uncertainty after contacting the second entrepreneur. Alternatively, the investor will not grant a loan at all. If VN = 2 ≥ 0 the loan market opens up. This occurs if c is not too high. If VN = 2 ≥ 0, (1) also holds, but not necessarily vice versa. We summarise the benefits of benchmarking based on the above analysis as follows: Proposition 2 By using the first entrepreneur as a benchmark and comparing the second entrepreneur with him, the investor can gather more information and raise the expected return on her loan. If the signals received from the entrepreneurs differ, incomplete information is eliminated, and the investor can grant the loan to the good entrepreneur. Even if both signals are the same (s2) and incomplete information obtains, the investor can update prior beliefs on types of entrepreneurs. In spite of all the benefits of using the first entrepreneur as a benchmark, the investor’s lending decision is still less efficient than under perfect information. From (1) and (11), we see that four inefficiencies remain: i) The first en- trepreneur is good, but his type is unobservable to the investor because of signal s2. The investor may waste resources by searching for a second entrepreneur or she may inefficiently exit the credit markets; ii) The investor encounters two good entrepreneurs, but the entrepreneurs’ types remain unobservable. If p(g | s2, s2)Y < r, the investor makes a mistake and denies a loan; iii) The investor contacts a bad entrepreneur who signals s2 and who inefficiently receives a loan, if c is sufficiently high and p2(g | s2)Y > r (part ii) of Proposition 1); iv) The investor contacts two bad entrepreneurs with s2, and she grants a loan if p2(g | s2, s2)Y > r. 3.4 Discussion The model with one investor, two entrepreneurs, and three signals is admittedly limited. In the subsequent sections we will allow for multiple entrepreneurs and financiers. While the extension of the model to arbitrary number of signals is beyond the scope of this paper, it is clear that the basic insight about the value of making benchmarks and comparisons would not change in so far the signal space is finite.10 To gain intuition for the upcoming results and illustrate the value of benchmarking, we illustrate few examples. • Variation of signals across sectors: Financial ratios reveal valuable information to investors, but a part of this information is sectorspecific. What is regarded as a good ratio of asset turnover, administration costs, gross profit or solvency will vary across industries. Thus, even when the financial ratios of a sector are fixed in time, the critical values of financial ratios differ across sectors. Hence, if an investor who has no previous experience in the sector evaluates a firm, the firm’s financial ratios do not reveal its true financial condition to the investor. To evaluate the firm 10 Increasing the number of intermediate signals that do not perfectly reveal the borrower type would make the information asymmetry friction costlier to resolve but would not otherwise affect the results. If there were uncountable measure of signals, having access to many borrowers would not eliminate the information asymmetry. However, even in that case benchmarking and comparing would be valuable. 99 Finnish Economic Papers 2/2007 – Juha-Pekka Niinimäki and Tuomas Takalo properly, the investor must compare the financial ratios of the firm with the financial ratios of the other firms in the very same sector. Only after studying sufficiently many firms, will the investor understand the correct meaning of financial ratios in the sector. • Variation of signals over time: The investor may have previous experience in the sector, but the signal value fluctuates over time, making the information value of a single signal modest. For instance, a good firm might earn handsome profits if the industry is booming or moderate profits if the industry is in recession, whereas a bad firm might earn moderate profits during a boom or fail in a recession. Hence, whether moderate profit indicates a good or a bad firm would depend on the stage of the industry cycle. Without comparing, the investor might make a wrong decision by granting a loan to a bad firm with moderate profits. • Variation of signals across regions: Production costs and market potential differ from one region to another. The same wage cost per employee, for example, may indicate a good, efficient firm in Area A, or a bad, inefficient firm in Area B. To be able to evaluate the competitiveness of a firm in its local region, the investor needs to compare the firm’s characteristics with its local competitors. • Variation of signals in research and development: The progress of research and development is stochastic almost by definition. At first glance, the prototype of an entrepreneur may seem to be promising. However, careful comparison with the other entrepreneurs’ prototypes or products in the sector may reveal that the prototype is lagging. Financing the first entrepreneur is likely to be a mistake since its product will hardly be commercially viable. • Variation of signals according to the industry dynamics. Multiple equilibria are pervasive in network industries. A network firm’s profit may be negative, but contrasting the firm with other firms in the industry may reveal that the firms are engaged in fierce competition for dominance where all firms are making losses, and that the firm is leading the competition for a dominant position in the market. Once 100 in the dominant position, the firm will be able to raise its price and make substantial profits. Denying the firm finance would probably be a mistake. • The profitability of a firm varies with the industry equilibria. Efficient firms may, for example, earn supernormal profits if the firms in an industry collude and moderate profits if they compete. Less efficient firms may earn moderate profits if the industry is in collusion or zero profits if there is competition. Moderate profits may signal an efficient firm if the firms compete or an inefficient firm in case of collusion. • Technological cycles change the meanings of signals. The propensity to patent changes over time depending on the legal and technological environment. For example, it is known that innovations can come in waves: after a breakthrough invention it is easier to make follow up innovations. A successful innovative firm may possess dozens of patents after a breakthrough, having had only a handful before. A less innovative firm, having struggled to obtain one patent before the breakthrough, may easily obtain a handful of patents after the breakthrough. For an outsider, it is hard to know whether a handful of patents indicates an innovative or an unsuccessful firm. 4. Benchmarking and comparing with N loan applicants So far we have assumed that the investor can contact at most two firms. Although a complete characterization of a more general case with an arbitrary number of entrepreneurs is beyond the scope of this study, in this section we briefly confirm that the insights gained from the two entrepreneur case apply for a larger pool of loan applicants. We first note that incomplete information can be eliminated with certainty when the number of contacted entrepreneurs approaches infinity. Recall that incomplete information obtains only if the investor receives signal s2. Consequently, when the number of compared entrepreneurs grows, incomplete information still obtains after n contacts only with probability (1– h)gn + N N 2 N invest in information gathering, taking into21 account the costs, we write then initial value of a loan toand (1 − h) g + h(1 − g ) n . With probability 1-h theanalogously stateVisN low with has ((11) )g ]vinvestor = hg Y− ras) +probability [h(1 − g ) + (1g− hthe N ( s 2 ) + (1 − h )(1 − g ) v N 21 analogously to (11) as (1 − h )(n1 −Takalo V N = 2/2007 hg (Y − – r ) + [h(1 − g ) + (1Niinimäki − h )g ]v Nn ( sand g ) v N ( s3 ) − c , n Finnish Economic n 2 ) + Tuomas Papers (1 − h) gonly + h(good 1 − g )entrepreneurs. . With probability the Juha-Pekka state is low g high the 21 contacted where subscript Nand denotes the number of investor entrepreneurs. With1-h probabilities h and (1with − g)probability thetotal state is and thehas The f n n n n + h(1 − g ) . With probability 1-h the state is low and with probability g the investor has ( 1 − h ) g h(1– g) . With probability 1-h the state is low21 (13) V N = hg (Y − r ) + [h(1 − g ) + (1 − h )g ]v N ( s 2 ) + (1 − h )(1 − g ) v N captures (13) possibility that the first is s1 , prom where subscriptthe denotes number of signal entrepreneurs. The f contacted only goodinvestor entrepreneurs. probabilities hNprobabilities and (1 −the g) ntotal the andstate with probability gn the has con-With investor compared only bad entrepreneurs. Because g n state and is(1high − g) n and arethe bability 1-h the is low andhas with grn) the investor has ( ( ) ( ) ( )( ) Vprobability = hg Y − + [ h 1 − g + 1 − h g ] v ( s ) + 1 − h 1 − g v (13) n N N 2 N ( s3 ) − c , 21 contacted entrepreneurs. With probabilities h and the (1 −total g) the stateofisentrepreneurs. high and theThe first term in the ri tacted onlyonly goodgood entrepreneurs. With probabiliwhere subscript N denotes number n nthird (13) captures the possibility that the arise firsthas signal s , where prom immediately. The second and term from the n iscases (1 − hh)and gdecreasing +investor h(1 −ngthe ) nhas .n, With probability 1-hbad the state is low and with probability g the the investor nis ties (1– g) state high and the inveswhere subscript N denotes total compared only entrepreneurs. Because probabilities g n number and (1n−of in the probability that incomplete information obtains approaches zero, when →g)∞ . are1 neurs. With probabilities h and (1 − g) the state is high and the n (13) possibility that the signal is s1 are , prompting the investo compared only1-hbad entrepreneurs. The first term in where subscript Ninvestor denotes the total number of entrepreneurs. The investor has compared only bad is entrepreneurs. Because probabilities gfirst and (1 −the g) nright-hand h) g n + h(1 −tor g ) nhas . With probability theentrepreneurs. state low captures andBewith the probability g n The the has immediately. second and third term arise from the cases where n n n . As discussed in the previous se The first signal is s cause probabilities g and (1– g) are decreasing side of (13) captures the possibility that the first 3 contacted only good entrepreneurs. With probabilities h and ( 1 − g) the state is high and the ninvestor n Even if the has not received two different signals over the first n contacts, decreasing in n, the probability that incomplete information obtains approaches zero, when n → ∞ . subscriptgN denotes number of entrepreneurs. The first term in the right-hand side of bad entrepreneurs. Because where probabilities and (1the − g)totalare (13) captures the possibility that the first signal is s , prom in n, the probability that incomplete information is s , prompting the investor grant a loan immediately. Thesignal second and third term arise from the cases where the first signal is decreasing in n, the probability that incomplete information obtains approaches zero, when n → ∞ . 1 n 1 acted only good entrepreneurs. With probabilities h and (1 − g) the state is that high theis s . Asis discussed in the previous se first signal investor knows theand entrepreneur bad with certainty. This ca n and nthis, 3To see obtains comparing approaches zero, when n → ∞. immediately. The third term arise can inEven practice render the deficiency of information insignificant. consider if the the investor received twoThe different signals over the first n contacts, investor has compared only bad entrepreneurs. Because probabilities g and ( 1 − g) are (13) captures possibility thatnot first signal is ssecond , prompting the investor grant a loan that incomplete information obtains approaches zero, when nhas → ∞ .the 1 if thehas investor has nottwo received two different signals overthe the first nthe contacts, Even if theEven investor not received dif- The from the cases where first signal isarise s2 orfrom s3. the cases immediately. The second and third term in previous section, if thewhere first first signal n is s 3 . As discussed n stor has compared only badthe entrepreneurs. Because probabilities g knows andn-1 (1is −the g) are if theprevious second entrepreneur releasessTo , the the investor canThis elimi investor that entrepreneur is.sin bad with certainty. ca ferent signals over the first n contacts, comparThe first signal s . As discussed pre2 see contacting nth entrepreneur that yields, like all contacts, signal The probability comparing can in practice render the deficiency of information insignificant. this, consider 3 or has not received twoindifferent signals over firstand n contacts, decreasing n, the probability thatthe incomplete information approaches zero, n→∞ immediately. The second third term ariseobtains from the cases where the when first 2signal is . s 2 or s 3 . comparing can in practice render the deficiency of information insignificant. To see this, consider ing can in practice render the deficiency in- that vious if the signal investor 3, the discussed theused previous The first signal is certainty. sis3 .sAs investorofknows thesection, entrepreneur isfirst bad with This caninbe as a bes iflike theallsecond entrepreneur ss2with the cerinvestor can elimi easing in n, the probability that incomplete information obtains approaches zero, →second ∞ .releases s 3 , the investor do comparing signals. If ncontacts, the is, also n when formation insignificant. Toentrepreneur see this, consider knows that the entrepreneur issignal bad contacting the nth that yields, previous n-1 signal er the deficiency of information insignificant. To see this, consider 2 . The probability ( 1 ) − h g Even if the investor has not received two different signals over the first n contacts, . As discussed in the previous section, if the first signal is s 3 , the first signal isall s3=previous contacting entrepreneur that yields, like n-1 contacts, signal s . The probability ( ) p g S or thatthe thenth entrepreneur isThe good is 2 contacting the nth entrepreneur that yields, like tainty. This can be used as a benchmark so that 2 , n if the second entrepreneur releases s 2 ,entrepreneur the investoriscan incomplete investor bad eliminate with certainty. This ca (1comparing (1 first − h)over g n +knows hsignals. − nthat g ) nnIfthe Even investor has not received different signals the contacts, s 3 , there the investor do the second signal is also contacting. Thus the value ofs2a,consider loan when are N pot all ifprevious n–1 contacts, signal ss2two . The probaifcontinue the second entrepreneur releases the investhat yields, like allthe previous n-1 contacts, signal the The probability comparing can ininvestor practice render of information insignificant. To see this, ( 1 ) − h g 2 . deficiency n with certainty. This can be used as a benchmark so that knows thep(g entrepreneur is) gbad ( ) p g S = or thatentrepreneur the entrepreneur isthat good is ( 1 − h bility that the is good is | S ) = tor can eliminate incomplete information by 2 , n n n is alsoreleases 2, n signals. if(1Ifthe s 2 , the does investor can elimi s 3 , the investor not lend and comparing the signal g Sinformation or the entrepreneur good is p(of −signal h)second gsecond +see hs (1entrepreneur − g )Thus 2, n ) = n first ncontacting. paring can inthat practice render the isdeficiency insignificant. this, is written as the value of a loan comparing signals. Ifconsider the second signal iswhen also there are N pot (1 − hall ) g previous +continue h(1 − gn-1 )To 3 can be contacting that yields, like contacts, signal s . The probability (1 − hthe ) g n nthifentrepreneur 2 the s 2 , the investor can eliminate incomplete information by p (g S 2 , n ) = or second entrepreneur releasess3comparing , the investor does lend may may s , theentrepreneu investor d the signal is or also contacting. Thus thesignals. value ofIfanot loansecond whenand there are N potential − h) g n + h(1 −that g ) nyields, like all previous 1 continue acting the nth(1entrepreneur n-1 contacts, The probability first signal sis2 . scontacting. as the value of a3(12) not signal continue Thus 3 can be written . p (g S 2, n ) = n (1 − h)is g also s3 , the investor does not lend and may or may not comparing signals. second signal h If1the or that the entrepreneur is good there N potential 1 +is p(g S(first 1n ) n is s3 nloan signal can bewhen written as areThus 2 , n )−= continue contacting. the value entrepreneurs of a loan when there are N pot n 1 + hwhen (1 − )v(s3 , s3 ),as0}, (12) v Ng()sthe max{signal g (Y − is r) − ccan + (1 −beg written 1 1 − (h1 − gh) g (1 − h. ) g and s 3 ) =first ( ) = p g S 3 2 , n (12) is good . 1 the value (12) p (g Sis (continue g S 2, n ) =contacting. orof a loan when there are N potential entrepreneurs the entrepreneur 2 , n )p= and when the nn h (111−+h) ghnn Thus + (h(1 − 1g)) first signal is s 3 can be written as + − 1 ( 1 ) . (12) (14) v N (s3 ) = max{g (Y − r ) − c + (1 − g )v(s3 , s3 ), 0}, 1− h g 1− h g first signal is s 3 can be written as − 1) n {g (Y − r ) − c + (1 − g )v(s3 , s3 ), 0}, v N (s3 ) = max S 2,n, s=2, 2s ,…, s ,..., sis2,n the is the vector of signals from n entrepreneurs. (12) it where vs(2s 3received , s 3 ) is the value of a loan afterFrom two observations of s 2 ,1 , s 2 ,1 22, n where pSwhere s2, 1 (2, n . vector of (12) g S = 2, n ) = h 1 signals s2 received From where vv N(s(3s, s is the ofc a+ (loan )3=) max {g (value Y − r) − 1 − g )after v(s3 , stwo 1 +.= s n, entrepreneurs. − 1 )sn is the 1from (s 1 ,..., 3 ), 0}, where vector of signals s3,2sthe received from nof entrepreneurs. From (12)aitloanofat s (12) p (g S 2, n ) = ) ninvestor where v(sas is the value aFrom loan after two observations ] whereit Sis = [s 2,1 , Ssthat s 22gh,,1ng < is vector of signals sobservations received from entrepreneurs. (12) itnot negative, can always decide to grant 2that ,2n,..., 2g , 2the 2 ,probability nprobability 3indicates 3of (12) is evident if , the < the that signal s a good entrepreneur is decreasing evident if s . Note that v ( s , s ) cannot be − 1 2 , n 2 , 2 3 3 3 2 2 h 1 n v N (s3 ) = max{g (Y − r ) − c + (1 − g )v(s3 , s3 ), 0}, (14) + − 1 ( 1 ) signal s2 indicates entrepreneur investor decide whereFrom v(s 3(12) ,iss 3 ) itnegative, is the valueasofthe a loan after can two always observations of not s3 . Note that v(s the vector ofthat signals from an good entrepreneurs. g 1 −sh2 received 1 if ifgg > negative, as the investor can always decide to n. grant loan 1 1 , the probabils3 at.B the ainvestor continues comparing if thenot signal decreasing inSimilarly, n.if Similarly, < probability signal sloan indicates aare good entrepreneur isfirst decreasing is evident to(1), grant at all.s2 Since also g <that , the probability that signal sthat indicates a2 good entrepreneur is decreasing is evident that with good isg (Y – r) – c > 0 increasing in In a is in n. 2if g > 2 , 2the probability that2 entrepreneurs ity that entrepreneurs with s2 are negative, good is as in-the by (1), the investor continues comparing if the (s 3 ,always where vcan s 3 ) is the value loan after observations decide notoftoa grant a loantwo at all. Since alsoofg (s obability that signal s 2 indicates a good entrepreneur is decreasinginvestor where S 2,ninin = n. s 2,In s the is the of signals sstationary, from ncontinues entrepreneurs. From (1), the investor comparing if(12) the itfirst signal is s .B 1 vector 1 s 2 , n when creasing n, the approaches first signal is sare the investor’s problem we can easily solve (14) recursively. Thisin yields 1Similarly, 2g , 2 ,..., 2 received 3. Because > limit , the probability that entrepreneurs with s good is increasing in n. In in n. Similarly, if,where g > probability that entrepreneurs with s are good is increasing n. n. if the limit when n approaches infinity, incomplete informational is removed with certainty: If In be 3 2 2 2v (s , s ) is2 the value of a loan after two observations of s . Note that v (s , s ) cannot 3 3 3 3 3 infinity, incomplete informational is removed is stationary, we can easily solve (14) recurnegative, ascomparing the investor can first decide to grant a loan at the investor continues the signal is snot re S 2,n = sthat signals s(1), n entrepreneurs. Fromif (12) italways 3 .Because the inves 2 ,1 , sentrepreneurs 2 , 2 ,..., s 2 , n is the 2 received robability withvector s 21 areofgood is increasing in from n. In stationary, can easily solve (14) recursively. This yields sively. This=we yields 1 lim with certainty: Ifngg < , Sthe p(g |and S2, n) = 0, and <when probability that signal s 2pindicates a1is.good entrepreneur is decreasing is evident iflim the limit when approaches infinity, incomplete informational removed with certainty: If the n approaches infinity, incomplete informational is removed with certainty: If 2 g that < 12 ,limit p g = 0 , if g > , lim g S We will conclude this as follows. negative, as decide not g , n the investor can always g , n to grant a loan at all. Since also g (Y − r ) − c >0 by n → ∞ 2 n − >∞ n −>∞ (1), the investor continues comparing if the first signal is s3 .B 1 stationary, we can easily solve (14) recursively. This yields N −1 limprobability p(g | S2, nis ) = 1. We will conclude < 1 2 , the that signal s indicates a good vident that incomplete ifif gg > infinity, informational removed with certainty: If entrepreneur is decreasing ª1 follows. − (1 − g ) in ºn. In 1 0 , and if g > 21 , lim p (g 1S n → ∞ p (1g S ) ) = = 1 . We will conclude this as g > , the probability that entrepreneurs with s are good is increasing ingn.< Similarly, if g < , lim p g S = 0 , and if g > , lim p g S = 1 . We will conclude this as follows. g , n g , n 2 , lim 2 ( ) [ ] = − − ( ) . v s g Y r c (15) 2 g ,n g ,3n signal is s3 .Because 2 investor the investor's problem is continues comparing if theN first 2 (1), the 2 « » n − >∞ n −>∞ n − >∞ n −>∞ this as follows. stationary, we can easily solve This yields ¬ (14)grecursively. N −1 ¼ ) if g > 12 , lim p(g> S1 g,,nthe = 1probability . We will conclude this as follows. g that entrepreneurs with s are good is increasing in n. In Similarly, if ª º ( ) − − 1 1 g 2 2 n −>∞ [isg (first − r ) − c ]«with certainty: v N (sThis Yremoved the limit when nstationary, approaches infinity, incomplete informational » . If bound, 3 ) = yields we can easilyofsolve (14) recursively. N −signal 1 RemarkRemark 1 When 1. the number of contacted and In words, if s3g, thewithout investor When the number contacted and evaluated ª1 the º ¬ isgrows − (loan 1 − g )applicants ¼ ]«with certainty: − r ) − ccontacting v N (s3 ) = [gis (Yremoved loan applicants grows without a bound, continues and the entre» . comparing limit when evaluated n approaches infinity, incomplete informational If 1 1 g grows g <problem lim p g S gthe 0 , and if number g > 2 , islim p gevaluated S gpreneurs 1loan . We will conclude as follows. Remark 1. When of contacted and bound, ¬applicants ¼ thiswithout , n1.=number ,n = 2 , the N −1 2. The bound, the information until she encounters When the and evaluated loan applicants of incomplete information is eliminated with certainty. n −Remark nof >problem ∞ of incomplete −elim> ∞contacted ª1 − (1signal −grows g ) ºswithout 1of contacted 1 ( [ − c ]« v N this sthe gfollows. (Y −isr )increasing inated with certainty. value of loan in the » . total and evaluated loan applicants grows without bound, 3)= , lim p g S = 0 , and if g > , lim p g S = 1 . We will conclude as g ,n N −1 2 2 g n − >∞ ninformation −>∞ ª1 − (1 −with º of entrepreneurs in¬ the economy, theg ,nproblem of incomplete is eliminated certainty. ) gnumber ¼ since the problem vofN incomplete is eliminated with certainty. (s3 ) = [g (Y −information ] (15) r) − c « ». g The above discussion dismisses the costs increasingly likely that the investor mation is eliminated with certainty. ¬ of it becomes ¼ The1.above dismisses costs contacting. the investor contacts n entrepreneurs, contacting. IfWhen the discussion investor contacts n the entreprewill findloan aIfgood entrepreneur and canbound, grant a the Remark the number of contacted andofevaluated applicants grows without n [ ] [ [ ] ] [ ] ( ) ( ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( neurs, the total cost of contacting amounts to ) ) loan. The above discussion dismisses theevaluated costs of contacting. If the investor contacts bound, n entrepreneurs, the mark 1. When ofofcontacted and grows total cost contacting amounts n loan c .costs Toapplicants investigate thesignal investor’s how The above discussion dismisses the of contacting. Ifwithout the investor n ofentrepreneurs, n c.the To number investigate the investor’s optimal choice The first is soptimal inchoice section 3, if much the tothe 2. Ascontacts the problem of incomplete information istoeliminated with certainty. the costs of of contacting. If the investorincontacts n entrepreneurs, the how much to invest information gathering, signal is optimal s2, and choice the second signal total cost of contacting amounts to n c . To investigate first the investor’s of how muchistodifferproblem of incomplete information iscontacting eliminated with total cost ofthe to ninic . Toent investigate optimal information choice of howismuch to taking into account costs, weamounts writecertainty. the (either sthe s3), incomplete 1 orinvestor’s to n c . To investigate optimal choice of how tial value the of ainvestor’s loan analogously to (11) as much toeliminated and the investor can make an optimal lending However, if the second signal The above discussion dismisses the costs of contacting. If the decision. investor contacts n entrepreneurs, the is also s2, the investor can update her priors. above discussion dismisses the costs of contacting. If the investor contacts n entrepreneurs, the total cost of contacting amounts to n c . To investigate the investor’s optimal choice of how much to 101 cost of contacting amounts to n c . To investigate the investor’s optimal choice of how much to comparing canis ineliminated practice render deficiency of information (either s1 orinformation s 3 ), incomplete information andmake the can can make an her insignifican lending decision. However, if theand second signal iscan also s 2the , investor the update ferent (either s1different or s 3optimal ), incomplete is eliminated the investor an investor decreasing in n, the probability that incomplete information obtn t (either s1 or s 3 ), incomplete information is eliminated and thetheinvestor can entrepreneurs. makethat an yields, only good With probabilities h and (1 − g) contacting nth like all previous optimal lending decision. However, thecontacted second signal is alsoof , entrepreneurs the investor can update her n-1 priors. Subsequently, the investor grant to entrepreneur either releasing signal s 2 ,1contacts, sig 2 update imal lending decision. However, if the second signalif can is also s 2a, loan the investor cansthe her ( ) = . p g S if the investor has 2 , n not received two differ Finnish Economic Papers 2/2007 – Juha-Pekka Niinimäki andEven Tuomas Takalo h s 2,n1 is the S 2,n = s 2,1 ,Because s 2n, 2 ,..., n v lending decision. However, if the second signal is also investor s 2 , the investor can update her1bad where ( ) = . p g S has compared only entrepreneurs. probabiliti 2 , n the (1 −a hthird priors. Subsequently, theexit can grant a loan to either of signal s1)2 g+, loan ( − 1 ) can decide to thetocredit market without lending, or entrepreneurs she can to compare hpproceed ors. Subsequently, the she investor can ainvestor loan ofa the releasing signal , )render (g(Ss122,nreleasing theentrepreneurs entrepreneur is good is gor 1 − hof informatio Subsequently, thegrant investor can either grantthat loan to comparing To understand Proposition recall can practice the deficiency n from (12) − 1=) n3, 1 +in ( 1 ) − h g + h(1 − g1 ) n h g − 1 Subsequently, the investor can grant a loan to the either thesignal entrepreneurs ,that either ofdecide the entrepreneurs releasing that p (gprobability | Ssignal ) issnot ina nthird when gg < <the ,. the probabi is evident that 2, be 2, nproceed 2decreasing decreasing inreleasing n, incomplete information 2 obtains appro applicant. she takes lastofoption, she swill in athe similar but identical position asif after she can toIfexit the credit market or she can to compare loan can decide to exit market without lending, or without shewithout can lending, proceed to compare a third loan she the cancredit decide to exit the credit market Thus, if granting a loan to thethat firstyields, entrepreneur contacting the nth entrepreneur like all previous n-1 [ ] decide to exit the credit market without lending, or sheshe canwill to compare loan lending, or she can proceed compare aproceed third sthird isor unprofitable (p (her greceived | s2beliefs. )Y < r), itg will second contact: either theto incomplete information isEven eliminated she canhas update 2not ifathe investor not two different signals > 12 , the probab n. Similarly, ifthe applicant. she takes option, be in asignalling similar but identical position as after plicant. If she takes lastIfoption, she the willlast in a similar but not as afterwhere thein S 2,n = s 2,1 , sentrepre2 , 2 ,..., s 2 , n is the nvecto loanthe applicant. If she takesbethe last option, sheidentical remainposition unprofitable for all subsequent ( 1 ) − h g Sneurs =inswith ,as s 2she vector signals ss2 received from nt. If she takes the last she will benot in identical a after similar but not where identical (ghave ) =information pout Softhat that entrepreneur is is good is ,= n the 2 ,1or , 2after 2 ,update nalso will be option, in a similar position as s1,..., .can Itsthe turns an exit, Inbut general, the investor encountered who emitted 2 , nof (has )2position second contact: either the incomplete information her beliefs. comparing practice render the deficiency . the giscan S 2eliminated 2entrepreneurs 2 , n insignifi , ncan the limit when n approaches infin ond contact: either the incomplete information is eliminated or pshe update herhn-1 beliefs. ( 1 ) ( 1 − h g + h −g 1 1 n isevident after the second contact: either the incomplete yielding not optimal In probability < 2 ., the that if ifgg < − 1 )is 1 + zero (payoff, contact: either the incomplete information is eliminated or she can update her beliefs. 1 h< 2g,the −gg < information eliminated orbethe she can as update her thethat case probability thatallasignal new s 2 , congeneral, after investor has encountered n-1entrepreneur entrepreneurs have emitted thethat probability s 2 indicates a go is evident if1of the value of a loanhas can written the nth yields, previous n-1 contacts, 1 like swho In general, after theisIninvestor encountered n-1contacting entrepreneurs who have emitted 2 , g < 2 , lim p g S g , n = 0 , and if g > 1 n − >∞ beliefs. tact eliminates incomplete information exceeds In general, after the investor has encountered n-1 entrepreneurs who have emitted1 s 2 , in n. Similarly, if g > 2 ,n the probabilit after thebe investor g and, thus return from theInvalue of a loan written has as encountered > 2expected , the probability that entrepreneurs in n. Similarly, if gthe (1each − h) gnew with s 2 value of a loan can begeneral, written as can or the entrepreneur is is p(g S 21, n ) = (recall n-1 entrepreneurs who have emitted s2, that the valcontact g (Y – r) – c > 0 (1)). The n infinity . p (gexceeds S 2good ,n ) = theh limit when (1 n− h)nsg2 napproaches ) +(16) h(1 − gfrom e of a loan can be written as v(S is the vector of1 signals received n entr (S 2,n−1 ), t nwhere (Y − r ) S+2(,1n −= t nsinvestor )2v,1(,Ss22,,n2 ),..., max{v Ras − thus cs}2,n compares −1 ) = ue of a loan can2,nbe written entrepreneurs until in1+ ( − 1 )incomplete informational i the limit when n approaches infinity, heliminated. g complete information1 −isRemark 1. When the number of co g < 12 , lim p g(16) S g ,n = 0 , and if g > 12 1 (16) (1 − t n ) vthat ( } −− rcis)}+evident S 2,nif) −Ifcgg > n − > ∞ , the investor’s behaviour is different. < probability that signal s indicates a good ent {v R (Sv2(,Sn−21,)n,−t1n)(=Y max ) v(S 2,n −1 ) = max − r ){+v R(1(S−2t,nn−)1v),(tSn2(,Y (16) n g < 12 , lim p g2 S g ,n 21 = 0 , and if g > 12 , lim p2 g S g ,n = 1 . We will n −such n − >of >∞ ∞number In circumstance the optimal of the problem incomplete informatio (S 2,n−1 ) = max{vR (S 2,n−1where ), t n (Y −vr )(S+ (1 −)t=n )max v(S 2,n ) − c } (16) 1 under uncertainty after n-1 {p(g S 2.n−1in)Yn n.− rSimilarly, ,0} p is(gthe value aisloan always finite, verified by with then s are goo = > 12of, the . that as Scomparisons R 2 , n −1 probability entrepreneurs 2if ,n ) g n h ( 1 − h ) g + h ( 1 − g ) . With probability 1-h the state low probability g the where S = s , s 1is,..., s andiswith the vector of signals s22 investo receive 2 , n proposition. where vR (S2, n–1) = max{p (g | S2, n–1)Y–r, 0} is the following 1 + 2,1 (2, 2 − 1 )2n,n h g − 1 ( ) { ( ) } v S = max p g S Y − r , 0 is the value of a loan under uncertainty after n-1 where n–1limit Remark 1.that When the number of RSloan 2 , n −under 1 and uncertainty 2+sig [1 when )](1 − g ) isafter where t2.n −=1 after p (h Sof gsloan −under p (h Sn2,uncertainty the probability incomplete max{of ps(2gasignals n-1 ere v R (S 2,n −1 ) =value 2 , n −1a) n −1approaches infinity, incomplete informational is conta remo 2. n −1 )Y − r ,0} is then value the 1 h and (1 − g) n the state is high and contacted only good With probabilities The above discussion dismisses theapp c nals and where t ( h | S2, n–1)g + [1–p ( h |entrepreneurs. S2, n–1 )] Proposition 4 If g > , investor stops comRemark 1. When the number of contacted and evaluated loan g < the probability that signal s indicat is evident that if n = p 2 2 v R (S 2,n −1 ) = max{p (g S 2.n −1 )Y − r ,0} is the value of a loan under uncertainty after n-1 (1–g) is theand probability that incomplete paring new loan applicants even ifincomplete incomplete the of information ( ) [ ( ) ] ( ) s signals where t = p h S g + 1 − p h S 1 − g is the probability that incomplete 1infor1problem information will be eliminated by the nth contact. Here 2 n 2 , n − 1 2 , n − 1 lim probability p g S g ,n =that 0 , and if g > 2 , lim p g S g ,n = 1 .n We will conclunis signals and where t n = p (h S 2,n −1 )g + [1 − p (h S 2,n −1 )](1 −gg<) 2is, the incomplete cost of contacting amounts nc n −problem > ∞bad > ∞is eliminated mation will be eliminated by the nth contact. remains. the of incomplete certainty. investor has compared only Because probabilities and (1 −tog)w > 1 ,total then −probability thatgwith entrepreneurs ininformation n. entrepreneurs. Similarly, if ginformation als and where t n = p (h S 2,n −1 )g + [1 − p (h S 2,n −1 )](1n −−1 g ) is where the probability incomplete S 2,n = s 2,1that , s 2, 2 ,..., s 2,n is the2 vector of signals s 2 received from n e information will h(1be by the nth Here contact. Here − g ) by eliminated ormation will the Here p(hbeS 2,n −1 ) =eliminatedn −1 )limit = 1 − p (g nth S 2On is contact. the conditional that the in state is the one hand, p (g |probability S2, nobtains ) is increasing nzero, by , n −1incomplete n− 1 decreasing in n,hthe probability that information approaches when n→ the when n approaches infinity, incomplete informat h ( 1 − g ) + ( 1 − ) g 1 tion will be eliminated the is evident nth that contact. Here n −1by The above discussion dismisses the costs (12), if g > . The probability approaches unity g < , the probability that signal s indicates a good if 2 n −1 h ( 1 − g ) 2 hp(1(h−Sg2,)n −1 ) = ) probability = 1if−conditional p (g The S 2,n −1. iswhen the conditional probability that the stateover isreturn discussion the of evaluated contacting. If first the investor 1above n isnumber largedismisses enough, andcosts the expected When the oftwo contacted and loan applicants n −1p (g S nis −1 theRemark h S 2,n −1 ) = = 1− that is Even the different signals the n cont 1 (1 −2,nh−)1 g)signals g has < 12 ,not limreceived p the g S gstate previous are s 2investor . , n = 0 , and if g > 2 , lim p g S g , n = 1 . W h(h1(−1 −g )gn)−1n −+1 high (1 − hwhen ) ghn(1−1−allg )n-1 + total cost of contacting to nc . T n − > ∞ 1under uncertainty, p (g | S2, n)Y – r, n − > ∞amounts from a loan apg > , the probability that entrepreneurs with s in n. Similarly, if = 1 − p (g S 2,n −1 ) is the conditional probability that the2 state is 2 are −1 ) = n −1 n −1 total cost of contacting amounts to n c . To investigate the investor’s h(1 − g ) is+ (the 1 − hconditional )g Y – r. On the other hand, the expected probabilitycan that staterender is ofproaches comparing in the practice the deficiency of information insignificant. To see this, cono problem incomplete information is eliminated with certainty. high when all n-1 signals are sthe 2 . h when all n-1 previous signals areprevious sprevious . return from contacting a new loan applicant is high when all n–1 signals are s . 2 2 limit when n approaches infinity, incomplete informational the is re always lower than Y – r – c. Thus, when n is The value of the loan (16) could be solved hen all n-1 previous signals are s 2 . contacting the nth entrepreneur that yields, like all previous n-1 contacts, signal s 2 . The probab large enough, thethe investor granting backwards, beginning with the termination payRemark 1. When numberprefers of contacted and aevaluated lo g < 12 , lim p g S g ,n = 0 , and if g > 12 , lim p g S g ,n = 1 . We will con n − loan n −>∞ >∞ n of The above dismisses the costs contacting. If the investor contac under uncertainty to contacting and comoff vR (S2, N) = max{p (g | S2, N)Y–r, 0}. Because thediscussion (1 − h) g (g problem S 2, n )a=new ortheisnumber that the entrepreneur good is pthe paring loan napplicant, and of with certai problem is non-stationary, however, issolving of incomplete information eliminated n (1 − h) gto +n ch(.1To ) − ginvestigate of contacting amounts compared loan applicants is finite. the investor’s optimal (16) completely is a messy exercisetotal andcost does [ [ ] ] ( [ ) ] ( ( ) [ ( ( ] ( ( ) ) ) ] ) [ ( ) ) ( ( ) ) An implication of Proposition 4 is that it can not yield substantial insights. Nonetheless, from beWhen optimal grant ofa contacted loan already the firstloan applica (16) we obtain a few general results that are 1. Remark the to number andtoevaluated above discussion the about costs ofhis contacting. If the in entrepreneur even ifdismisses uncertainty type intuitive but tedious to prove. In the remainder The 1 remains, as in the two-entrepreneur economy of of the section we presentp (the results (Proposi. (1 g S 2, n ) = the problem of incomplete information is eliminated with certainty. h for1 total of contacting to nsuch c . To investigate the inves It is easyamounts to see that a lending tions 3 and 4) and give heuristic arguments 1+ ( −section 1 ) n cost 3.3. 1 − h g strategy is optimal if the first loan applicant is them (for the formal proofs of the propositions, good with a sufficiently high probability or if see Niinimäki and Takalo, 2007). The above discussion dismisses the costs of contacting. If the investor con the contacting is sufficiently costly. Proposition 3 If the net present value of a loan [s(s2,12,) ≤ 0) ] is ofthecontacting S 2,n (v = R s 2, 2 ,..., s 2,ncost vector of signals from n entrepreneurs. From (1 total amountss 2toreceived n c . To investigate the investor’s optim under uncertainty iswhere negative and the prior probability that a loan applicant has a 5. Multiple investors and financial good project is less than one theprobability < 12 ), , the that signal s 2 indicates a good entrepreneur is decrea is evident thathalf if g(g < intermediation investor continues to contact and compare new Sectionsthat 3 and 4 show howwith making benchmarks loan applicants until problem of g > 12 , the probability entrepreneurs s 2 are good is increasing in in the n. Similarly, if incomplete and comparisons is beneficial even if there is information is eliminated. only oneincomplete investor ininformational the credit market. If there the limit when n approaches infinity, is removed with certaint are multiple investors, however, an arrangement 102 g < 12 , lim p(g S g ,n ) = 0 , and if g > 12 , lim p(g S g ,n ) = 1 . We will conclude this as follows. n − >∞ n −>∞ Remark 1. When the number of contacted and evaluated loan applicants grows without bo Finnish Economic Papers 2/2007 – Juha-Pekka Niinimäki and Tuomas Takalo wherein each investor separately collects information has many shortcomings: If an investor contacts one loan applicant and receives s2, the investor operates under incomplete information. The investor can gather more information by using the first signal as a benchmark and comparing signals from subsequent loan applicants with it. But this is costly. Each investor needs to contact several loan applicants even if each investor has only a unit of capital and she can grant only one loan. Each loan applicant is then contacted several times although each time the monitoring provides the very same information. Moreover, an investor cannot be sure ex ante that comparing several entrepreneurs will eliminate incomplete information. In this section we show how investors can overcome these shortcomings by establishing a coalition, financial intermediary as in Boyd & Prescott (1986) and Diamond (1984). For brevity, we focus on the case where there are (very) large numbers of entrepreneurs and investors. Suppose that an investor establishes a financial intermediary and invests her endowment in it as equity capital. This investor is called the banker. The other investors, labelled as depositors, invest their endowments in the intermediary. The banker offers a standard deposit contract to the depositors, promising to pay fixed interest rD on deposits that is senior to payments on equity capital. Let us proceed under the assumption that the banker contacts loan applicants and monitors them on the behalf of the other investors and check later that the contract is incentive compatible. Since the intermediary has a lot of funds and there are many entrepreneurs, it is likely that the banker contacts two different types of loan applicants, which eliminates incomplete information. Even if all the intermediary’s loan applicants are similar, the banker can be quite confident about the true state of the world and types of the loan applicants. In the limit, when the financial intermediary is sufficiently large, the incomplete information will be eliminated with certainty (Remark 1). Furthermore, the banker does not evaluate a loan applicant twice, and the duplication of information gathering is eliminated. To put it differently, a sufficiently large financial intermediary achieves the very same optimal solution that is achieved under perfect information. A conclusion follows: Proposition 5 If the investors join together and establish a financial intermediary, the duplication of information provision cost is avoided. When the intermediary is sufficiently large, incomplete information will be removed with certainty. This result resembles that of Diamond (1984). In both models, the financial intermediary is bank-like and eliminates the duplication of information provision, thereby cutting the costs of lending. Nonetheless, the models differ in some important aspects: In Diamond (1984), centralised information provision is profitable, since a single investor can finance only a small fraction of a project. Thus many investors are needed to finance the whole project. If each investor monitored the project, the cost of monitoring would be duplicated. The duplication can be eliminated by establishing a financial intermediary, which monitors the project only once. On the contrary, in our model, centralised information provision is profitable even if a single investor can finance the whole project! If a single investor financed only one project, she should contact numerous loan applicants to gather information. With multiple investors, the same loan applicants would be contacted by several investors and the cost of contacting would be duplicated. Useless duplication can be avoided by establishing a centralised intermediary. In our case the banker monitors each loan applicant at most once. The exact number of contacted loan applicants depends on the ratio of good loan applicants to investors. Let F ∈Z + denote the number of investors. When F and N (the number of entrepreneurs) are very large, the realized share of contacted good loan applicants is fixed, g, owing to the law of large numbers. If gN > F, there are more good projects than investment funds in the economy. Since each contact is costly, the banker stops contacting upon encountering F good loan applicants. Hence the optimal number of contacted loan applicants is given by N* = F/g where N* < N. On the contrary, when gN ≤ F, good projects are scarcer, and the banker opti103 29 Finnish Economic Papers 2/2007 – Juha-Pekka Niinimäki Tuomas Takalo applicants who and proved to be good. The rest of the funds are mally contacts all loan applicants because the applicants who proved to be good. The rest of . Finally, ( F −in1)rthe option (the F −α gN *)rare D denotes expected return from a contact is positive (recall funds invested outsidepayments option on deposit 28 (1)), i.e., N* = N. (F– α gN*)r. Finally, (F–1)rD denotes payments using rD given bymanipulation the Remark 2, using (17) can 28 the Pushing the ondefinition deposits.ofAfter some thebe rewritten a 28 argument for centralised finan1 cial intermediation we canand also definition of rD given by the Remark 2, (17) can intermediary has F investorsto(the F −limit, 1 depositors thedebanker), F Π is the profit share of a single termine the deposit rate. Let Π denote the total be rewritten as 1 has the F investors and the nvestors28 ( F − 1intermediary depositors and banker), (F1FΠ− 1is depositors the profit share of banker), a single F Π is the profit share of a single profit of the intermediary. Because the intermeinvestor. (18) π B = Max { rD + N * [c − (1 − α )g (Y − r )],0 } . diary has F investors (F–1 depositors and the investor. 1 theprofit profitshare shareofofa asingle single in- This shows that the banker’s income is increasositors and the banker), banker), F ΠΠ isis the ing in α and is thus maximised when α =1. That vestor. is,tothe contacts andreturn, monitors optimal Remark 2. A sufficiently large intermediary can anbanker investor a fixed of the in Thispay shows that the banker's income is increasing Į and is thus maxim amount of entrepreneurs. In this case the bankRemark 2 A sufficiently large intermediary can Remark 2. A sufficiently large intermediary can pay to an investor a fixed return, of fficiently large intermediary can pay to an investor a fixed return, of ers income is r + cN* which exactly equals to pay1 to an investor a fixed return, of banker contacts and monitors the optimal amount of entrepreneurs. In t D N* [ rD ≡ lim F Π = r + g (Y − r ) − c )] . the opportunity cost of the equity capital inF →∞ F N * N* 1 [g (Y − r ) − c )] . r+ is rD+cN* whichinexactly equals to intermediary the opportunity and cost of [g (Y − rcan ) − cr)D]pay .≡ Flim vested the financial thethe equity cap F Π ermediary an= investor →to ∞ F a fixed return, of F (non-monetary) costs of contacting. Just as in intermediary and (1984) the (non-monetary) of contacting. Diamond the incentivecosts problem betweenJust as in Di The result follows from the law of large numthethe bank its depositors is At eliminated thanks The result from thethe lawidea of large numbers (1984). and it utilises ideaand of Diamond (1984). the bersfollows and it utilises of Diamond problemtobetween the bank and its depositors is eliminated thanks to the thethe law theoflarge numbers. At the beginning ofutilises period, each investor deposThe result follows from the law of large numbers and it utilises theofidea Diamond (1984). At the rom the law of large numbers and it the idea of Diamond (1984). At beginning of unit period, eachintermediary. investor deposits unit conin the intermediary. Thethat banker contacts theno incentive Finally, note investors have its her in the The her banker Finally, note that investors have no incentive to form an beginning of period, each investor deposits her unit in the intermediary. The banker contacts thepower, to form an intermediary to gain market tacts the optimal number of loan applicants, N*, , each investor deposits her unit in the intermediary. The banker contacts the optimal numbergood of loan applicants, N *something , finances is good projects and, if something they is left, puts the all the sursince by assumption can extract finances projects and, if left, numbers and it utilises the idea of Diamond (1984). At the power, since by assumption they can extract all the surplus from e number of applicants, Nsomething * , finances projects if somethingThe is left, puts the oan applicants,optimal N * ,the finances projects is good left,plus puts the and, from entrepreneurs. tendency towards puts rest ofgood theloan funds inand, the ifoutside option. rest of the funds in the outside option. At the end of the period, the loans yield a net return of centralised financial intermediation arises soleAt the end of the period, the loans yield a net towards centralised financial intermediation arises solely from economi sits her unit in the intermediary. The banker contacts the rest ofAtthe in the period, outside option. the end the period, the loansofyield return of the outside option. thefunds end of the loansAtyield a netofly return ofeconomics from scalea innetcomparing. return of N* ( gY– c) and the outside option N * ( gY − c) and the outside option yields ( F − gN *) . The intermediary can then pay a return of rD (F– gN*)r. The intermediary can the then pay , finances goodyields projects and, if something is left, puts * ( gY(−F c−) gN and the outside option yields ( F −pay gN *) . The intermediary can then pay a return of rD e outside optionaNyields *) . The intermediary canthe then return of r per deposit unit and bankera return of rD D per deposit unit and the banker also obtains return rD on his investment. Clearly, equation (1) obtains the return rD yield on hisa investment. 6. Conclusion 6. Conclusion At the end of also the period, loans net return ofClearper obtains deposit return unit and banker also obtains return rD on (1) his investment. Clearly, equation (1) d the banker also rD the on his investment. Clearly, equation ly, equation (1) implies that r > r. From the D implies that rD>r. From the assumed market structure, itasfollows that entrepreneurs earn zero profit. In this paper we study ex ante benchmarking ds ( F − gN *) . The intermediary can then pay a return rstructure, sumed market structure, follows thatofentrepreD rD>r. From theitassumed market it follows that entrepreneurs earn zero profit. om the assumedimplies marketthat structure, it follows that entrepreneurs earn zero profit. and comparing a source of information in neurs earn zero profit. In equilibrium there is no incentive problem between the bankerasand the depositors. In this paper we study ex ante benchmarking and comparing financial markets. Making and as a sourc In equilibrium there is no incentive problem btains return r on his investment. Clearly, equation (1) D equilibrium therethe is no incentive problem between the banker and thebenchmarks depositors. ilibrium there is no incentiveInproblem between banker and the depositors. comparing it amount Suppose that thethe banker misbehaves and contactsSuppose only a fraction α of the others (optimalwith number of) loan to a simple between banker and the depositors. markets. Makingαbenchmarks andItnumber comparing others with it amount of the learning. has many features ket structure, itSuppose follows that the entrepreneurs earn profit. that banker misbehaves contacts only a ainstrument that banker misbehaves and contacts only fraction of (optimal of) loan nker misbehaves and the contacts only a fraction αand ofzero the (optimal number of) loan applicants. In this way she can not only save some costs of contacting but also invest an extra common with other forms of learning such as fraction α of the (optimal number of) loan aplearning. It has many features common with other forms of learning learning by doing, experimentation and imitaincentive problem between the banker and the depositors. applicants. In this way she can not only save some costs of contacting but also invest an extra plicants. In this way she can not only save some way she can not only save some costs of contacting but also invest an extra amountcosts of the funds in the outside option. The net revenue – thehowever, retion.intermediary's The other forms of learning, of intermediary's contacting but also invest an extra experimentation and imitation. The other forms– of learning, however, re funds in the outside option. intermediary's the contacts only aamount fraction αthe of intermediary's the (optimal of)in loan quire many observationsnetonrevenue the same entrepremediary's funds in the of outside option. Thenumber intermediary's netoutrevenue – The the amount of the intermediary’s funds the banker’s income - is at most (when the banker has contacted sufficiently many loan applicants to be neur over timeover whereas comparing exploits the the differe side option. The intermediary’s net revenue the–contacted same entrepreneur timeloan whereas comparing banker’s income - is but at most (when the banker many applicants toWe be exploits yatsave of contacting also invest an extra mostsome (whencosts the banker has contacted sufficiently many loanhas applicants tosufficiently be differences between entrepreneurs. show the banker’s income – is at most (when the able to interpret the signals correctly) how incomplete be reduced reducedbybymaking bench banker has contacted sufficiently many loan We ap- show how incompleteinformation information can can be able toThe interpret the signalsnet correctly) signals correctly) the outside option. revenue – the cor- making benchmarks and comparisons. By complicants tointermediary's be able to interpret the signals paring sufficiently entrepreneurs, an incomparing sufficiently manymany entrepreneurs, an investor can separate go rectly) anker has contacted sufficiently many loan applicants to be vestor can separate good from bad loan appli(17) (17) π B = Max {YαgN * +( F − αgN *)r − ( F − 1)rD , 0 } If every investor invests in information gathering, it wi cants. { } π = Max Y α gN * + ( F − α gN *) r − ( F − 1 ) r , 0 (17) Max {YαgN * + (F − αgN *)r − (BF − 1)rD , 0 } (17) IfD every investor invests in information gathSince the intermediary is very large, the realised ering, it will be inefficient, since loan applicants are compared several timesowing with to zero informafractions of different are fixed owing of different Since the intermediary is veryasset large,types the realised fractions asset types are fixed tion gain. To prevent the useless duplication of to the law of large numbers. In (17) Y α g N* repSince the intermediary is very large, the realised fractions of different asset types are fixed owing to large, realised fractions of different asset types owing to } lending αry gNis*)very r −the ( F law − 1the )rof (17) are fixed D , 0large numbers. In (17) * represents αgNcontacted returns the frominvestors the contacted loan join togethcomparing, optimally resents returns from Ythe loanlending large numbers. (17) Yα gN *the represents umbers. In (17)theYαlaw gN *ofrepresents lendingIn returns from contactedlending loan returns from the contacted loan 104 realised fractions of different asset types are fixed owing to gN * represents lending returns from the contacted loan Finnish Economic Papers 2/2007 – Juha-Pekka Niinimäki and Tuomas Takalo er and establish a financial intermediary, which contacts each loan applicant only once. If the intermediary can grow without bound, the problem of incomplete information can be eliminated with certainty without further investment in information acquisition. This provides a novel rationale for centralised financial intermediation. An implication of our model is that financial institutions such as banks can become dominant financiers of an industry by exploiting scale economies in comparing. Once a bank has gathered information about firms in the industry by comparing them, it is difficult for new financial institutions to enter the market for finance of the industry. The entrants should start the process of comparing from the beginning whereas the incumbents know the firms and the signals. Thus, even if the incumbents and entrants observe the same information, the incumbents may have an information advantage since they are able to interpret the information correctly. Only in new industries will old and new financiers compete on equal footing. In such circumstances the efficient use of benchmarks and comparisons can be the crucial determinant of financial institutions’ successes and failures. Indeed, although we have emphasised the role of comparing in credit markets and that the intermediary arising from our analysis is banklike, comparing is perhaps even more relevant for business angels, venture capitalists and other entities that focus on financing new high-tech industries. As carefully documented by Gompers and Lerner (2004), such private equity financiers frequently encounter ideas for businesses in areas where there is little available information. The lack of track records for applicants or a particular business area does not lead to the collapse of markets for innovation finance, since financiers seek many applications from the same narrow area. In comparing applications, it becomes evident that funding should be denied to some business ideas. The most promising projects receive the first stage financing. After a new round of comparing, only the most successful firm can obtain second stage financing. The next logical step is to endogenise the form of financial contract so as to enable assessment of the relative benefits of benchmarking and comparing in private equity and debt finance. Another interesting issue would be to introduce some tradeoffs to counter the tendency towards bigger financial intermediaries predicted by our model. For example, investors should be allowed to go beyond benchmarking and comparing and use other strategies to mitigate information asymmetry such as estimation of cash flows. Finally, the model has been simplified by assuming that the state of the world has no effect on the project output. This is a strong assumption. Relaxing it and many other intriguing issues are left for future work. QED References Balk, B. (2003). “The residual: on monitoring and benchmarking firms, industries, and economies with respect to productivity.” Journal of Productivity Analysis 20(1), 5–47. Bergemann, D., and U. Hege (1998). “Venture capital financing, moral hazard, and learning.” Journal of Banking & Finance 22, 703–735. Bergemann, D., and U. Hege (2002). “The value of benchmarking.” In Venture Capital Contracting and the Valuation of High Tech Firms. Eds. J. McCahery and L. Renneboog. Oxford University Press, Oxford. Berger, A., S. Frame, and N. Miller (2005). “Credit scoring and the availability, price, and risk of small business credit.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 37(2), 191–222. Bester, H. (1985). “Screening vs. rationing in credit markets with imperfect information.” American Economic Review 75, 401–405. Blochlinger, A., and M. Leippold (2006). “Economic benefit of powerful credit scoring.” Journal of Banking and Finance 30(3), 851–873. Boot, A. W. (2000). “Relationship banking: what do we know?” Journal of Financial Intermediation 9, 7–25. Boyd, J., and E. Prescott (1986). “Financial intermediarycoalitions.” Journal of Economic Theory 38(3), 211– 232. Broecker, T. (1990). “Credit-worthiness tests and interbank competition.” Econometrica 58(2), 429–452. Cerasi, V., and S. Daltung (2000). “The optimal size of a bank: costs and benefits of diversification.” European Economic Review 44(9), 1701–1726. Courty, P., and G. Marschke (2004). “Benchmarking performance.” Public Finance and Management 4(3), 288– 316. Diamond, D. (1984). “Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring.” Review of Economic Studies 51, 393–414. Freixas, X., and J-C. Rochet (1997). Microeconomics of Banking. The MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts. Hellwig, M. (2000). “Financial intermediation with risk aversion.” Review of Economic Studies 67, 719–742. Holmström, B. (1979). “Moral hazard and observability.” Bell Journal of Economics 10, 74–91. 105 the most successful firm can obtain second stage financing. The next logic the most successful firm can obtain second stage the most successful firm can obtain second stage financing. The next logical step is to endogenise the form of financial contract so as to enable assessment of the relative b the form of financial contract so as to enable ass 31 31 the form of financial contract so –asJuha-Pekka to enable assessment theTuomas relative Takalo benefits of benchmarking Finnish Economic Papers 2/2007 Niinimäkiofand and comparing in private equity and debt finance. and comparing in private equity and debt finance. Holmström, B., andin J. private Tirole (1997). “Financial intermeRamakrishnan, R., and A. Thakor (1984). “Information and comparing equity and debt finance. the most successful firm can obtain second stage financing. The next logical step is to diation, funds firm and the sector.” Quarterly reliability and anext theory of financial intermediation.” Rethe mostloanable successful canreal obtain second stage financing. The logical step is tobeendogenise endogenise Another interesting issue would to introduce some tr Journal of Economics 112, 663–691. view of Economic Studies 51, 415–432.interesting issue would Another Gombers, P., andAnother J. Lerner interesting (2004). The Venture Capital Sharpe, S. (1990). “Asymmetric information, bank lending issue would be to introduce some tradeoffs to counter the the form of financial contract as enable of relative benefits of benchmarking the form financial contract so so as to to enable2ndassessment assessment of the the relativeintermediaries benefits benchmarking Cycle. TheofMIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts, andbigger implicit contracts: A stylizedofmodel of customer tendency towards financial predicted by our model. tendency financial intermediaries Edition. relationships.” Journal towards of Financebigger 45(4), 1069–1087. tendency towards bigger financial intermediaries predicted by our model. For example, investors Gorton, G., and A. Winton (2003). “Financial IntermediaSiems, T., and R. Barr (1998). “Benchmarking the producand in equity and finance. and comparing comparing in private private equity and debt debt finance. should be allowed go beyond benchmarking and comparing and use oth tion.” In Handbook of The Economics of Finance. Eds. tive to efficiency of U.Sbe banks.” Financial Studies, should allowed to goIndustry beyond benchmarking a G. Constantinides, M. to Harris and R. M.benchmarking Stultz. Elsevier, and comparing 11–24. should be allowed go beyond and use other strategies to mitigate interesting would to some tradeoffs to counter the Another interesting issue issue would be be to introduce introduce some tradeoffs to and counter the North Holland, Another Amsterdam. Thomas, L. such (2000). “A survey of of credit behavioural information asymmetry as estimation cash flows. Finally, the mode information asymmetry suchtoasconsumestimation of cash Krasa, S., and A. Villamil (1992). “Monitoring the moniscoring: Forecasting financial risk of lending information asymmetry such as estimation of cash flows. Finally, themodel. model For has been simplified by tor: An incentive structure for a financial intermediary.” ers.” International Journal of Forecasting 16(2), 149– tendency towards financial intermediaries by our example, investors tendency towards bigger bigger financial predicted bythe ourworld model. example, investors assuming thatpredicted the state of hasFor no effect on the project output. Thi Journal of Economic Theory 57, 197–221.intermediaries 172. assuming that the state of the world has no effect Millon, M., and A. the Thakor (1985). “Moral hazard in- on Tirole, J. (2006). The Theory ofisCorporate Finance. Princassuming that state ofbeyond theinformation world hasgathering noand effect the project output. This a strong assumption. should be allowed to go benchmarking and comparing and use other strategies to mitigate formation sharing: A model of eton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey. should be allowed to go beyond benchmarking comparingtoand use other strategies to mitigateThat and man It would beand illuminating consider the reserve assumption. agencies.” Journal of Finance 40, 1403–1422. Von Thadden,ItE-L. (1995). “Long-term contracts, short-the reserve a would be illuminating to consider Niinimäki, J-P. (2001). “Intertemporal diversification in term investments and monitoring.” Review of Economic It would be illuminating to consider the reserve assumption. That and many other intriguing issues information asymmetry such of cash flows. Finally, the information asymmetryJournal such as asofestimation estimation offor cash flows. Finally, the model model has has been been simplified simplified by by financial intermediation.” Banking and FiStudies 62(4) , 557–575. are left future work. left(2004). for future work. information, nance 25(5), 965–991. Von Thadden,are E-L. “Asymmetric are left for future work. Niinimäki, J.-P., Takalo Benchmarking and on bankproject lendingoutput. and implicit The winner’s curse.” assuming that the of the has This is assumption. assuming thatand theT.state state of(2007). the world world has no no effect effect on the the project output. Thiscontracts: is aa strong strong assumption. comparing entrepreneurs with incomplete information. Financial Research Letters, 11–23. HECER Discussion Paper No. 173 (July, 2007). It be to the reserve That and intriguing issues It would would be illuminating illuminating to consider consider the reserve assumption. That and many many other other issues Pagano, M., and T. Jappelli (1993). “Information sharing assumption. Appendix A: Proof of Proposition 1 intriguing in credit markets.” Journal of Finance 48, 1693–1718. Appendix A: Proof of Proposition Appendix A: Proof are left work. are left for for future future work. of Proposition 1 1 Proof of part i): In the proof we use the following observation Proof of part i): In the proof we use Proof of part i): In the proof we use the following observation frequently 2 h(1 − g ) + (1 − h) g − g (1 − g ) = (1 − h) g 2 + h(1 − g ) . ( ) h 1 − g + ( 1 − h ) g − g ( 1 − g ) = (1 − h) g 2 + h 2 2 Appendix A: Proof of Proposition 1 ( ) ( ) h 1 − g + ( 1 − h ) g − g ( 1 − g ) = ( 1 − h ) g + h 1 − g . (A.1) Appendix: Proof of Proposition 1 Given (3), (6), and (10), it is profitable to contact the second applicant if Given (3), (6), and (10), it is profitable to contact Proof ofproof part i): Inuse the the proof we use use the following observation frequently Given andthe (10), it isi): profitable to contact second applicant if Proof of (3), part(6), i)Proof In we following observation frequently of part In the proof we the following observation frequently t 2 (Y − r ) + (1 − t 2 )Max{p ( g s 2 , s 2 )Y − r , 0}≥ Max{p ( g s 2 )Y − r , 0} + c ( ) + (1 − t 2 )Max{p( g s 2 , s 2 )Y − r , 0}≥ t Y − r 2 (A.2) (11 −−{ggp)(22g.. s 2 )Y − r , 0}+ c −−g gr))+ ++((1 1(1− −− h ht 2)) g g)Max −g g{((1 1p (− −gg gs))2 ,= =s((21 1)Y− −h h−))rg g, 220}+ +≥h hMax (A.1) (A.1) thh2(11(Y− − (A.1) The inequality is satisfied if p ( g s 2 ) Y ≤ r for sufficiently low c. Hence The inequality is satisfied if p ( g s 2 ) Y ≤ r for Given (3), (6), and (10), is profitable to applicant if Given to≤contact contact thesecond second applicant Given(3), (3),(6), (6),and and (10), itit it is isifprofitable profitable to contact the second applicant if if we focus on the case p( g s 2 ) Y r for the sufficiently low c. Hence, The inequality is (10), satisfied where p ( g s 2 ) Y > r . There are two possibilities, depending on wheth are two possibilit − r ) + (1 − t )Max{p (g ss 22 ))Y − pp (( gg ss 22 ))Y − ,, 00} + (A.2) (A.2) tt 22 (Y g ss 22 ,,two Ypossibilities, − rr ,, 0 0}≥ ≥ Max Max{depending Ywhere − rron +pcc( g s 2 ) Yp (>grs. ,There (A.2) where pY( g−sr2 )+Y1>−rt 22. Max Therep (are whether 2 s 2 ) Y − r is t 2 = p (h s 2 )g + positive or negative. Hence, Usingwe (9), we The inequality is is satisfied if p(g | s2) Y ≤ r for sufficiently low c.positive on therewrite case where orfocus negative. Using (9), we p (( g ss 22 )) Y ≤ rr for sufficiently low c. Hence, we focus on the case The inequality satisfied if p g Y ≤ for sufficiently low c. Hence, we focus on the case The inequality is satisfied if )g2) Y – r t 2 =p(g p (h | ss22, s + [1 − is p (hpositive s 2 )](1 − or g ) negaas positive Using (9),depending we rewrite p(g | s2) Y > r. or Therenegative. are two possibilities, on whether g (1 − g ) − g) t 2 =possibilities, depending . As a g (1result, if ) Yp (−grs 2 is ,s ) Y < r , where p g rr .. There are on where p ((g(9), g(1ss 22−))we Y) > >rewrite There are two possibilities, on whether whether pp (( gg ss 22 ,,.ssAs Ya −result, r ais 2 result, i tive. Using t2 = p (h | two s2)g + [1–p 22 ) As gY h(1 −(hg |) s+2)](1–g) (1depending − h) gas t 2 = h(r1 ,− g )(A.2) + (1 − h)simplifies g t2 = . As a result, if p( g s 2 , s 2 ) Y < to h(1 − g ) + (1 − h) g p (h s )g + [1 − p (h s )](1 − gg ) as positive 1 − g ) rewrite positive or or negative. negative. Using Using (9), (9), g (we we rewrite tt 22 = (1 −ash )(A.1), g if p(g | s2, s2) Y < r, (A.2) simplifies to using (Y − r ) ≥= p hg(1s(122−−ghg)+g) 1 − p(YYh−−s 22rr )+≥1c−or, using to Y −r h(1 − g ) + (1 − h )g (1 − h )hg(1 − g Y) +−(1r−+hc)gor, using (A.1), g (1 − g ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) h 1 − g + 1 − h g h 1 − g + 1 − h g ( ) Y − r ≥ to g ( 1 − g ) g (1 − g ) (1 − g )aa+ (1 −result, h )g (A.1), tth22(1= .. hAs if =−tog ) + (1 − h )g As result, if 2 pp (( gg ss 22 ,, ss 22 2)) Y Y< < rr ,, (A.2) (A.2) simplifies simplifies to to h h((1 1− −g g )) + + ((1 1− −h h)) g g r (1 −32 h) g + h(1 − g ) + gY (h − g ) ≥2 [h(1 − g ) + 2(1 − h )g ]c . r (1 − h) g + h(1 − g ) + gY (h − g ) ≥ [h(1 − g (A.3) r (1 − h) g 2 + h(1 − g )2 + gY (h − g ) ≥ [h(1 − g ) + (1 − h )g ]c . (A.3) (11 −− hh )gg g g (1 1− −g g) ( ) Y − r ≥ − + or, using (A.1), to Y r c Y − rY(1– h)g Y −ofr(A.3) + c or, using (A.1), to 2 2 in the LHS Adding subtracting Y≥(1h (A.3) yields Adding yields (11 −− LHS )and h + − h h(1 1− −g gand + (1 1subtracting −h h )g g h−(1 1h− −)gg g )in+ + the h )g g of [ ] [[ ]] [ ] [ 22 22 2 (A.4) rrr (((111 − (1(−hh h−−)ggg )2 ≥≥+[hhYgh (11 −−(1gg−) ++g )(11≥−−[hhh(1)gg−]ccg ..) + (1 − h )g ]c . − + h((11 − + gY − hh h))) gg g2 + + hh 1− − gg g )) − + YgY [ ] (A.4) (A.3) (A.3) ] 2 2 2 2 Since p(gp |( sg2, s (1– h)g ofLHS (A.4)ofis(A.4) positive. Hence, (1 − the Since s 22,) Y < r s 2 ) Y implies < r implies (1 − Yh < (1– h)g ) g 2 Y < (1 − + h(1– g) h) g 2 + h r, g ) LHS r , the is positive. (A.4) holds if c is sufficiently low. Hence, (A.4) holds if c is sufficiently low. 106 Now assume p ( g s2 , s2 ) Y > r . Equation (A.2) simplifies to Y [t 2 − p ( g s 2 ) + (1 − t 2 ) p ( g s 2 , s 2 )] ≥ c . (A.5) [[ ]] 2 2 2 22 2 Since Sincep (pg( gs 2s,22s,2s)22 Y ) Y< <r rimplies implies(1(− 1 −h)hg) gY2 Y< <(1(− 1 −h)hg) g + +h(h1(− 1 −g )g ) r ,r the , theLHS LHSofof(A.4) (A.4)isispositive. positive. 2 2 (A.2) simplifies to Y [t 2 − pNow ( g s assume ) + (1 − tp2 ()gp (sg2 , ss22 ,)sY2 )>] ≥r .cEquation . (A.5) Hence, Hence,(A.4) (A.4)holds holdsif2 ifc cisissufficiently sufficientlylow. low. Finnish Economic Papers 2/2007 – Juha-Pekka Niinimäki and Tuomas Takalo Y [t 2 −Now p (1g−sassume ) g+2 (+1 h−p(1t(2g−)spg(),g2s s)2 Y, s 2>)]r .≥Equation c. (A.5) h2assume simplifies toto to Now p ( g2s22 ,2sby > r . (A.5) Equation (A.2) simplifies 2) Y Now assume p(g | s2, s (A.2) simplifies 2 Since (A.1), can(A.2) beto further simplified 1− t2 = 2) Y > r . Equation h(1 − g ) + (1 − h) g 2 −)h))+g+(21(+−1 h− ( 1 t 2(1t)22p−)(pgg()gs 2s,by ≥ ≥c .c(A.5) (A.5) (A.5) . (A.5) 2s,2s)(A.1), 2]) ] Since can be further simplified to 22 2 2 Y [Y1t 2−[t−22t 2(−p1=(−pg(ggs)2sgh c h) g h(1 − g ) + ≥(1 − , (A.6) h(1 − g ) + (1 − 2h)22g Y 2 22 h)hg) g + +h(h1(−1 −g )g ) (1(−1 − Since byby(A.1), (A.1), (A.5) can further simplified Since t 2t 22=(1=− g ) gh tototo Since1 −1 − (A.1),(A.5) (A.5)can canbebe befurther furthersimplified simplified (A.6) )g+) +(1≥(−1 −hc )h,g) glow. h(h1c (−1is−gsufficiently which his(1true if − g ) + (1 − h) g Y (1(−1 −gProof )ggh c c From (A.2) we see that a necessary condition for the optimality of a ) gh of part ≥ ≥ ,ii): (A.6) which is true if c is sufficiently , low. (A.6) (A.6) h(h1(−1 −g )g+) +(1(−1 −h)hg) g Y Y loan under Proof uncertainty the(A.2) firstweentrepreneur's type is p ( g s for − roptimality > 0. When 2 ) Ythe of part about ii): From see that a necessary condition of a which whichisistrue trueifififcccisisissufficiently sufficientlylow. low. which true sufficiently loan uncertainty about the first entrepreneur's type is p ( g s 2 ) Y − r > 0. When p ( g sunder 2 ) Y − r > 0 , (A.2) implies that the loan under uncertainty is optimal if ofofpart From condition forforthe Proof partii):ii): From (A.2) wesee seethat thatacondition anecessary necessary condition theoptimality optimality ofa a Proof of part Proof ii) From (A.2) we see(A.2) that awe necessary for the optimality of a loan of under uncertainty about the first entrepreneur’s type is p(g | s2) Y – r > 0 When p(g | s2) Y – r > 0, (A.2) imp ( gunder sunder the{entrepreneur's loan ) + (1the )Max }− c isisis optimal p2 () gYs−2uncertainty )rY −>r 0≥,t(A.2) −about rimplies −the tthat pentrepreneur's ( g sunder , s )Yuncertainty − r ,type 0type (A.7) 2 (Y 2is loan about first p (pg( gs 2s)if22 Y) Y− −r r > >0.0. When loan uncertainty first When plies that the loan under uncertainty optimal if2 2 Y{p−( gr − optimality of the(A.7) loan Because( gthes 2 RHS isr )smaller )Max (A.7) )Y − rof≥ (A.7) t 2 (Y −implies + (1 − t 2than s 2c, s, 2auncertainty )Ysufficient − r , 0}− ccondition for p (pg( gs 2s)p22 Y ) Y− −r r > >0 ,0(A.2) , (A.2) impliesthat thatthe theloan loanunder under uncertaintyisisoptimal optimalif if Because the RHS ofis(A.7) isissmaller a sufficient condition optimality of the loan r − c . As a result, for aforsufficient condition for under uncertainty that LHS ofthan (A.7)Y – r – c, exceed − r − c ,Ya−sufficient optimality of the loan Because the RHS of (A.7)the smaller than {pY{(pexceed p (pg( gs 2s)22Y)Y− −r is ≥r ≥tthat −the g( gs 2s,22s,2s)Y – r – c. − −r ,r0,}0−As (A.7) ) +(1(−1 −tof )Max }−c ccondition under uncertainty (A.7) a result, a sufficient condition for −r )r+LHS (A.7) 2 t(Y 2 t)22Max 22 (Y 22Y)Y part ii) of Proposition 1 to hold is part ii) of Proposition 1 to is under uncertainty is that the LHS of (A.7) exceed Y − r − c . As a result, a sufficient condition for Because r −c ,c a, asufficient sufficientcondition conditionforforoptimality optimalityofofthe theloan loan Becausethe theRHS RHSofof(A.7) (A.7)isissmaller smallerthan thanY Y− −r − (A.8) ( ) c ≥ 1 − p ( g s ) Y . (A.8) 2 part ii) of Proposition 1 to hold is under r −c .c As . Asa aresult, result,a asufficient sufficientcondition conditionforfor underuncertainty uncertaintyisisthat thatthe theLHS LHSofof(A.7) (A.7)exceed exceedY Y− −r − Condition (A.8) holds if c or p(g | s2) is sufficiently large. The latter occurs when g is close to one ( ) c ≥ 1 − p ( g s ) Y . (A.8) Condition (A.8) holds if c or p ( g s 2 ) is sufficiently large. The latter occurs when g is close to one 2 or h is close to zero (see (9)). part ii)ii) ofofProposition 1 1toto hold part Proposition holdisis or h of is close to zero (see (9)). Condition s 2 ) investor is sufficiently large. The lattertooccurs when g is close(A.8) to one Proof iii) sif.2) Y – r < 0 does not grant a loan the first entrepreneur. Thus, c c≥part s 2p(g ≥(1(−1(A.8) −p (pgIf ( gholds s)22)Y ) )| Y .c or p ( gthe (A.8) if c is so high that (A.2) is violated, the investor does not grant a loan. part iii): If p ( g s 2 ) Y − r < 0, the investor does not grant a loan to the first or h is close toProof zero of (see (9)). Condition Condition(A.8) (A.8)holds holdsif ifc or c orp (pg( gs 2s)22 )isissufficiently sufficientlylarge. large.The Thelatter latteroccurs occurswhen wheng gisisclose closetotoone one entrepreneur. Proof Thus, of if cpart is soiii): high the investor investor does does not not grant a loan loan.to the first If that p ( g(A.2) s 2 ) Yis−violated, r < 0, the ororh hisisclose closetotozero zero(see (see(9)). (9)). entrepreneur. Thus, if c is so high that (A.2) is violated, the investor does not grant a loan. Proof Proofofofpart partiii): iii):IfIf p (pg( gs 2s)22 Y) Y− −r r < <0,0,the theinvestor investordoes doesnot notgrant granta aloan loantotothe thefirst first entrepreneur. entrepreneur.Thus, Thus,if ifc cisissosohigh highthat that(A.2) (A.2)isisviolated, violated,the theinvestor investordoes doesnot notgrant granta aloan. loan. 107