* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Diversification, Pricing, Policy and Credit Union Risk
Syndicated loan wikipedia , lookup
Moral hazard wikipedia , lookup
Merchant account wikipedia , lookup
Shadow banking system wikipedia , lookup
Financialization wikipedia , lookup
Interest rate ceiling wikipedia , lookup
Public finance wikipedia , lookup
Credit bureau wikipedia , lookup
Financial economics wikipedia , lookup
Credit rationing wikipedia , lookup
Systemic risk wikipedia , lookup
Securitization wikipedia , lookup
DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK Neil Esho * Paul Kofman ** Ian G. Sharpe *** and Ren Huang *** Working Paper 2004-01 Australian Prudential Regulation Authority January 2004 * Australian Prudential Regulation Authority (APRA) ** University of Melbourne *** University of New South Wales. The views and opinions in this paper are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of APRA. The authors wish to thank Wayne Byres, Warren Hogan and Li- Anne Woo for helpful comments on earlier drafts of the paper, Michael Kollo for research assistance, and the Australian Research Council and the Australian Prudential Regulation Authority for financial support. DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK ABSTRACT Using a sample of Australian credit unions, we examine the relationship between diversification, pricing policy, risk, and earnings. Credit unions with more concentrated revenues have higher earnings and volatility of asset returns. Those that use pricing policy to reduce dependence on interest on personal loans by increasing transaction fees have higher risk and smaller earnings while those with a higher proportion of revenues derived as commissions and off-balance sheet facility fees have higher risk. Credit unions deriving a higher proportion of revenue from interest on residential loans and a lower proportion from interest on personal loans have lower risk and return. APRA i JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK 1. INTRODUCTION With the deregulation of the financial system, globalisation of financial markets, a trend towards disintermediation and funds management, and technological advances, Australian depository institutions faced a highly competitive environment in the 1990s. This placed pressure on interest margins and profitability of traditional lines of business and generated pressures for institutions to cut costs, outsource back office functions, diversify into new activities, eliminate cross-subsidies, and increase non-interest income. Australian credit unions were particularly susceptible to these developments with high cost structures, a focus on retail banking activities, and relatively small scale. 1 To maintain their position in financial markets, many credit unions diversified by expanding products and services. Initially they expanded lending beyond personal installment loans and into residential lending. For the credit unions in this study, the proportion of total revenue derived as interest on personal loans and advances fell from 57.7% to 38.3% between 1993(02) and 2001(03), while the share of interest on residential loans rose from 22.7% to 31.6%. They also engaged in fee generating activities including securitisation, off-balance sheet activities, funds management, superannuation, insurance, and financial 1 Credit unions play an important role in the Australian financial system in providing competition for the four major nationwide banks in the provision of financial services to households. Currently, approximately 20% of Australia’s adult population are members of credit unions, while in June 2002 13% of household deposits were held by credit unions (Sources: CUSCAL and APRA). Although Australian credit unions differ from the banks in being mutually owned, they are subject to the same prudential regulation as banks and are required to pay corporate taxes. APRA 1 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK advisory services (see CUSCAL, 1998). 2 Moreover, they gradually eliminated many of the cross-subsidies in their transaction banking and lending activities by introducing transaction and service fees. This resulted in transaction fees on loans and deposits increasing from 2.0% of total credit union revenue in 1993(02) to 8.5% in 2001(03). An important issue for credit union management and for the prudential regulator, the Australian Prudential Regulation Authority (APRA), is the effect of the change in product mix and the increased reliance on fee (non-interest) income on credit union risk and earnings. Do these activities offer an efficient source of risk diversification or do they enhance profitability at the expense of higher risk? The conventional view is that product diversification reduces an institution’s exposure to any particular activity and thus leads to lower risk. In addition, fee income is often believed to be more stable than interest revenue, the latter being affected by movements in interest rates and the business cycle. Moreover, Boot and Thakor’s (1991) analysis of agency costs in off-balance sheet (OBS) activities demonstrates that OBS product expansion, particularly into loan commitments, can lower bank risk. An alternative view is that the expansion of financial institution activities beyond traditional deposit taking and lending leads to greater risk taking. Litan (1985) notes the moral hazard problem associated with deposit insurance that is not risk based. The deposit insurance system distorts payoffs in such a way that risk-taking behaviour is encouraged. 3 This may take the form of increasing risk in lending or alternatively of 2 Credit union revenues from commissions and off-balance sheet facility fees for the sample increased from 2.1% to 3.6% of total revenues between 1993(02) and 2001(03). 3 It is important to note that there is no explicit system of deposit insurance operating in Australia. APRA 2 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK entering new, high risk, activities. In addition, Jensen (1986) and Stulz (1990) note that diversification of activities may be associated with high agency costs if the diversification arises from the accumulation of excess free cash and resources. This generates an overinvestment problem and may threaten the long-run viability of the institution. De Young and Roland (2001, pp. 56-57) question the view that fee income is more stable than income from traditional banking activities. First, they note that high switching and information costs make it costly for borrowers to change banks and this may lead to a relatively stable income stream from traditional banking activities. In contrast, in some fee-based activities such as funds management, banks face a highly competitive market, relatively low information costs, and less stable demand for the product. Second, they argue that fee-based financial services entail a higher ratio of fixed to variable costs (operating leverage) than traditional banking products. Thus a given change in revenue from fees will generate a greater change in earnings than would an equal change in interest revenues. Finally, they note that prudential regulators do not require capital to be held for fee-based activities. This allows banks to have greater financial leverage, and thus higher earnings volatility, on fee-based activities. There is an extensive empirical literature dealing with the effects of product expansion in U.S. banking, though the results are somewhat mixed. Eisenbeis, Harris and Lakonishok (1984) examine the announcement effects of the formation of bank holding companies on shareholder returns and conclude that diversification enhances bank value . However, Apilado, Gallo and Lockwood (1993) find only weak support for the hypothesis that bank expansion into securities underwriting activities is value enhancing. APRA 3 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK Brewer (1989) examines the effect of non-banking activities on bank holding company (BHC) risk and finds that they are associated with a reduced probability of bankruptcy. However, when Demsetz and Strahan (1997) decompose the variance of bank returns into systematic and unsystematic components they find that while large BHCs are better diversified in their activities than smaller BHCs, this does not translate into lower risk. Rather, diversification allows large BHCs to pursue riskier lending and to operate at higher leverage. When Hassan, Karels and Peterson (1994) use market based risk measures they find that off-balance sheet activities are risk-reducing. Boyd et al (1993) examine Z-Scores from simulations of hypothetical mergers between BHCs and other non-bank financial firms. While they find that a BHC - insurance company merger is risk reducing, BHC -securities company and BHC-real estate company mergers are risk increasing. Allen and Jagtiani (2000) extend the Boyd et al (1993) approach to consider market based risk measures and find that the addition of non-banking activities increases the merged institution’s exposure to market risk. Whereas much of this earlier literature involved combining earnings streams from somewhat unrelated activities with differing production and marketing functions, De Young and Roland (2001) study the effects of changes in product mix within established, integrated production processes. Using the degree of total leverage model they examine the relationship between bank earnings volatility and the share of revenue generated by fee-based activities and find that t he shift towards fee income generating activities within traditional banking has been associated with increased bank risk. Whereas De Young and Roland focus on the effect of the shift in product mix on risk, in this paper we extend APRA 4 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK their analysis by evaluating the effect of the introduction of fees and charges on traditional product lines on the financial institution’s risk. In contrast with the extensive U.S. empirical literature, there are few Australian studies examining the effect of product expansion on financial institution risk. Rather, the focus has been on macro or industry wide effects of banking deregulation in the 1980s and early 1990s on bank risk (see Hogan and Sharpe (1984), Harper and Scheit (1992), Gizycki and Goldsworthy (1999) and Dennis and Jeffrey (2002)). An exception, however, is Sharpe and Tuzun’s (1998) study of the relationship between banks’ use of a direct credit substitute, standby letters of credit, and the risk premium paid on their CDs. They find that while riskier banks make greater use of standby letters of credit than less risky banks, there is little evidence of a feed-back effect from standby letters of credit to bank CD risk premiums. This paper makes several important contributions to the literature. First, it recognizes that the shift to fee income within financial institutions arises not only from shifts in product mix towards new products with income derived from fees and charges but also from a change in pricing policy on traditional banking products. Second, we use a relatively new risk measure for financial institutions: the degree of total leverage. This measure of risk is becoming more relevant as the business mix and production functions of financial institutions move towards greater reliance on fee-based activities. Third, we focus on the risk of credit unions and the effect of changes in their product mix and pricing on that risk. The absence of prior studies of credit union risk and the observation that many credit unions lack scale and managerial skills to implement complex risk APRA 5 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK management systems make a study of credit union behaviour particularly interesting. Fourth, we use data for Australian credit unions because of the detailed disaggregation of fee-based revenues that is available in the APRA quarterly general returns. In addition to a comprehensive break-down of interest revenues by asset category and dividend and trading revenues, credit unions report three categories of fee income: transaction fees on loans and deposits, commissions received, and facility fees (off balance sheet). A shift in pricing strategy on traditional loan and deposit products towards fee income would be reflected in an increased share of revenues in the form of transactions fees on loans and deposits while diversification into the non-traditional activities for credit unions would be reflected in a greater share of commissions and facility fees in total revenue. As credit unions are limited in their ability to tap into the public debt markets for funding, market based measures of credit union risk are not available. Thus the focus in this study is on earnings based risk measures that have been used in prior studies: the coefficient of variation of earnings and return on assets, the standard deviation of the return on assets, the probability of bankruptcy model as in Boyd et al (1993), and De Young and Roland’s (2001) degree of total leverage model. However, we extend the existing literature by incorporating a fifth measure. Because regulators and management are concerned with the possibility of breaches of the regulatory risk based capital adequacy requirement, we examine whether changes in product mix and/or pricing policy affect the probability of credit unions exhausting their regulatory capital. The plan of the paper is as follow s. Section II defines the five risk measures that underlie the study. Then Section III presents the model linking diversification with credit APRA 6 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK union risk and describes the data. The results are then summarized in Section IV while Section V concludes. 2. RISK MEASURES 2.1. The coefficient of variation We define the coefficient of variation, CV, for two measures, earnings denoted p, and return on assets, ROA :4 CV _ π = STD _ π Mean _ π CV _ ROA = (1) STD _ ROA Mean _ ROA (2) where STD is the standard deviation of the measure, p is the operating profit/(loss) before income tax, extraordinary items, loan loss provisions and after charge -offs and recoveries, and ROA is earnings scaled by total assets. 5 Because several credit unions have very small or negative mean earnings, 6 we use the inverse of the coefficient of variation multiplied by minus one to obtain a measure that is directly related to risk. 2.2. Variability of return on assets 4 Results using the coefficient of variation of return on equity were almost identical to those based on ROA and hence are not reported in this study. 5 Return on assets is calculated using an average of the beginning and end of quarter total assets . Adjusting the definition of profit, π, so that it is also net of the change in specific provisions, rather before loan loss provisions, does not affect the results. 6 Only one credit union had a negative Mean_π over the sample period. APRA 7 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK An alternative to the coefficient of variation measures is to examine the standard deviation of the return on assets, ROA, denoted STD_ROA. 2.3. The Z-Score The Z-SCORE is an accounting based measure of the probability of bankruptcy, and is defined as the likelihood of incurring a loss greater than the credit union’s total capital. For our purposes total capital, denoted E, includes permanent share capital, share premium account, general reserves, retained profits (accumulated losses), and outside equity interests in controlled entities. Denoting minus the capital to total assets ratio by k = (− E TA) , then following Boyd et al (1993, pp. 48-49) the probability of bankruptcy is: p(π < − E ) = p(ROA < k ) = ∫ φ( ROA )dROA k −∞ (3) where φ(ROA ) is the probability density function of the return on assets. If ROA is normally distributed then: p (π < − E ) = ∫ N (0,1)dz z (4) −∞ where z is the number of true standard deviations, σ, below the true mean return on assets, ρ, that profit must fall to eliminate capital: 7 z= 7 k −ρ σ (5) Boyd et al (1993) note that even if ROA is not normally distributed, z provides an upper bound on the probability of bankruptcy. APRA 8 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK Using sample estimates for ρ and σ and the average of beginning and end of quarter data for capital and total assets then the Z-SCORE , which is an estimate of –z, is: Z − SCORE = Mean _ ROA + Mean _ k STD _ ROA (6) As the Z-SCORE statistic is inversely related to the probability of bankruptcy, in the empirical analysis that follows we use minus the Z-SCORE as a direct measure of risk. 2.4. The probability of exhausting regulatory capital From a regulatory perspective, a credit union that incurs losses greater than the beginning of period excess regulatory capital is one that requires regulatory intervention. Thus we define a measure of the probability that a credit union will breach the 8% risk adjusted capital adequacy requirement, and denote the measure REG_Z-SCORE. 8 The calculation of the REG_Z-SCORE is identical to equation (5) except that the total capital to total assets ratio is replaced by the excess regulatory capital to total assets ratio. Excess regulatory capital is defined as total risk adjusted capital less 8% of total risk adjusted assets. As for the Z-SCORE measure, in the empirical analysis we use minus the REG_ZSCORE as a direct measure of risk. 2.5. The degree of total leverage model 8 For simplicity we ignore the distinction between Tier 1 and Tier 2 regulatory capital. Most regulatory capital of credit unions is Tier 1 capital. APRA 9 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK The accounting treatment of the degree of total leverage, DTL, as described in De Young and Roland (2001), is: DTL = REV − VC REV − VC − FC (7) where REV is total revenue, VC is variable costs and FC is fixed costs. For a given total revenue, firms with relatively high fixed costs vis-à-vis variable costs will have a high DTL. When a firm is operating above break-even (where REV marginally exceeds the sum of VC and FC), DTL is positive and varies in the range of +1 for a highly profitable firm to +8 for a firm operating just above break-even. For firms operating below breakeven, DTL is negative and lies within the range of 0 for firms operating at the shut-down point (where REV=VC) to -8 for firms operating just below break-even. Thus DTL has a discontinuous range between 0 and 1. De Young and Roland (2001) note that the degree of total leverage concept, while elegantly presented in accounting texts, is difficult to apply. The distinction between fixed and variable costs is often based on arbitrary cost accounting rules while the multiproduct nature of financial institution operations presents difficulties in allocating fixed costs to product lines. Consequently, it is necessary to develop a proxy for the degree of total leverage. Noting that the variability of a firm’s earnings to a given change in revenue is directly related to its ratio of fixed to variable costs and thus its degree of total leverage, we then have for credit union i: %∆ π i = APRA % ∆π i × % ∆REV i = DTL i × %∆REV i %∆ REV i 10 (8) JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK where the degree of total leverage of credit union i is the revenue elasticity of its earnings and π is as defined earlier. Following Mandelker and Rhee (1984), O’Brien and Vanderheiden (1987), Dugan and Shriver (1992) and Lord (1998), De Young and Roland use a two-stage time series regression approach to obtain an estimate of each bank’s earnings sensitivity to changes in revenue. In the first stage of our study, each credit union’s quarterly total revenue and earnings are de-trended and de-seasonalised by regressing the profit and revenue series on a (cubic) time trend, T, and the first, second and third quarter dummy variables, Q1, Q2 and Q3: π it = πi 0 + ψ i1T + ψ i2T 2 + ψ i3T 3 + ψ i 4Q1 + ψ i5Q 2 + ψ i6Q 3 + µ(π)it REV it = REV i 0 + γ i 1T + γ i 2 T 2 + γ i 3 T 3 + γ i 4 Q1 + γ i 5 Q 2 + γ i 6 Q 3 + µ( REV )it (9) (10) The residuals from these first stage regressions, µ(π )it and µ(REV )it are then used in the second stage regressions for each credit union: µ(π )it = α i + β i µ(REV )it + ε it (11) The β i are then transformed to an elasticity measure of DTL: Mean _ REV DTL i = β i Mean _ π i (12) 3. THE MODEL AND DATA 3.1. Specification of the model We examine the cross-sectional relationship between the six measures of credit union risk described in the previous section and measures of product diversification and APRA 11 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK pricing, while controlling for merger activity and credit union size. Following De Young and Roland (2001), we proxy product mix by revenue shares of the six primary sources of credit union revenues: interest on personal loans and advances, INT_PERSONAL, interest on residential loans and advances, INT_RESIDENTIAL, revenue from securities and investments, REV_INVESTMENTS, loan and deposit transaction fees, FEES, commissions and off balance sheet facility fees, COMM_FEES, and other revenues, OTHER_REVENUE. Initially we combine the revenue shares across the six revenue sources into a single measure of concentration (lack of diversification) of the credit unio n’s revenues across the product categories. For this purpose we define the Herfindahl index of revenue shares: HERFINDAHL = ∑ (RS j × 100) 2 (13) j where RSj is the revenue share of product category j for j = 1 to 6. As a proxy for merger activity associated with a credit union we include the number of quarters within the sample period in which it was involved as an acquirer. 9 This variable is denoted MERGER_Q. Moreover, credit union scale is proxied by the credit union’s total revenue, REV. However, to account for possible non- linearity in the relationship between credit union scale and risk we also include total revenue squared, REV 2 . Thus our basic cross-sectional regression model is: ( RISK m = f CONSTANT , HERFINDAHL , MERGER _ Q , REV , REV 9 2 ) (14) The merger targets have been absorbed into the acquirer and hence do not feature in the database. APRA 12 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK for the m different risk measures defined in Section II. The aggregate measure of credit union revenue concentration, HERFINDAHL, is unable to distinguish the effects on risk emanating from alternative product mix and pricing strategies. Thus as an alternative to the formulation in (14) we substitute product revenue shares for the Herfindahl index. As the six revenue shares sum to unity, to avoid singularity we exclude INT_PERSONAL from the regressions. As credit unions have tended to diversify their activities away from personal loans and advances, this provides a convenient form in which a revenue share regression coefficient indicates the effect on risk of a shift in revenue shares from interest on personal loans and advances to the alternative product. 3.2. The data The data for the study is obtained from the quarterly general credit union return data reported to APRA, and its predecessor organizations under the Financial Institutions Scheme, expressed in real 1990 dollars using the consumer price index. The data includes the profit and loss statement, balance sheet assets and liabilities, off-balance sheet facilities, and risk-weighted capital adequacy. Each of the risk measures is calculated over the 34 quarters from 1993(02) to 2001(03) for credit unions with complete data over the sample period.10 As mergers can significantly distort measures of earnings volatility, we follow De Young and Roland (2001) in adjusting the financial statement data for mergers. First, in 10 The use of complete data is consistent with the U.S. literature on bank risk. APRA 13 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK any quarter the credit union’s profit and loss or balance sheet data is the sum of its own reported data plus the corresponding figure of the credit union(s) that it acquired during the quarter or in subsequent quarters during the sample. Second, credit unions that were involved in mergers in more than four quarters durin g the sample period were removed from the sample. This reduced the sample by one, leaving a final sample of 198 credit unions. Third, data for the merger quarter is excluded from the time series estimates of the risk measures. Fourth, in addition to the data modifications, in the cross sectional regressions examining the effect of diversification and pricing policy on credit union risk we include a control for the number of quarters in which the credit union was an acquirer in a merger or takeover of another credit union. Fifth, we perform a sensitivity analysis of the results to merger activity by undertaking the cross-sectional regression analysis on a smaller sample of 155 credit unions that were not involved in any mergers during the sample period. Summary statistics for the full sample of 198 credit unions are displayed in Table 1. The credit unions are relatively small financial institutions with mean and median total assets of $103m and $37m respectively in 1990 dollars. They have a mean quarterly return on equity (ROE) of 2.84%, while the mean return on assets (ROA) of 0.27% and return on total revenue ( ROR) of 10.71% are considerably smaller than the quarterly ROA and ROR of 0.43% and 16.12% for U.S. banks in the De Young and Roland study. The credit unions are well capitalized with a mean risk-adjusted capital ratio of 15.6%, well in excess of the regulatory minimum of 8%. The typical credit union was not heavily involved in merger activity during the sample with the mean number of quarters of APRA 14 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK merger activity of 0.38 suggesting that the typical credit union experiences a merger quarter (as an acquirer) approximately once every 25 years. The revenue mix of the credit unions over the sample period is concentrated in interest income on personal and reside ntial loans with 46.1% and 28.1% of total credit union revenues respectively. Of the remaining product categories, revenues from securities and investments generated 13.5% of total revenues, while loan and deposit transaction fees generated 5.0%, commissio ns and OBS facility fees generated 2.8%, and all other revenue sources generated 4.5% of total revenues. The mean value of the Herfindahl index, 3737, reflects the high level of concentration of revenues in personal and residential lending, though it range s in value from 2132 to 8425. 11 Several features of the risk measures are noteworthy. First, the mean Z-SCORE of 73.6 (and median of 67.9) implies a default probability very close to zero. Thus the overall risk of Australian credit unions is very low. Second, the mean DTL of 1.61 is much higher than the mean DTL of 0.31 reported by De Young and Roland in their U.S. bank sample. However the median credit union DTL of 1.38 is identical to the median DTL of U.S. banks. Table 2 examines the relationship between the six risk measures. The top panel reports the correlation between the risk measures and, as expected, the correlations are generally significantly positive. The exceptions are the correlations involving the degree 11 The maximum value of the Herfindahl index for a credit union with 100% of its revenues in a single activity would be 10,000. APRA 15 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK of total leverage, DTL, and the remaining risk measures. While positive, they are much weaker than the paired correlations between the other four measures. 12 As an alternative to the correlations, the bottom panel of Table 2 reports the nonparametric Wilcoxon signed-rank test of the hypothesis that the pairs of risk rankings have the same distribution. The test statistic is based on the ranks of the absolute values of the differences between the credit union rankings produced by the risk measures. The test statistic for all paired risk combinations are not statistically significant indicating that we cannot reject the hypothesis that the measures have the same distribution. 4. REGRESSION RESULTS 4.1. Credit union risk The ordinary least squares regression results for the six risk measures for the full sample of 198 credit unions and using the aggregate measure of product concentration, HERFINDAHL , are reported as Regs 1 to 6 in Table 3.13 As noted previously, the dependent variable in the coefficient of variation Regs 1 and 2 is minus the inverse of the coefficient of variation. The explanatory power of the regressions varies considerably across the risk measures, with an adjusted R2 of between 0.200 and .241 for the coefficient of variation and standard deviation of the return on assets models in Regs 1 to 3, but almost zero for the Z-SCORE , REG_Z-SCORE, and DTL models in Regs 4 to 6. 12 13 This may be attributable to the discontinuity in the theoretical measure of degree of total leverage that is ignored in the DTL proxy (see De Young and Roland, 2001, p. 71). As in De Young and Roland (2001) the regression models were also estimated on a smaller sample of N=155 credit unions that did not engage in merger activity. As the smaller sample results mirror those of the full sample, for space reasons they are not reported. They are available from the authors on request. APRA 16 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK The results in Table 3 provide some support for the hypothesis that credit unions with a highly concentrated product (revenue) mix have higher risk than more diversified credit unions. For two of the six risk measures (the standard deviation of the return on assets and degree of total leverage) the regression coefficient of the Herfindahl concentration index is positive and statistically significant. This is cons istent with the traditional view that more diversified credit unions have lower risk exposure. Moreover, the coefficients of the linear and quadratic total revenue variables are generally significantly negative and positive respectively. This is consistent with risk initially falling with increasing scale but then increasing at large scale. Taking the derivative of the estimated equation with respect to REV and setting the derivative equal to zero, Regs 1 and 2 suggest that, ceteris paribus, credit union risk in this sample is minimized at a level of revenue of $14m and $16m in 1990 dollars respectively. With 193 of the 198 credit unions in our sample operating at a scale below this risk minimizing level there is considerable scope for risk reducing scale economies in Australian credit unions. Finally, there is evidence in the coefficient of variation regressions that the credit unions involved in merger activity had higher levels of risk than non-acquiring credit unions. In Table 4, the Herfindahl index is replaced by the product revenue share variables, the revenue share on personal loans and advances being excluded to avoid singularity. The explanatory power of the regressions with revenue shares is higher than those using the Herfindahl index, with the adjusted R2 varying from .265 for the coefficient of variation of the ROA model to .058 for the degree of total leverage model. APRA 17 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK In the introduction it was noted that Australian credit unions have diversified their revenue streams by increasing transaction fe es on loans and deposits, by engaging in new activities earning commissions and off-balance sheet facility fees, and by shifting their lending away from personal loans and into residential lending. With respect to the change in pricing policy, the results indicate that a reduction in the revenue share of interest on personal lending offset by an equal increase in the revenue share of loan and deposit transaction fees (FEES) is associated with higher credit union risk. For five of the six risk measures the coefficient on the FEES variable is positive and statistically significant. The exception is the standard deviation of the return on assets regression where the coefficient has a positive coefficient but is insignificant. As the FEES variable captures the shift in pricing policy away from interest income on personal loans towards a fee for service on deposit accounts and loan facilities, the results are consistent with this change in pricing policy being associated with increased credit union risk. Thus credit unions with a greater share of their total revenues in loan and deposit transaction fees are associated with higher levels of risk. Not only is the change in pricing policy effect on the risk measure statistically significant but it is also economically significant. An increase in loan and deposit transaction fees of 1% of total revenue matched by a fall in interest revenue on personal loans will increase the coefficient of variation of earnings by 1.7%, the coefficient of variation of return on assets by 1.8%, the Z-SCORE by 3.6%, and the regulatory Z-Score by 6.3%.14 14 The respective coefficient on FEES is multiplied by 0.01 and divided by the mean value of the dependent variable from Table 1. APRA 18 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK In contrast with the results for the change in pricing policy, the results in relation to diversification into new business lines earning commission and off-balance sheet facility fees suggest that these have had little influence on credit union risk. The coefficient on the COMM_FEES variable is statistically significant and negative in the standard deviation of the return on assets regression, Reg 3, but is insignificant for the five remaining regressions. A possible explanation for the results could lie in the commissions and off-balance sheet facility fees comprising such a small proportion of total revenues for the average credit union (2.8%) that the effect on aggregate levels of risk is difficult to detect. There is strong evidence supporting the hypothesis that diversification away from interest revenue on personal loans and advances towards residential lending reduces credit union risk. The estimated coefficient on INT_RESIDENTIAL is significantly negative in four of the six risk measures, including the coefficient of variation of earnings, the standard deviation of return on assets, and the two Z-SCORE measures. In terms of economic significance, the risk effect of an increase in interest on residential loans of 1% of total revenue and an equal fall in interest on personal loans is considerably less than that associated with the change in pricing policy above. Thus the coefficient of variation of earnings falls by 0.6%, the standard deviation of the return on assets by 0.6%, Z-SCORE by 0.6% and the regulatory Z-Score by 0.8%. With respect to the controls for scale and merger activity, the results in Table 4 mirror those in Table 3. Risk initially falls with increasing scale to a gross revenue level APRA 19 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK of $13m to $15m but increases at greater scale. Moreover, credit unions that have engaged in merger activity generally have higher risk. 4.2. Credit union returns In Table 5 we examine the effect of changes in credit union pricing policy and product mix on credit union earnings defined in Regs 1 and 3 as return on assets, ROA, and in Regs 2 and 4 as the return on total revenue, ROR. Regs 1 and 2 use the Herfindahl index as the aggregate measure of revenue concentration while Regs 3 and 4 subs titute the revenue shares for the Herfindahl index. As the results in Table 3 suggest that greater revenue concentration, reflected in higher levels of the Herfindahl index, is associated with higher risk, we would expect an increase in the concentration of revenue shares to be associated with higher earnings. This is borne out in Regs 1 and 2 of Table 5 where the coefficient of HERFINDAHL is positive and statistically significant. Credit unions with more concentrated revenue streams have higher returns on assets and on gross revenues. With the disaggregated product revenue share regressions, Regs 3 and 4, a somewhat different picture emerges. All revenue share coefficients are negative, indicating that over our sample period, a reduction in the total revenue share of interest revenue on personal loans was associated with a reduction in earnings. However only four of the revenue share regression coefficients are statistically significant. Consistent with the prediction from the asset pricing literature, an increased revenue share of residential lending is associated with both a reduction in risk (from Table 4) and a reduced return on assets. Moreover, the results in Table 5 are consistent with a shift from personal lending towards APRA 20 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK holding cash reserves and fixed income investments lowering credit union returns, though there is no evidence from Table 4 that credit unions with greater revenue share in cash, deposits, and liquid investments have lower risk. Furthermore, a pricing decision that increases the share of loan and deposit transaction fees in total revenue is associated with higher risk and lower earnings. While this result is inconsistent with the traditional risk-return relationship, a possible explanation may lie in the introduction of transaction fe es being a response of credit unions experiencing severe pressures on their interest margins. When Australian banks initially introduced transaction fees across a wide range of their business to offset declining interest margins, their customers reacted ne gatively to the shift in pricing policy. Credit unions then attempted to gain a competitive advantage by continuing to offer their services without transaction fees. This placed pressure on credit union interest margins which, by 1997, no longer covered their expenses (see CUSCAL, 1998, p.21). Ultimately transaction fees were introduced by credit unions with those experiencing the severest pressure on interest margins being the leaders in introducing the fees. Hence we observe the inverse relationship between risk and return. 4.3. Sub-period results In order to examine the stability of the results over time, the sample period of 34 quarters was split into two 17 quarter sub -periods and the risk measures and revenue shares computed for each of the sub-perio ds. As the degree of total leverage measure produced implausible and highly volatile estimates of risk for the 1997(03)-2001(03) sub - APRA 21 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK period, it is excluded from the stability results. Table 6 reports the sub-period means and standard deviations of the risk measures and revenue shares together with a t test of the significance of the difference in sub-period means. Three of the five measures, STD_ROA , Z-SCORE and REG_Z-SCORE, are significantly lower in the latter period consistent with credit union risk declining over time. Moreover, the revenue shares reveal a significant decline in the share of personal loans in total revenues and an increase in the proportion of revenues from fees (though from a relatively low base). The diversification effect of these cha nges is evident in the significant fall in the mean Herfindahl index across the sub -samples. Finally, we note the very significant fall in the return on total assets reflecting the deteriorating competitive position of credit unions in recent years, though this is less pronounced in the return on total revenues measure. 15 Tables 7 and 8 report the revenue share decomposition regressions for the 1993(2)1997(2) and 1997(3)-2001(2) sub -samples while the corresponding earnings regression results are reported in Table 9.16 These results are generally consistent with the full sample results reported earlier. The shift to residential lending is associated with lower risk and returns in both sub-periods while the shift towards loan and deposit transaction fees is as sociated with higher risk but lower returns. An interesting aspect of the sub sample results that is not evident in the full period results relates to the effect of the shift towards new lines of business generating commissions and off-balance sheet facility fees. For the earlier sub -period results in Table 7, four of the five COM_FEES regression 15 16 Consistent with the asset pricing literature, the latter period is characterized by lower credit union risk and returns. Sub-sample regressions were also run for the model using the Herfindahl index but were very similar to the full sample results and hence are not reported. APRA 22 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK coefficients are positive and statistically significant reinforcing the pricing decision results that the shift towards fee income is risk increasing. In the later sub-period this variable is only significant and positive in the regulatory Z-Score regression suggesting that the risk effect was largely associated with the early part of our sample period. Moreover, there is little evidence in Table 9 that the shift towards new fee income activities affected credit union returns. With respect to the controls, the sub-period results are also consistent with the existence of scale economies at revenues less than $15m and diseconomies at higher levels. Thus the great majority of credit unions may increase returns and reduce risk by increasing scale. However, unlike the full sample results, there is little evidence that credit unions engaging in merger activity have higher levels of risk. 5. CONCLUSION Australian credit unions have diversified their activities in the 1990s to reduce their reliance on interest revenue from personal loans and advances. This took three primary forms: (i) a change in pricing policy that introduced transaction fees on loans and deposits; (ii) the introduction of new financial services including insurance, funds management and off-balance sheet activities that generated commissions and facility fees; and (iii) a shift in the portfolio mix of assets away from personal loans and advances into resid ential lending. The study uses a cross-sectional ordinary least squares regression analysis of 198 Australian credit unions and six risk measures to examine the relationship between a APRA 23 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK credit union’s product mix, pricing policy, risk, and earnings. The results confirm the findings of the only other previous study to use the DTL risk measure. DeYoung and Roland’s (2001) finding that increased reliance on fee income generating activities is associated within increased risk, not only applies to U.S. commercial banks, but also to Australian credit unions . While there are differences evident in the results across the risk measures, we find that credit unions with highly concentrated revenues have higher levels of risk and returns. On a disaggregated level, credit unions that diversify by reducing the revenue share of interest on personal loans and increasing the revenue share of transaction fees on loans and deposits have higher risk and lower returns. There is also evidence in the early part of the sample that credit unions which diversify into new activities generating commissions and facility fees have higher levels of risk. Moreover, credit unions with a higher proportion of total revenue in the form of interest on residential loans and a lower proportion of revenues in interest on personal loans have significantly lower risk and returns, consistent with modern portfolio theory. Finally, the results suggest the possibility of scale economies in risk and return for many of the small credit unions. An important caveat in interpreting these results is that a significant relationship need not imply causality. Thus the finding that credit unions with a higher proportion of fee income are associated with higher risk is consistent with either the credit unions taking on a higher risk activity or alternatively higher risk credit unions electing to get into this new business line. Bearing this caveat in mind, the results have several implications for the Australian credit union industry and for its prudential regulator, APRA 24 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK APRA. In its 1998 review of credit union performance and future structure of the industry, the movement’s central body, CUSCAL, identified the need to reduce credit union costs by increasing scale as a key element of the industry’s long-run viability (see CUSCAL, 1998, pp 60-66). While our results are consistent with this strategy, they also suggest that the benefits of increasing scale could go beyond that of improving credit union profitability. Enhancing the scale of smaller credit unions may also reduce their risk. However, CUSCAL also argued that high priority needed to be given to increasing non- interest income in order to improve returns through economies of scope and reduce risk through diversification. Our results suggest the need for caution in imple menting this strategy in that over our sample period the credit unions that generated a higher proportion of gross revenues from non- interest income had higher risk and lower returns than those that had relatively small proportions of non- interest income. APRA 25 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK TABLE 1 Summary Statistics for the Sample of 198 Australian Credit Unions, 1993(2) – 2001(3). Mean Std Dev Median Min Max Revenue in 1990$M (REV) Profit in 1990$M (π) $2.499 $4.230 $0.876 $0.005 $29.508 $0.295 $0.530 $0.083 -$0.001 $2.958 Total Assets in 1990$M (TA) Return on Assets (ROA) Return on Equity (ROE) Return on Revenue (ROR) $102.76 $173.41 $37.17 $0.21 $1,182.01 0.27% 0.12% 0.26% -0.00% 0.81% 2.84% 2.75% 1.37% -0.04% 7.44% 10.71% 4.74% 10.25% -0.10% 28.96% Risk Adjusted Capital Ratio Merger Quarters (MERGER_Q) 15.63% 6.14% 13.95% 5.21% 46.44% 0.384 0.881 0.000 0.000 4.000 0.461 0.170 0.451 0.053 0.915 0.281 0.152 0.300 0.000 0.733 0.135 0.053 0.122 0.058 0.358 0.050 0.044 0.046 0.000 0.246 0.028 0.021 0.026 0.000 0.103 0.045 0.042 0.032 0.000 0.235 3736.7 1165.5 3358.4 2132.3 8425.2 -1.81 0.98 -1.77 -5.33 0.02 -1.937 1.170 -1.825 -6.540 0.018 0.17% 0.10% 0.15% 0.04% 0.73% -73.62 35.01 -67.86 -256.62 -10.11 -37.40 26.41 -31.28 -203.94 0.68 1.61 10.06 1.38 -128.95 26.11 Revenue Shares INT_PERSONAL INT_RESIDENTIAL REV_INVESTMENTS FEES COM_FEES OTHER_REVENUE Herfindahl Index HERFINDAHL Risk Measures -(CV_π)-1 -(CV_ROA)-1 STD_ROA -(Z-SCORE) -(REG_Z-SCORE) DTL APRA 26 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK TABLE 2 Correlation Matrix and Wilcoxon Rank Correlation Test for Risk Measures of Australian Credit Unions over the 1993(2) – 2001(3) period. Correlation Matrix -1 -(CV_π) -(CV_ π) -(CV_ROA)-1 STD_ROA -(Z-SCORE) -(REG_Z-SCORE) DTL -1 1 0.77*** 0.51*** 0.50*** 0.35*** 0.02 -(CV_π)-1 -(CV_ π)-1 -(CV_ROA)-1 STD_ROA -(Z-SCORE) -(REG_Z-SCORE) DTL -0.528 -0.305 -0.430 -0.290 -1.446 -1 -(CV_ROA) 1 0.56*** 0.61*** 0.36*** 0.02 STD_ROA -(Z-SCORE) -(REG_Z-SCORE) DTL 1 0.57*** 0.27*** 0.14** 1 0.90*** 0.14** 1 0.12* 1 Wilcoxon Rank Correlation Statistics -(CV_ROA)-1 STD_ROA -(Z-SCORE) -0.109 -0.855 -0.330 -1.465 -0.622 -0.087 -0.528 -0.038 -0.649 -(REG_Z-SCORE) -0.300 '***','**', and '*' denote significance at the 99%, 95% and 90% confidence levels respectively. APRA 27 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK TABLE 3 Revenue Concentration and Credit Union Risk: Ordinary Least Squares Regression Results (Full Sample N=198) Dependent Variable -(CV_ π)-1 -(CV_ROA)-1 STD_ROA*100 -(Z-SCORE) -(REG_Z-SCORE) DTL Reg 1 Reg 2 Reg 3 Reg 4 Reg 5 Reg 6 Independent Variables CONSTANT Coeff. -1.801 HERFINDAHL x 10-3 0.084 REV REV 2 MERGER_Q -0.244 0.009 0.171 t-stat1 -7.32*** 1.47 -6.35*** 5.22*** 2.18** Coeff. -1.618 0.036 -0.317 0.010 0.230 t-stat1 -5.67*** 0.54 -7.11*** 5.20*** 2.53** Coeff. 0.055 t-stat1 2.26** Coeff. -68.797 0.036 6.35*** 0.031 -2.837 0.120 -1.929 -0.009 0.000 0.003 -2.39** 1.75* 0.43 t-stat1 -7.04*** Coeff. -28.177 t-stat1 -3.81*** Coeff. -3.342 t-stat1 -1.18 0.01 -2.413 -1.41 1.250 1.92* -1.86* 1.74* -0.62 0.287 0.008 -2.908 0.25 0.16 -1.23 0.119 -0.006 0.356 0.27 -0.32 0.40 SUMMARY STATISTICS Adjusted R2 F-Test 1 0.200 13.3229*** 0.241 16.659*** 0.233 15.9231*** 0.006 1.316 0.001 0.970 0.001 0.962 '***','**', and '*' denote significance at the 99%, 95% and 90% confidence levels respectively. APRA 28 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK TABLE 4 Revenue Composition and Credit Union Risk: Ordinary Least Squares Regression Results (N=198) Dependent Variable -(CV_ π)-1 -(CV_ROA)-1 STD_ROA*100 -(Z-SCORE) -(REG_Z-SCORE) DTL Reg 1 Reg 2 Reg 3 Reg 4 Reg 5 Reg 6 Independent Variable CONSTANT Coeff. -1.556 t-stat1 -5.44*** Coeff. -1.715 t-stat1 -5.12*** INT_RESIDENTIAL REV_INVESTMENTS FEES COM_FEES OTHER_REVENUE -1.198 1.559 3.034 1.854 -0.388 -2.69*** 1.20 1.95* 0.55 -0.24 -0.848 1.971 3.403 -3.127 1.593 -1.63 1.29 1.87* -0.79 0.85 -0.265 -0.056 0.072 -0.730 -0.073 REV REV 2 MERGER_Q -0.238 0.009 0.160 -5.76*** 5.06*** 2.08** -0.295 0.010 0.243 -6.10*** 4.76*** 2.69*** -0.008 0.000 0.002 Coeff. 0.288 t-stat1 9.92*** Coeff. t-stat1 -68.083 -6.35*** Coeff. -38.422 t-stat1 -4.87*** Coeff. -0.397 t-stat1 -0.12 -5.86*** -0.43 0.46 -2.13** -0.45 -44.629 -24.515 268.521 28.017 50.852 -2.67*** -0.50 4.59*** 0.22 0.84 -29.211 -43.422 234.245 124.927 42.281 -2.38** -1.21 5.45*** 1.34 0.95 1.561 21.576 46.271 -28.350 -69.626 0.31 1.45 2.61*** -0.74 -3.80*** -1.87* 1.64 0.21 -3.877 0.158 -0.894 -2.50** 2.38** -0.31 -1.013 0.052 -1.920 -0.89 1.06 -0.90 0.203 -0.011 0.094 0.43 -0.54 0.11 SUMMARY STATISTICS Adjusted R2 F-Test 1 0.238 8.6755*** 0.265 9.8914*** 0.230 8.3715*** 0.156 5.5481*** 0.198 7.0859*** 0.058 2.5212** '***','**', and '*' denote significance at the 99%, 95% and 90% confidence levels respectively. APRA 29 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK TABLE 5 Revenue Concentration, Composition and Credit Union Returns: Ordinary Least Squares Regression Results (N=198) Dependent Variable ROA 1 Reg 1 Independent Variables CONSTANT Coeff. 0.148 t-stat2 4.53*** 1 ROR ROA 1 ROR1 Reg 2 Reg 3 Reg 4 Coeff. 6.876 t-stat2 5.35*** INT_RESIDENTIAL REV_INVESTMENTS FEES COM_FEES OTHER_REVENUE HERFINDAHL REV REV 2 MERGER_Q 0.025 3.29*** 0.767 2.59** 0.022 -0.001 -0.015 4.32*** -3.21*** -1.46 0.711 -0.024 -0.631 3.55*** -2.62*** -1.54 Coeff. 0.411 t-stat2 10.69*** Coeff. 14.059 t-stat2 9.34*** -0.144 -0.628 -0.346 -0.412 -0.184 -2.41** -3.58*** -1.65 -0.90 -0.85 -0.174 -14.596 -25.214 -22.988 -6.251 -0.07 -2.12** -3.07*** -1.29 -0.74 0.018 -0.001 -0.016 3.17*** -2.44** -1.56 0.656 -0.022 -0.702 3.02*** -2.33** -1.73* SUMMARY STATISTICS Adjusted R2 F-Test 1 2 APRA 0.100 6.4644*** 0.064 4.3617*** 0.122 4.4281*** 0.093 3.5302*** Return on assets and return on revenues are scaled by a factor of 100. '***','**', and '*' denote significance at the 99%, 95% and 90% confidence levels respectively. 30 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK TABLE 6 Sub-Sample Summary Statistics for the sample of 198 Australian Credit Unions. 1993(2) - 1997(2) Sub-Sample Mean -2.263 -2.274 0.171 -74.699 -36.847 3.928 Std Error 1.334 1.340 0.110 35.029 24.450 10.975 Mean -2.141 -2.258 0.145 -100.650 -51.827 22.816 Std Error 1.437 1.613 0.104 54.828 38.520 464.733 Test of Difference in Means t-Statistic 1 0.86 0.07 -2.79*** -5.61*** -4.62*** 0.57 ROA ROR 0.003 0.112 0.001 0.049 0.002 0.103 0.001 0.054 -5.58*** -1.68* HERFINDAHL 3628.4 1328.3 3056.2 1263.1 -4.38*** INT_PERSONAL INT_RESIDENTIAL REV_INVESTMENTS FEES COM_FEES OTHER_REVENUE 0.440 0.271 0.138 0.028 0.022 0.040 0.206 0.160 0.052 0.035 0.019 0.045 0.349 0.288 0.133 0.067 0.032 0.049 0.203 0.158 0.059 0.054 0.023 0.047 -4.37*** 1.25 -1.78* 8.79*** 4.71*** 2.15** Model Variables -(CV_ π)-1 -(CV_ROA)-1 STD_ROA -(Z-SCORE) -(REG_Z-SCORE) DTL 1 APRA 1997(3) - 2001(3) Sub-Sample '***','**', and '*' denote significance at the 99%, 95% and 90% confidence levels respectively. 31 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK TABLE 7 Revenue Composition and Credit Union Risk: Ordinary Least Squares Regression Results for Sub-Sample 1993(2) – 1997(2) (N=198) Dependent Variable -(CV_π)-1 -(CV_ROA)-1 STD_ROA * 100 -(Z-SCORE ) -(REG_Z-SCORE) Reg 1 Reg 2 Reg 3 Reg 4 Reg 5 Independent Variable CONSTANT Coeff. -1.885 t-stat1 -5.37*** Coeff. -2.057 t-stat1 -6.15*** INT_RESIDENTIAL REV_INVESTMENTS FEES COM_FEES OTHER_REVENUE -1.811 1.702 3.600 10.425 0.126 -3.19*** 0.98 1.44 2.09** 0.07 -0.853 1.947 3.273 8.641 1.817 -1.58 1.18 1.38 1.82* 0.99 REV REV 2 MERGER_Q -0.301 0.010 0.116 -4.88*** 3.11*** 0.60 -0.429 0.015 0.318 -7.29*** 5.13*** 1.73* t-stat1 8.62*** Coeff. -61.599 t-stat1 -6.53*** Coeff. -26.701 t-stat1 -4.04*** -0.224 -0.032 0.203 -0.068 -0.104 -4.63*** -0.22 0.95 -0.16 -0.63 -29.414 -67.810 326.757 273.453 2.175 -1.93* -1.46 4.88*** 2.04** 0.04 -23.611 -84.722 250.763 202.950 13.051 -2.22** -2.61*** 5.34*** 2.17** 0.36 -0.014 0.000 -0.006 -2.59** 1.75* -0.34 -6.650 0.205 -2.429 -4.01*** 2.44** -0.47 -2.004 0.050 -4.449 -1.73* 0.84 -1.22 Coeff. 0.258 SUMMARY STATISTICS Adjusted R2 F-Test 1 23.34% 8.4992*** 30.92% 12.0239*** 17.72% 6.3031*** 19.85% 7.0983*** 19.33% 6.9008*** '***','**', and '*' denote significance at the 99%, 95% and 90% confidence levels respectively. APRA 32 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK TABLE 8 Revenue Composition and Credit Union Risk: Ordinary Least Squares Regression Results for Sub-Sample 1997(3) – 2001(3) (N=198) Dependent Variable -(CV_π)-1 -(CV_ROA)-1 STD_ROA * 100 -(Z-SCORE) -(REG_Z-SCORE) Reg 1 Reg 2 Reg 3 Reg 4 Reg 5 Independent Variable CONSTANT Coeff. -2.084 t-stat1 -4.83*** Coeff. -2.008 t-stat1 -4.18*** INT_RESIDENTIAL REV_INVESTMENTS FEES COM_FEES OTHER_REVENUE -1.156 3.531 2.665 -0.763 1.106 -1.79* 1.95* 1.40 -0.17 0.51 -1.530 3.539 1.969 -2.226 2.282 -2.13** 1.76* 0.93 -0.45 0.95 REV REV 2 MERGER_Q -0.248 0.008 0.214 -4.76*** 4.17*** 1.29 -0.273 0.008 0.280 -4.71*** 3.86*** 1.52 t-stat1 8.20*** Coeff. -91.982 t-stat1 -5.46*** Coeff. -55.590 t-stat1 -4.85*** -0.277 -0.018 0.009 -0.405 0.017 -6.04*** -0.14 0.07 -1.29 0.11 -100.510 3.995 206.176 266.057 114.484 -4.00*** 0.06 2.77*** 1.55 1.36 -61.109 -28.902 234.246 245.341 78.339 -3.57*** -0.60 4.63*** 2.09** 1.37 -0.008 0.000 0.002 -2.29** 2.22** 0.19 -5.590 0.223 1.426 -2.75*** 2.98*** 0.22 -1.698 0.085 -1.344 -1.23 1.68* -0.31 Coeff. 0.252 SUMMARY STATISTICS Adjusted R2 F-Test 1 18.49% 6.5843*** 19.88% 7.1088*** 21.50% 7.7436*** 14.81% 5.2795*** 20.04% 7.1702*** '***','**', and '*' denote significance at the 99%, 95% and 90% confidence levels respectively. APRA 33 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK TABLE 9 Sub-Sample Ordinary Least Squares Regression Results for Profitability Measures of 198 Australian Credit Unions. 1993(2) - 1997(2) Sub-Sample 1997(3) - 2001(3) Sub-Sample Dependent Variable ROA 1 Reg 1 Independent Variables CONSTANT INT_RESIDENTIAL REV_INVESTMENTS FEES COM_FEES OTHER_REVENUE Coeff. 0.425 -0.118 -0.557 -0.047 -0.546 -0.365 t-stat2 10.10*** -1.74* -2.69*** -0.16 -0.91 -1.58 Dependent Variable 1 ROR 1 ROA ROR1 Reg 2 Reg 3 Reg 4 t-stat Coeff. 12.969 2 9.01*** 0.197 -7.435 -15.042 -37.963 -12.470 0.08 -1.05 -1.47 -1.86* -1.58 Coeff. 0.392 2 t-stat t-stat 2 9.85*** Coeff. 14.855 8.77*** -0.145 -0.738 -0.381 -0.125 -0.098 -2.43** -4.43*** -2.17** -0.31 -0.49 -0.325 -22.618 -26.603 -10.380 -1.760 -0.13 -3.19*** -3.56*** -0.60 -0.21 0.010 2.19** 0.428 2.09** HERFINDAHL REV 2 REV MERGER_Q 0.019 2.52** 0.710 -0.001 -0.018 -2.03** -0.77 -0.029 -0.870 2.81*** -2.25** -1.10 0.000 -0.018 -1.54 -1.15 -0.012 -0.516 -1.58 -0.79 SUMMARY STATISTICS Adjusted R2 F-Test 1 2 APRA 0.065 2.7141*** 0.045 2.1587** 0.126 4.5521*** 0.103 3.815*** Note: Return on assets and return on sales are scaled by a factor of 100. '***','**', and '*' denote significance at the 99%, 95% and 90% confidence levels respectively. 34 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK REFERENCES Allen, L. and J. Jagtiani, 2000, The impact of new bank powers (securities and insurance activities) on bank holding companies’ risk, Journal of Economics and Business 52, 485-497. Apilado, V.P., Gallo, J.G. and L.J. Lockwood, 1993, Expanded securities underwriting; Implications for bank risk and return, Journal of Economics and Business 45, 143-158. Boot, A.W.A. and A. Thakor, 1991. Off-balance sheet liabilities, deposit insurance and capital regulation, Journal of Banking and Finance 15, 825-846. Boyd, J.H., Graham, S.L. and R.S. Hewitt, 1993, Bank holding company mergers with nonbank financial firms, Journal of Banking and Finance 17, 43-63. Brewer, E., 1989, Relationship between bank holding company risk and nonbank activity, Journal of Economics and Business 41, 337-353. CUSCAL, 1998. Review of movement performance and future structure: Issues paper. Credit Union Services Corporation (Australia) Limited, Sydney. Demsetz, R.S. and P.E. Strahan, 1997, Diversification, size, and risk at bank holding companies, Journal of Money Credit and Banking 29, 300-313. Dennis, S. and A. Jeffrey, 2002, Structural changes in Australian bank risk, Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money 12, 1-17. De Young, R. and K.P. Roland, 2001, Product mix and earnings volatility at commercial banks: Evidence from a degree of total leverage model, Journal of Financial Intermediation 10, 54-84. Dugan, M.T. and K.A. Shriver, 1992, The effects of estimation period, industry and proxy on the calculation of the degree of operating leverage, Financial Review 24, 309-321. Eisenbeis, R.A., Harris, R.S. and J. Lakonishok, 1984, Benefits of bank diversification: The evidence from shareholder returns, Journal of Finance 39, 881-890. Gizycki, M. and B. Goldsworthy, 1999, Australian banking risk: The stock market’s assessment and the relationship between capital and asset volatility, Research Discussion Paper RDP 1999-09, Reserve Bank of Australia. Harper, I. and T. Scheit, 1992, The effects of financial market deregulation on bank risk and profitability, Australian Economic Papers 31, 260-271. APRA 35 JANUARY 2004 DIVERSIFICATION, PRICING POLICY AND CREDIT UNION RISK Hassan, M.K., Karels G.V. and M.O. Peterson, 1994, Deposit insurance, market discipline and off--balance sheet banking risk of large U.S. commercial banks, Journal of Banking and Finance 18, 575-593. Hogan, W.P. and I.G. Sharpe, 1984, Regulation, risk and the pricing of Australian bank shares 1957-1976, Economic Record 60, 34-44. Jensen, M., 1986, Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance and takeovers, American Economic Review 76, 323-329. Litan, R.E., 1985, Evaluating and controlling the risks of financial product deregulation, Yale Journal on Regulation 3, 1-52. Lord, R.A., 1998, Properties of time series estimates of degree of leverage measures, Financial Review 33, 69-84. Mandelker, G. and S.G. Rhee, 1984, The impact of the degree of operating and financial leverage on systematic risk of common stock, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 19, 45-57. O’Brien, T. and P. Vanderheiden, 1987, Empirical measurement of operating leverage for growing firms, Financial Management 16, 45-53. Sharpe, I.G. and T. Tuzun, 1998. Standby letters of credit and bank default risk, Australian Economic Papers 37, 152-168. Stulz, R., 1990, Managerial discretion and optimal financing policies, Journal of Financial Economics 26, 3-27. APRA 36 JANUARY 2004