* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Interest Rate Channel in Indonesia during Inflation - UvA-DARE
Pensions crisis wikipedia , lookup
Financialization wikipedia , lookup
Present value wikipedia , lookup
History of the Federal Reserve System wikipedia , lookup
Interest rate swap wikipedia , lookup
Global saving glut wikipedia , lookup
Credit card interest wikipedia , lookup
International monetary systems wikipedia , lookup
Hyperinflation wikipedia , lookup
Quantitative easing wikipedia , lookup
Money supply wikipedia , lookup
Stagflation wikipedia , lookup
Universiteit Van Amsterdam Faculty of Economics and Business MSc Economics MASTER THESIS Interest Rate Channel in Indonesia during Inflation Targeting Era Author: Wulan Widyasari Mantik Student Number: 6260462 Supervisor: Dr. A. Ormeño Sanchez 1 Table of Contents Chapter 1............................................................................................................................................................... 4 INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................................................................. 4 1.1 Background.............................................................................................................................................. 4 1.2. Problem Statement.............................................................................................................................. 5 1.3 The Organization of Writing............................................................................................................. 6 Chapter 2............................................................................................................................................................... 7 THEORY AND LITERATURE REVIEW....................................................................................................... 7 2.1 Inflation Targeting................................................................................................................................ 7 2.1.1 Why Inflation Targeting? .......................................................................................................... 7 2.1.2 What is Inflation Targeting? ..................................................................................................10 2.1.3 How Does Inflation Targeting Work? ................................................................................11 2.1.4 Has InflationTargeting Mattered? .......................................................................................12 2.2 Interest Rate Channel........................................................................................................................18 2.2.1 The Importance of Interest Rate Channel........................................................................18 2.2.2 Determinant of Interest Rate Pass‐Through ..................................................................21 2.2.3 Evidence on Interest Rate Pass‐Through.........................................................................23 3.1 The Adoption of Inflation Targeting ...........................................................................................25 3.2 Interest rate channel .........................................................................................................................28 Bibliography ......................................................................................................................................................31 2 List of Tables Table 1: Inflation Targeting Countries in the World, 1990-2008 ........................................... 35 Table 2: Measures of Inflation Deviations from Targets and Inflation Deviations in IT Countries, from IT Starting Quarter through 2008IV ............................................................. 36 List of Figures Figure 1: Central Bank Transparency Index for Country Groups by Monetary Policy Regimes, 1998-2006 ............................................................................................................... 38 Figure 2: Central Bank Transparency Index for Industrial and EME IT Country Groups, 1998-2005 ............................................................................................................................... 38 3 Chapter 1 INTRODUCTION 1.1 Background Monetary policy consists of rules and actions that are used by central banks to achieve their objective. Many central banks around the world have put more attention on the importance of having a stable price level so they set price stability as their ultimate objective. High level of uncertainty on inflation rate is not desirable because it could hamper economic growth of a country through its effects on households’ and firms’ decisions to consume and invest. Price stability enables households and firms to easily identify the changes in the relative price of various goods and services so that they will not misinterpret changes in general price level as changes in the relative price. As a result, they have better information to make investment and consumption decisions (ECB , 2000). In order to achieve price stability, many central banks changed their policy instruments or redesigned their monetary operating procedures, involving the transmission mechanism of monetary policy. The monetary transmission mechanism is a process in which a change in monetary policy affects inflation and real economy. Monetary transmission mechanism consists of various channels, namely interest rate channel, exchange rate channel, credit channel, asset prices channel, and expectation channel. Most central banks usually choose interest rate as their policy instrument. Changes in the policy rate will first have effects on changes in short-term interest rates and then will be followed by changes in the deposit and loan rates. Eventually these changes will affect investment and consumption decisions by firms and households. With some lags, the level of investment and consumption will determine the level of output and price. The worldwide emergence of using short-term interest rates as the main instrument of monetary signals has made the interest rate channel the key transmission channel. Bank Indonesia (BI), the central bank of Indonesia, has also realized the importance of price stability. It is stipulated in the Act no 23/1999 that the sole and ultimate objective of BI is to achieve and maintain the stability of the rupiah. The Act also outlines a clear mechanism for accountability and transparency of monetary policy that could be achieved through, inter alia, announcing annual inflation target. The Act brought a substantial change to the conduct of 4 monetary policy after the country was hit by a severe crisis in 1997. The crisis resulted in the abandonment of the unsustainable, rigid rupiah. As the rupiah became freely floating, BI needed to choose a new nominal anchor. BI then decided to turn to a new approach by using the inflation rate as a nominal anchor. Following such a decision, and with the mandate of the new act, BI decided to announce its annual inflation target, starting at the beginning of 2000. This action became the initial step towards the adoption of inflation targeting (IT) framework. However, the official launching of IT as BI’s new monetary policy framework only took place in July 2005. As a preparation towards the adoption of a formal or a full-fledged IT framework, BI conducted comprehensive research on the key transmission channels, including the interest rate channel. Kusmiarso, Sukawati, Pambudi, Angkoro, Prasmuko, and Hafidz (2002) measure the significance of interest rate channel in influencing inflation for both the precrisis and post-crisis periods. For the pre-crisis period, interest rate channel performed quite well to influence interest rates for deposits and lending, but was not effective enough in affecting consumption and investment due to the abundant foreign capital inflows. Interest rate channel still showed a good performance during the post-crisis period, although its strength was influenced by the conditions of the banking system and the overall higher uncertainty. Earlier studies also reveal that interest rate channel is strong for the pre-crisis period and recommend the use of the interest rate as the operational target for monetary policy (Boediono, 1998, Sarwono & Warjiyo, 1998, Warjiyo & Zulverdi , 1998). However, it is unknown whether interest rate channel is still performing well after the adoption of IT framework in Indonesia. This leave room to conduct a literature study to assess this issue. 1.2. Problem Statement In the previous section, the motivation behind this research is described. To summarize, there is still a void of research about the performance of interest rate channel after the adoption of IT framework in Indonesia. This interest rate performance can be measured by the strength of interest rate pass-through, i.e. the pass-through of money market interest rates to retail interest rates. Retail interest rates consist of deposit rates and lending rates. This paper aims at answering the research question of “Does the pass-through to deposit and lending rates remain strong after the adoption of IT framework in Indonesia?” by conducting a literature study. 5 1.3 The Organization of Writing 1. Introduction 1.1 Background 1.2 Problem Statement 1.3 The Organization of Writing 2. Theory and Literature Review 2.1. Inflation Targeting 2.1.1 Why Inflation Targeting? 2.1.2 What is Inflation Targeting? 2.1.3 How Does Inflation Targeting Work? 2.1.4 Has Inflation Targeting Mattered? 2.2. Interest Rate Channel 2.2.1 The Importance of Interest Rate Channel 2.2.2 Determinant of Interest Rate Pass-Through 2.2.3 Empirical Evidence on Interest Rate Pass-Through 3. Monetary Policy in Indonesia 3.1. The adoption of Inflation Targeting Framework 3.2. Interest Rate Channel 4. Analysis 5. Concluding Remarks 6 Chapter 2 THEORY AND LITERATURE REVIEW This chapter is divided into two sections. The first section aims to provide the theory and evidences on IT. The theory about IT includes the background of IT adoption, the definition of IT, and the implementation of IT. This part also shows some empirical evidences regarding IT successfulness in achieving price stability and improving macroeconomic conditions. The second section discusses the importance of interest rate channel, the determinants of interest rate pass-through, and some evidences on the performance of interest rate pass-through. 2.1 Inflation Targeting The collapse of the Bretton Woods System in 1971 had spread the search for a new monetary policy framework. In 1990, New Zealand pioneered a new approach to monetary policy that is based on reaching a specific inflation target. This approach was later known as inflation targeting (IT). Within two decades from its first introduction, IT has gained 28 followers (Schmidt-Hebbel, 2009). As shown by Table 1, among these countries, about half of them are developing and emerging-market economies. In addition, many advanced countries like the U.S., Japan, and the Eurozone accepted many attributes of IT while some other countries are on their way to adopt IT (Roger, 2010). 2.1.1 Why Inflation Targeting? A low and stable inflation is important in creating a well-functioning economy because the costs of high inflation are pretentious. High inflation could dampen the level of output through, among other things, its influence on saving and investment decisions by households and firms. This happens because households and firms take into account the expected future price when making a decision. As high rates of inflation entail high variability of inflation, any unexpected disinflation will make these decisions subject to higher risks (Freedman & Laxton, 2009). When a firm finance long-term investment with long-term debt, for example, and an unexpected disinflation takes place, this firm is prone to the risk of losses. Moreover, high and unstable inflation may cause households and firms making wrong investment or 7 consumption decisions. This happens because they have difficulties in distinguishing relative price changes, i.e. the prices of goods in terms of other goods, from the general price. A period of high inflation is also likely to induce asset price bubbles, although it is not always the case that these bubbles occur at times of inflation. During the period of high inflation, it is difficult to measure the developments of future asset prices, and thus these assets tend to be overvalued. As a result, price bubbles may occur. The serious costs that are imposed by high inflation has made monetary authorities around the world become more and more alert to the significance of achieving and maintaining price stability (Freedman & Laxton, 2009). Moreover, as generally economists agree that monetary policy can affect real quantities, like output and unemployment, only in the short run, choosing inflation as the main objective becomes more convincing when medium- to long-term horizons are considered (Bernanke & Mishkin, 1997). In pursuing a low and stable inflation rate, central banks usually choose a nominal anchor. Freedman and Laxton (2009) explain why a nominal anchor can bring many merits to the conduct of a monetary policy. First, a nominal anchor is very useful in helping central banks to stay focus on the main objective and not to astray to very different objectives that may be proposed by the monetary policy decision makers. Second, a publicly announced nominal anchor will give clarity to the public about central bank’s objective in choosing a policy action and the reason behind a change in policy instrument. Finally, a credible nominal anchor is helpful in keeping public’s expectations ally with the policy goal, and therefore expedites the goal’s accomplishment. In the past, the monetary aggregate was common to be used as a nominal anchor. Unfortunately, targeting monetary aggregate was found to be ineffective due to the unstable money demand function (Bernanke & Mishkin, 1997). Moreover, according to Roger (2010), monetary targeting has not been successful because of financial market innovations. From the 1980s on, the emergence of financial globalization has made monetary targeting increasingly difficult. Besides money targeting, many countries chose to tie their domestic currency to a major currency as to achieve the similar low rates of inflation with the chosen major currency. It means that the exchange rate was used as nominal anchor. However, in the first 8 half of 1990s, many countries that opted for fixed exchange rate, such as Indonesia, Thailand, the U.K., Sweden, and Finland, were put under market pressure. As a result, they had to abandon the fixed exchange rate regime. Since the exchange rate could no longer be used as a nominal anchor and since the monetary aggregate was likely lacking of stability, these countries had to choose an alternative nominal anchor. Their choice fell to the sole sound and available option, which was IT. Hammond (2010) sees this as a pragmatic reason for adopting IT. He argues that the adoption of IT is mainly due to a failure in other monetary regimes rather than an advance in theory. However, Mishkin (2000) argues that IT is predominant from monetary targeting because it does not rely on the stability of the relationship between money and inflation. IT basically utilizes all the available information to choose the best settings for the monetary policy instruments. Furthermore, IT is also more advantageous from exchange rate peg. This is because IT could respond to shocks to the domestic economy well. In nearly all cases, the intention to achieve and maintain a lower rate of inflation has been the driving factor for a country to adopt IT (Freedman & Laxton, 2009). The economic conditions surrounding the adoption of IT, however, varied from country to country. New Zealand and Canada, the inflation targeter pioneers, chose to adopt IT not because their economy was in a crisis. They switched to IT mainly because they found IT best suited their needs of having a framework that could operate well in achieving price stability under a flexible exchange rate and unstable monetary aggregates. In some cases, like in the U.K., Sweden, and Brazil, the adoption was a result of the abandonment of the fixed exchange rate regime. As the exchange rate became more flexible, they need to choose an alternative nominal anchor. Against the background of unstable monetary aggregates, they considered IT framework as the best available mechanism. In other countries like Chile and Israel, IT adoption occurred gradually. In the beginning, they combined IT with the existing exchange rate target but along the time they put increasingly emphasis on IT. In addition, the reason why more and more countries chose to adopt IT is because IT is associated with increased transparency of monetary policy and increased accountability of the monetary policy makers. An explicit quantitative target of inflation brings about transparency because it communicates a clear and understandable goal for monetary policy. As the monetary policy becomes more transparent, central bank will likely be more committed in meeting its target, and thus improving accountability of the central bank. Both transparency 9 and accountability are important in enhancing the credibility of monetary policy. A credible monetary policy is crucial because it helps to anchor public’s expectations about current and future inflation. 2.1.2 What is Inflation Targeting? Inflation targeting is defined as a framework of monetary policy which consists of four main elements: (1) public announcement of inflation target over a specified time horizon (inflation target serves as nominal anchor); (2) explicit pursuit of a low and stable inflation as a primary and long-term goal, to which other goals are subordinated; (3) a more transparent central bank through conducting good communication to the public about the chosen plans, objectives, and decisions; (4) central bank’s accountability in achieving those objectives (Bernanke, Laubach, Mishkin, & Posen, 1999, Mishkin, 2000). Mishkin (2000) adds one critical element to that definition. He argues that IT should be supported by an information inclusive strategy that will determine the settings of policy instrument. This strategy should contain many variables and not only monetary aggregates or the exchange rate. He underlines that IT is not merely about announcing inflation target for the year ahead, but also having the other four aforementioned elements in the monetary policy strategy as to assure IT will be sustainable over the medium term. The above definitions are based on so-called full-fledged IT. However, there are many countries that perform “lighter” versions of IT either as a preparation towards full-fledged IT or to avoid the implications brought by the commitment to IT (Stone, 2003). IT, for example, was initially used by Chile and Israel in tandem with exchange rate regime but gradually increased the domination of inflation targeting regime. There is also other version in which a country is not as transparent as the general inflation targeters in communicating their strategy to the public. For the successfulness of IT adoption and maintaining, inflation targeter candidates should beforehand assess whether they have met several prerequisites. These prerequisites include the absence of fiscal and finance dominance, moderately low level of inflation, and central bank independence (Mishkin & Savastano, 2000, Mishkin & Schmidt-Hebbel, 2007). Central bank independence includes goal independence and instrument independence. Goal independence means that central bank is independent in formulating objectives, whereas 10 instrument independence implies the independence of central bank in choosing the instruments with which to achieve the chosen inflation target. In addition, it is also necessary, albeit not mandatory, to increase technical capability, especially in inflation and output forecasting. It is because any lack of this capability could hinder the smooth implementation of IT (Debelle, 1997). However, Batini and Laxton (2007) find that this is not a rigor rule. The start of IT can still work well with some pre-conditions left unfulfilled. 2.1.3 How Does Inflation Targeting Work? There is no consensus on how inflation targeting should be implemented and the policy practices also differ from one inflation targeter to the others. But in virtually all cases, central banks practice what later known as flexible IT. Bernanke and Mishkin (1997) argue that IT should be considered as a framework and not as a rule. When IT is seen as a framework, there are spaces for flexibility in which discretionary monetary policy actions can be accommodated. This implies that IT does not only constrain central banks from making policy decisions that could lead to undesirable long-run consequences (from its forwardlooking nature), but also permits some discretions when unexpected or exceptional circumstances occur. Akin to this view, Freedman and Laxton (2009) characterizes a flexible inflation targeting as a framework that aims at achieving the targeted inflation rate while minimizing the fluctuations in output and unemployment. The flexibility of inflation targeting gives chances for short-run stabilization objectives, especially with respect to output and employment. Bernanke and Mishkin (1997) mention some ways to achieve short-run stabilization objectives. First, prices that are typically prone to supply shocks are excluded from the price index on which the official inflation targets are based. The sources of these prices often are from food and energy prices, indirect tax changes, terms-of-trade shocks, and the direct effects of interest rate changes on index. Second, as already mentioned, inflation targets are usually defined as a range and not a single number. This arrangement gives central some flexibility in the short run to cope with the uncertainty that lies between policy levers and inflation outcomes. Third, short-term inflation targets can and have been adjusted to accommodate conditions that could not be controlled by the central bank, such as supply shocks or other exogenous changes. Inflation targeting is characterized by the announcement of inflation target, either by the 11 government, central bank, or the combination of both. As previously explained, such target is usually formed in a range rather than a single point, and is commonly arranged for multiple horizons ranging from one to four years. Many countries, especially emerging economies, experienced high rate of inflation before the adoption of IT. Even in some countries like Poland, Hungary, Serbia, and Ghana the inflation rate were at two digits, reaching around 10%. It was unrealistic for these countries to shrink the inflation rate instantaneously; therefore, IT generally allowed the transition process from the current level of inflation to the desired level to occur gradually. In this case, IT in the initial adoption was used as a tool for price stabilization through a so-called converging-target IT. Converging-target IT means that the inflation target is set at a moderate and even high inflation levels initially which then followed by pre-announcing a sequence of descending annual inflation targets to converge towards stationary targets (Schmidt-Hebbel, 2009). These steady-state targets are usually consistent with price stability. However, it should be borne in mind that in practice price stability does not mean zero inflation, but typically around two percent of annual rate of price change (Bernanke & Mishkin, 1997). As a way to increase transparency further, inflation-targeting central bank generally publish a regular, detailed assessment of the policy response. This includes inflation forecasts and policy responses that are needed to keep inflation on the right path. The Bank of England, for example, publishes a quarterly Inflation Report that contains detailed economic analyses, inflation projections as the basis of interest rate decisions, and assessment of the prospects for the U.K. inflation. 2.1.4 Has InflationTargeting Mattered? Many benefits can be obtained from introducing IT, which might also explain why the regime has worked well. Walsh, 2009 points out that the first lesson that could be drawn from IT experience is that IT is feasible and sustainable. This statement is supported by the fact that no countries have walked out on IT (Rose, 2007). Albeit its relative new existence among other monetary regimes, IT has been very durable in producing inflation outcomes (Mihov & Rose, 2008). However, there are numerous debates about the successfulness of IT in delivering satisfactory macroeconomic performance. Stiglitz (2008) argues that inflation targeting will not be able to 12 pass the test in the current economic crisis, while Walsh (2009) contends starkly by stating that financial crisis or demand shocks in general can be tackled by committing to explicit inflation target. The ability of IT to enhance macroeconomic performance has been questioned: whether this has been partially due to sheer good luck of a benign economic environment or solely to the IT (Lim, 2009, Lin & Ye, 2007, Walsh, 2009, Kurihara, 2010). This question was raised because the adoption of IT widely occurred during the Great Moderation, an economic era that was characterized by a low and stable inflation and a steady economic growth. If the Great Moderation was highly determined by good luck, then it may be difficult to see the marginal contribution of IT (Walsh, 2009). In general, studies reveal that the industrialized economies experienced little contribution of IT on either average inflation rates or inflation volatility, whereas the emerging economies found significant influence of IT. In order to see the difference that IT might make, Walsh (2009) suggests to looking at the three aspects that characterized a monetary policy environment, namely constraints, objectives, and beliefs. The effect of IT on constraints can be seen from its influence on the short run tradeoff between inflation and output. First, public will anchor their current and future expectations based on the explicit announcement of inflation target. This implies that IT allows a reduction in the average level of inflation without creating any increase in output volatility. Second, short-run tradeoff between output gap and inflation volatility can be enhanced by IT. As IT helps to align public’s expectations about future inflation, there will be greater stability of inflation expectations. This resulted in a lower volatility of inflation and also of real activity. Third, IT implies greater predictability of current and future targets, and thereby a decline in the volatility of cost shocks. However, this reduced uncertainty sometimes is being misinterpreted as good luck. IT is not only capable in altering the constraints faced by central bank, but also in altering the objectives of monetary policy. This could be done by clarifying central bank’s objectives and reassuring the absence of conflict among these objectives, especially with the objective of achieving and maintaining price stability. However, sometimes this is done with a cost. On the one hand, IT could indeed promote accountability, but on the other hand IT may sacrifice other macroeconomic goals (Friedman, 2004). If the latter happens, IT may entail a rise in real economic volatility. 13 Lastly, public’s beliefs about central bank’s commitment to low inflation could also be altered by IT. An explicit quantitative target for inflation increases public accountability of the central bank. Since policy decisions will be more transparent, this increases the incentives for the central bank to try to meet its target, instead of being distracted by outside pressures (Koder, Leber, & Mantik, 2010). Furthermore, this induces fewer chances that the central bank will fall into the time-inconsistency trap. Once a target has been announced, the central bank will definitely try to meet this target instead of pursuing another policy later, thereby enables central bank to achieve the gains from an optimal monetary policy. Central banks, for instance, can thus resist pressures from politicians to undertake expansionary monetary policy. Although Donald Brash (2000, p.4) argues “No amount of political promises, and no amount of institutional tinkering, will convince people that low inflation will be an enduring feature of the economic landscape if what they have actually seen over decades is promises regularly broken and the value of their money constantly shrinking.” The way IT influences all these three aspects shows that IT should be associated with a lower average inflation rate and lower inflation volatility (Walsh, 2009). When IT is able to trim down uncertainty about policy objectives, anchor public’s expectations about current and future inflation, and make the central bank’s hands are tied to their commitment, then IT will also induce a lower volatility of real economic activity. However, in some cases where IT put too much weight of the policy objectives on inflation, the volatility of real output is likely to increase. Several studies have investigated IT from an empirical perspective. Most of the studies presented in the literature focus on the impact of IT on the behavior of inflation and other macroeconomic variables, like unemployment, output, and interest rates. Besides, some studies look at the ability of IT to increase transparency. The results of these studies will be presented below. Evidence from industrialized economies Early study by Freeman and Willis (1995) estimate VAR models for real GDP, price levels, and interest rates in three IT ancestors, namely New Zealand, Canada, and the U.K. Their finding shows that interest rates did fall in the early 1990s, which signaled an improvement in monetary policy credibility. However, this did not persist in the long run. After a few years, 14 long-term rates started to increase again. This may suggest that the credibility effect of IT is short-lived, although Freeman and Willis argue that a global rise in interest rates may also be a strong reason for this resurgence. Ammer and Freeman (1995) estimate inflation forecasts with VAR and compare the results with actual income in the three countries. They find that inflation fell more than predicted by the VAR in the early 1990s, the time of IT adoption. However, a study by Debelle (1997) in these countries plus Sweden, Finland, Spain, and Australia reveals that the decline in inflation rates was followed by an increase in unemployment in some countries. This indicates that disinflation may occur not without a cost. Debelle also notes that the benign economic condition in the early 1990s made it difficult to see this disinflation as a success of IT regime because many non-inflation targeters also experienced disinflation. Kahn and Parrish (1998) examine the official central bank interest rate behavior in four IT countries viz. New Zealand, the U.K., Canada, Sweden and compare it with that in the U.S. They find that nominal short-term interest rate and its volatility in IT countries have declined after the adoption of IT. The decline in average short-term official rate was started from 622 basis point in New Zealand and 284 basis point in Sweden. However, the U.S. data also shows lower volatility of interest rate. The stable economic environment during this period may give a good reasoning for this result. Kutner and Posen (1999) estimate VARs for inflation, unemployment, short- and long-term interest rates to see the impact of IT on these variables. However, their empirical results are somewhat inconclusive. In Canada and the U.K., the introduction of IT did not lead to a change in the persistence of inflation, whereas in New Zealand, IT induced a decline in inflation persistence, but was followed by a stronger reaction to unemployment in the central bank’s reaction function. Walsh (2009) compares mean inflation rates and standard deviations between pre- and postIT adoption for ten Organization for Economic and Cooperation Development (OECD) countries. He finds that the adoption of IT helped to cut down average inflation. In general, the average decline was about 4.5 percentage points, from 6.55% to 2%. This decline was associated with a reduction in inflation volatility. In addition, Neumann and Hagen (2002) by comparing seven inflation targeters with three non-inflation targeters from industrialized 15 countries, also find that IT is not only able to cut down inflation but also to curb the volatility of inflation and interest rate. However, the above findings are not enough to justify that IT has succeeded in enhancing macroeconomic performance. Ball and Sheridan (2005) were the first to discuss that there is no causal link between IT and better inflation result. They examine twenty OECD countries, seven are inflation targeters that adopted IT in 1990s and the rest are non-inflation targeters. Inflation targeters indeed experienced reduced inflation rate, declining inflation volatility, and stable output growth, but surprisingly, non-inflation targeters also experienced the same improvements. This evidence shows that all OECD countries, and not only IT countries, have enjoyed lower and stable inflation rates. Moreover, they also find that non-inflation targeters obtained lower interest rate volatility than inflation targeters. This evidence makes them conclude that IT does not improve the economic performance of a country, although they also note that IT does no harm. Evidence including developing and emerging market economies One of the most basic yet important aspects that could indicate whether IT has mattered is the ability of inflation targeters to keep inflation rate close to their target. Schmidt-Hebbel (2009) observes inflation deviations from its target for both industrialized economies and emerging market economies (EMEs). He uses different measures, including mean absolute error, the mean squared error, and the root mean squared error. As could be seen from Table 2, by large most inflation targeters have succeeded to meet their target, especially the industrialized countries. However, some EMEs countries, like Serbia, Brazil, Mexico, Turkey, Indonesia, and Ghana show rather high deviations from the target. Another aspect that is of importance to be observed is transparency. Chortareas, Stasagave, and Sterne (2000) compare monetary policy transparency across 87 countries and find that transparency is a significant determinant of inflation rates and it affects inflation rates negatively. Since IT enhances the transparency of monetary policy, this result supports the view that IT is associated with a decline in inflation level. Svensson (1997) dubs IT as “inflation-forecast” targeting because the ability of IT to increase transparency is highly affected by inflation forecasts. Inflation forecasts could enhance and reinforce transparency and governance though better communication of policy decisions and macroeconomic 16 analysis to the public (Eijffinger & Geraats, 2006, Geraats, 2008). In turn, increased transparency will bring about higher credibility. In addition, Dincer and Eichengreen (2007) observe that the most transparent central banks appear to be inflation targeters, which are New Zealand, Sweden, the U.K, Canada, and the Czech Republic. Moreover, by investigating trends in transparency across four different monetary policy regimes over the period 1998-2006, Geraats (2008) finds that IT countries achieve by far the highest level of aggregate central transparency, which can be seen in Figure 1. More specifically, Figure 2 depicts the enhancement in transparency experienced by industrialized countries and emerging market economies during 1998-2005. Industrialized economies experienced much higher index of transparency than emerging market economies, but the gap has been shrinking over time. Some central banks in the EMEs have done individual study to see the effect of IT on their economies and find that the credibility of monetary policy and inflation targets has increased. This is particularly seen in Chile, the Czech Republic, Mexico, and Colombia. In general, these countries experienced more anchored expectations following an improvement of credibility. In Colombia, this enhanced credibility has partly contributed to a reduction in inflation persistence. Capistrán and Ramos-Francia (2007) explain that a credible inflation target will make agents set prices and wages based on this target, and thus weakening indexation mechanisms and adaptive expectations. As a result, shocks do not have permanent effects on inflation. In addition, central banks will also require less aggressive policy adjustments (Moreno, 2008). Evidence on inflation expectations Many of the potential benefits from IT work through its effect in anchoring expectations of future inflation. Walsh (2009) describes three ways to gauge the effects of IT on inflation expectations. First is by seeing how the inflation expectations react to news. Using inflation expectations implied by bond yields, Gürkaynak, Levin, & Swanson (2006) find a significant anchoring effect of inflation targeting. They test the responsiveness of inflation expectations to economic news and find that the inflation expectations in the U.S. reacted to news; an evidence that is not found in Sweden, an inflation targeter. This finding suggests that the expectations in Sweden were firmly anchored. This finding is confirmed by Gürkaynak, 17 Levin, Marder, & Swanson (2007). The second way to see the impact of IT on inflation is by observing whether the lag in inflation is correlated with the expectations of future inflation. Levin, Natalucci, and Piger (2004) estimate the effects of lagged inflation on long-term inflation expectations for several IT and non-IT industrialized countries. They find that lagged inflation is significantly correlated with expectations of future inflation in the non-IT countries. This correlation is non-existence among IT countries and thus shows that IT does play a role in anchoring inflation expectations. Lastly, it could also be measured by looking at the distribution of inflation expectations. Carrera (2008) uses this approach to see how well IT in anchoring expectations in Peru. He observes the distribution of individual responses to a survey of inflation expectations in this country from 2000 to 2007. The finding shows that since the adoption of IT in 2002, the distribution of inflation expectations has been shifting significantly. Almost all the mass of the distribution was concentrated within the official target ranges. 2.2 Interest Rate Channel 2.2.1 The Importance of Interest Rate Channel A good understanding of monetary transmission mechanism is one of the keystones of modern monetary policymaking (Gigineishvili, 2011). Monetary transmission mechanism is a process through which changes in central bank policy are transmitted to the real sector, allowing the central bank to steer the economy to attain the designated objectives. This mechanism consists of four main channels, namely the exchange rate channel, the interest rate channel, the asset prices channel, and the credit channel (Mishkin, 1996). The effectiveness of monetary policy relies on the speed and the strength of each of these channels. All these four channels transmit policy actions to aggregate demand through financial markets. However, the type of financial market that is used as a medium of pass through differs from one channel to the other channels (Gigineishvili, 2011). The interest rate channel works when a change in the policy rate is transmitted immediately to the short-term wholesale money markets, such as repos and interbank deposits. The 18 adjustment of long-term interest rate, however, occurs gradually and more complex. Interest rate channel emphasizes on the impact of real interest (rather than nominal) on consumer and business decisions due to its importance in affecting spending (Mishkin, 2009). With the sticky prices notion, in which the aggregate price level adjusts only gradually over time, an expansionary monetary policy does not only lower the short-term nominal interest rates but also the short-term real interest rates. The expectation hypothesis of term structure postulates that the long-term interest rate is determined by the average of expected future short-term interest rate; therefore, a persistent change in short-term real interest rate eventually reflects a change in long-term real interest rate (Bank of England, 2005, ECB, 2000, Kusmiarso,et al., 2002, Loayza & Schmidt-Hebbel, 2002, Mishkin, 2009). Changes in market interest rates will alter lending and deposit rates, which then influence investment and saving decisions made by firms and households. Eventually, this will affect aggregate demand and inflation. The asset price channel basically works in a similar way with the interest rate channel, but through the market value of securities, such as bonds, stocks, and equities. The policyinduced changes in interest rates alter the prices of these assets, which then influence the effective cost of capital and the net worth of households and firms. Consumption and investment will be adjusted accordingly, and as a result, aggregate demand and prices will also be affected. The policy-induced changes in interest rates can also affect the exchange rate through foreign exchange market. The exchange rate represents the relative price between domestic and foreign money. An unexpected increase (decrease) in policy rate, ceteris paribus, quickly reflects in an appreciation (depreciation) of the domestic currency. The appreciation (depreciation) of the exchange rate implies a higher (lower) domestic interest rate relative to foreign-currency assets, making domestic assets more (less) attractive to international investors. The higher (lower) value of the domestic currency is reflected in a higher (lower) price of domestic goods relative to foreign goods, causing a decrease (increase) in net export and consequently a decrease (increase) in aggregate demand. Lastly, the credit channel operates through the effects of asymmetric information problems in financial market on bank lending and firms’ and households’ balance sheet. Asymmetric information problems in financial market are the moral hazard and the adverse selection problems. An expansionary monetary policy, for example, raises the price of stock and 19 increases the net worth of firms, and thus driving down moral hazard and adverse selection problems. As a result, investment spending increases which will be followed by a rise in aggregate demand. The exchange rate channel is believed to play a vital role at the early stages of financial development (Gigineishvili, 2011). It is because foreign exchange is seen as the sole most liquid and inflation proof asset in countries with undeveloped capital and money markets. This view is supported by the evidence that exchange rate pass-through is much stronger in emerging market economies than in industrialized economies (Korhonena & Wachtel, 2005, Tieman, 2004). The other three channels generally perform well in more developed markets (Gigineishvili, 2011). Credit channel is of significance in markets with limited substitutability. Interest rate channel and asset price channel appear to be weak when the financial system is shallow and poorly diversified (Loayza & Schmidt-Hebbel, 2002). In countries with high inflation, the interest rate channel is also weak because high inflation usually entails high volatility of inflation (Lopes, 1998). Recently, there is a worldwide emergence of using short-term interest rate as the main instrument of monetary signals, which makes the interest rate channel as the key transmission channel. In addition, interest rate channel is one of the main foundations in IT regime, a regime that has been adopted by a growing number of countries. In emerging countries, the interest rate channel was weak during the 1980s and 1990s. This could occur because, inter alia, the bond and money markets were not well developed and there were frequent shifts in the risk premium. However, evidences show that the role of interest rate channel in emerging countries has increased through time (Mohanty & Turner, 2008). In Thailand, interest rate channel has become more important after the countries hit by the 1997-98 crises. In the Philippines, central bank lending rate dominates the transmission channel in the long run. In Czech Republic and Poland, there has been an increase in pass-through from policy rates to deposit and lending rates. In Mexico, the role of exchange rate has fallen quite significantly in early 2000 and as a return, interest rate started to contribute more to the short- and longrun variation in output and inflation. All in all, more and more emerging market economies follow the operating systems of monetary policy in industrialized economies, i.e. the central bank sets a short-term interest rate (policy rate) and market will determine other interest rates in the economy. 20 As interest rate channel has become increasingly important, there have been extensive empirical researches that seek to measure the qualitative and quantitative properties of interest rate pass-through. This pass-through shows the movement of changes in policy rate to changes in the target variables. Interest rate pass-through could be divided into three phases. First, changes in policy rates leads to changes in market rates, from the short-term rates moving to the long-term rates. Second, changes in market rates are transmitted further to commercial bank lending and deposit rates. Finally, these changes influence savings, investments, and consumptions, which altogether determine the level of aggregate demand and prices. The first phase generally occurs strongly and quite immediate. The second phase is more divergent and is an important phase in the process of monetary transmission. As the pass-through from market interest rates to loan and deposit rates gets quicker and fuller, monetary policy transmission will be stronger (Bondt, 2002). It is therefore important to understand the degree and speed at which changes in policy rates are passed-through to retail rates faced by firms and households. A complete pass-through happens when there is a one for one change from money market rates to retail rates. The retail rates are considered to be sticky when they respond sluggishly to movements in the money market. 2.2.2 Determinant of Interest Rate Pass-Through As already mentioned, the strength and speed of interest rate pass-through contribute to the effectiveness of monetary policy transmission mechanism. Moreover, in liberalized financial environment, the responsiveness of loan and deposit rates acts as a key feature of the monetary transmission process (Kamin, Turner, & Van‘t dack, 1998). A stronger and more rapid response of interest rates faced by borrowers and lenders to changes in money market rates makes the transmission of policy rate to the real economy becomes more effective. There are several factors that determine the strength and speed of interest-rate pass through. The most important factor is the competitiveness, depth, and diversity of the financial market. The degree of competition plays a key role in determining the speed and strength of the responsiveness of the loan and deposit rates (Kamin, Turner, & Van‘t dack, 1998). In an environment where there are numerous banking institutions and competitive market conditions, changes in the cost of fund will immediately reflect in the loan and deposit rates. Leuvensteijn, Sørensen, Bikker, and Rixtel (2008) investigate some countries in the euro area and also find that a stronger competition in the market of these countries resulted in a faster 21 transmission process. Moreover, a highly competitive banking market combined with improved availability of alternative capital market-based instrument for financial instrument will speed up the pass-through further (Gropp, Sørensen, & Lichtenberger, 2007). In a contrast, a banking sector that is highly concentrated will make the response of loan and deposit rates sluggish and asymmetric. The responsiveness of loan and deposit rate also tends to be weaker when state-owned banks are present because these banks are not forced to maximize profits. Kamin, Turner, & Van‘t dack (1998) argue that as the financial market gets deeper, the role of expectations will be enhanced. Consequently, this will hasten the speed at which changes in short-term rates are passed-through to other interest rates. Additionally, they also note that a thin or uncompetitive financial market can increase the volatility of money market interest rates. If the money market interest rates are highly volatile and tend to reverse their movements quickly, banks will be reluctant to adjust the loan and deposit rates because it entails high cost. As a consequence, interest rate pass through loses its strength. Weber, Gerke, and Worms (2009) mention that financial innovation can shorter the link between short-term market rates and lending rates. Based on their study, Gropp, Sørensen, and Lichtenberger (2007) find that advances in risk management technologies is one of the factors that could speed up the pass-through. Their results show that a high pass-through from long-term rates to rates on mortgages could be obtained when the access to financial instruments is easy. In addition, Kamin, Turner, and Van‘t dack (1998) mention that the access of household and firms to alternative domestic funding sources, such as securities markets also determines the loan and deposit rates set by the domestic banking system. The more various the alternative funding sources, the faster the speed of pass through. Moreover, if there is a good integration between the banking sector and the securities markets, then banks will be more pressured to improve interest rates responsiveness under their control. Volatility in money markets is another factor that determines the speed and strength of interest rate pass-through. Higher volatility tends to weaken the pass-through (Gigineishvili, 2011, Cottarelli and Kourelis, 1994, Mojon, 2000, and Sander and Kleimeier, 2004). Gigineishvili (2011) explains that the money market interest rates carry reliable information that is needed for banks to alter the deposit and loan rates. High volatility in the money markets brings about uncertainty into market signals, making banks be more cautious in 22 passing market rates to their customers. They prefer to wait until the noise is no longer there. In line with this, Lopes (1998) argue that in the case of high inflation, the high volatility of inflation should be taken into consideration when determining real interest rates. It means that the relevant cost of capital concept will be equal to nominal interest rates minus the certainty equivalent of inflation. This certainty equivalent will exceed its expected value by a ‘volatility’ premium when inflation is highly volatile; therefore, in the economy with high inflation volatility, a high real interest rate is not always similar to a monetary tightening. In addition, Lopes also notes that as the stabilization policies have been able to reduce inflation volatility, the interest rate channel will be stronger. Statistical evidence shows that bank rates responsiveness to a change in policy rate has been slower in emerging market economies than in industrialized economies (Kamin, Turner, & Van‘t dack, 1998). Low competition, less flexibility, and limited depth of financial markets in the emerging countries might be the reason for this result. It is therefore needed to develop the financial markets in these countries to strengthen transmission. Gigineishvili (2011) argues that countries with underdeveloped financial markets should opt for a monetary framework that uses monetary aggregates or exchange rates as a nominal anchor rather than inflation targeting framework that depends heavily on strong interest rate pass-through. 2.2.3 Evidence on Interest Rate Pass-Through As already mentioned, the strength and speed of interest rate pass-through contribute to the effectiveness of monetary policy transmission mechanism. Moreover, in liberalized financial environment, the responsiveness of loan and deposit rates acts as a key feature of the monetary transmission process (Kamin, Turner, & Van‘t dack, 1998). A stronger and more rapid response of interest rates faced by borrowers and lenders to changes in money market rates makes the transmission of policy rate to the real economy becomes more effective. There are several factors that determine the strength and speed of interest-rate pass through. The most important factor is the competitiveness, depth, and diversity of the financial market. The degree of competition plays a key role in determining the speed and strength of the passthrough to loan and deposit rates (Kamin, Turner, & Van‘t dack, 1998). In an environment where there are numerous banking institutions and competitive market conditions, changes in 23 the cost of fund will immediately reflect in the loan and deposit rates. Leuvensteijn, Sørensen, Bikker, and Rixtel (2008) investigate some countries in the euro area and also find that a stronger competition in the market of these countries resulted in a faster transmission process. Moreover, a highly competitive banking market combined with improved availability of alternative capital market-based instrument for financial instrument will speed up the pass-through further (Gropp, Sørensen, & Lichtenberger, 2007). In a contrast, as already mentioned, a banking sector that is highly concentrated will make the response of loan and deposit rates sluggish and asymmetric. The responsiveness of loan and deposit rate also tends to be weaker when state-owned banks are present because these banks are not forced to maximize profits. The adjustment of deposit and lending rates, however, sometimes appears to be asymmetric. In Colombia, pass through to deposit rates was quicker than to loan rates due to greater competition in the deposit market than in the loan market. The same case also occurred in Indonesia and Thailand. Commercial banks in these countries were likely to adjust the deposit rates more frequently than the loan rates. In general, the adjustment of deposit and loan rates in the banking sector depends on the initiative of the most prominent banks in the deposit and loan segment of the market (Kamin, Turner, & Van‘t dack, 1998). Statistical evidence shows that bank rates responsiveness to a change in policy rate has been slower in emerging market economies than in industrialized economies (Kamin, Turner, & Van‘t dack, 1998). Low competition, less flexibility, and limited depth of financial markets in the emerging countries might be the reason for this result. It is therefore needed to develop the financial markets in these countries to strengthen transmission. Gigineishvili (2011) argues that countries with underdeveloped financial markets should opt for a monetary framework that uses monetary aggregates or exchange rates as a nominal anchor rather than opt for inflation targeting framework that depends heavily on strong interest rate passthrough. 24 Chapter 3 MONETARY POLICY IN INDONESIA This chapter aims to give a brief overview of the conduct of monetary policy in Indonesia, emphasizing on the background of the adoption of IT framework. Besides, this chapter also provides a short explanation about how the interest rate channel works in Indonesia and how well this channel performed during the pre- and post-crisis period. 3.1 The Adoption of Inflation Targeting Since 1970, Indonesia has opted for three different exchange rate regimes. A fixed exchange rate regime was implemented from 1970 to 1978 and a managed floating exchange rate was chosen thereafter. However, due to a strong pressure on the rupiah at the onset of the 1997 crisis, the managed floating regime had to be abandoned. In August 1997, the rupiah started to free float. This new regime implies that the value of rupiah as an exchange rate is strongly determined by the supply and demand in the market. The crisis in 1997 brought a severe impact to the Indonesian economy and was considered to be the worst recession the economy has experienced (Goeltom, 2008). The output shrank by 13.68% and annual inflation rate skyrocketed to 77.6% in 1998 (year on year basis). Capital flight and unfavorable market sentiment were rampant, worsening the economy as they entailed excessive exchange rate volatility. It then became increasingly difficult for monetary policy to maintain the stability of rupiah. Moreover, as the weakening rupiah passed-through its effect to inflation, the interest rate had to be raised sharply to support economic and financial stability. The high interest rate combined with the substantial depreciation of the rupiah have worsened the banks’ asset quality and partly induced corporate failures. To prevent the collapse of the entire banking system, Bank Indonesia had to provide liquidity support to commercial banks, and thus raising the base money. This vicious cycle was likely to worsen the economic further and trigger hyperinflation. Before that happened, BI decided to stabilize the economy by restoring confidence in the national currency. During this stabilization period, BI gained support from the IMF. The IMF advised BI to tighten the monetary policy and adopt base money as both the operational target and the nominal anchor, but still kept its eye on various aggregates and interest rates. However, along 25 the time the use of base money as the operating target was found to be ineffective. Policymakers argued that it was troublesome to control M0 growth, making it difficult to achieve the base money target (Goeltom, 2008, Warjiyo & Agung, 2002). Moreover, base money could not give a good signal to the market, and thereby failed to maintain market expectations on future exchange rate movements. Following the abandonment of the managed floating exchange rate and the failing of base money as a nominal anchor, BI needed to choose an alternative nominal anchor. With this background, BI decided to choose inflation as a nominal anchor. As argued by Freedman and Laxton (2009), a nominal anchor is a vital element for conducting monetary policy because it helps to give clarity about the (intermediate and final) objectives of the central bank, and thus abating the central bank to achieve these objectives. By using inflation as the nominal anchor, public will be well guided to shape their inflation expectations needed to make decisions on investments and savings. Beside the need to find an alternative nominal anchor, BI’s decision to shift to IT regime was because there have been an increasingly number of countries joined the IT club and gained success in lowering inflation rate while keeping output volatility at a low level (Alamsyah, Joseph, Agung, & Zulverdy, 2001). In 1999, a new central bank act was enacted, namely the Act No. 23/1999. This act was then revised into the Act No. 3/2004. This new act postulates that BI is obliged to announce inflation target at the beginning of the year, starting from 2000. Besides, this act also mandates BI to (1) set price stability as the ultimate objective, (2) be independent in both setting the inflation target (goal independence) and conducting the monetary policy (instrument independence), (3) be free from governments’ and other parties’ intervention when choosing monetary policy, (4) have a clear mechanisms that strengthen its accountability and transparency in implementing policies (Goeltom, 2008). These core points of the act suit the characteristics of a central bank adopting IT framework as asserted by (Bernanke, Laubach, Mishkin, & Posen, 1999). The declaration of this act became the basis for central bank independence needed for the implementation of IT framework in the future. As mandated by the new act, BI has announced the annual inflation target and the plan of monetary policy since the beginning of 2000. However, it is worth noting that during this period, the explicit announcement of inflation target does not imply that BI has already adopted an IT framework. As what explained by (Stone, 2003), during this period BI could 26 be considered to perform a “lighter” version of IT as a preparation towards a full-fledged IT. The official adoption of a full-fledged IT framework in Indonesia occurred later in July 2005. In implementing IT, BI follows a flexible-type of IT which implies that IT is seen as a framework and not a rigor rule. With this principle, when performing monetary policy, BI also takes into account other goals other than a low and stable inflation. Since the enactment of Act no. 23/1999, BI has made a number of serious efforts to enhance the quality and credibility of its monetary policy (Goeltom, 2008, Warjiyo & Agung, 2002). These were done as preparations towards the implementation of IT as well as to support BI’s role for nurturing the economic recovery in Indonesia. To monitor the monetary policy stance and direction, BI conducts a monthly Board of Governors meeting. In addition, BI also carries extensive researches to provide better analysis and forecasts of inflation, economic, financial trends, and policy scenarios for the monetary policy, which was of importance to support BI in making decision. The announcement of inflation target and the consistent achievement of this target will raise the credibility of the monetary policy taken by BI. Increased credibility will make public expectations ally with the target set by BI. To increase transparency, BI communicates the result of the Board of Governors meeting to the public through various media, including press releases, press conferences, seminars with academicians and other stakeholders, as well as on the Bank’s website. BI also provides quarterly reports to the Parliament to increase accountability. These reports include a review of monetary policy and other tasks of BI on banking and payment system. All these efforts done by BI since the beginning of 2000 are important to speed up the adoption of a fullfledged IT framework. IT is forward-looking in the sense that BI needs to respond to future developments of inflation. At the operational level, BI rate as the policy rate is used to respond to the future trend of inflation. BI rate is announced by the Board of Governors of BI in each monthly Board of Governors meeting. The BI rate is implemented through open market operations for one-month Sertifikat Bank Indonesia (SBI) or BI’s certificates. SBI is used because of three important reasons, which are (1) it is a good signaling tool of monetary policy response, (2) it is used as benchmark by banks and market players in Indonesia, (3) it plays a prominent role in monetary transmission mechanism (Goeltom, 2008). When the forecasted future inflation 27 lies above (below) the established inflation target, BI generally will raise (lower) the BI rate. This is done without neglecting other factors in the economy. To achieve the monetary policy operational target, the BI monetary operations are used as a medium where BI rate is adjusted based on the liquidity management on the money market. The monetary policy operational target will determine the movement of the interbank overnight (O/N) rate. Changes in interbank O/N rate will be followed by changes in the deposit and lending rates. These changes will eventually affect output and inflation. 3.2 Interest rate channel In Indonesia, the BI rate serves as the main instrument for influencing economic activity and the overriding objective of attaining the chosen inflation target; hence, BI rate adjustments become the starting point of the monetary transmission mechanism. The transmission of BI rate decisions to achieve the targeted inflation level operates through five different channels and subject to time lag. These channels are the interest rate channel, the exchange rate channel, the asset price channel, the credit channel, and the expectations channel. There have been an extensive number of literatures that study the various transmission channels and how well they affect the effectiveness of monetary policy. Some recent studies allow for financial market imperfections, and it is found that financial market imperfections add the complexity of the monetary transmission mechanism. Imperfections and asymmetric information in financial markets may affect the transmission channels. Warjiyo & Agung, (2002) argue that the relative strength of the five transmission channels in general depends on the existing structure and arrangements of a country’s economy and financial markets. Due to this reason, monetary transmission is often dubbed as a “black box” in the theory of monetary policy. Understanding monetary transmission mechanism is of importance for Indonesia in order to enhance the role of monetary policy in maintaining the stability of the rupiah as a way to foster economic recovery during the crisis period (Warjiyo & Agung, Monetary Transmission in Indonesia: An Overview, 2002). As the crisis went by and Indonesia decided to adopt IT framework in 2005, the smooth functioning of monetary transmission mechanism gained importance to support the successfulness of IT adoption and implementation in Indonesia. It 28 is because the effectiveness of monetary policy is determined by how well the transmission channels transmit changes in the BI rate to the real economy and prices. With this background, BI conducted comprehensive researches in 2001 to study the transmission mechanisms through the five different channels of monetary policy. The results of these studies, more specifically on the interest rate channel, will be discussed further here. The interest rate channel in Indonesia transmits changes in the BI rate to bank deposit and lending rates. When the economy experiences a downturn, BI should stimulus the economy by lowering the interest rates. The decrease in interest rates will be followed by a reduction in bank lending rates. As the loan rates decline, corporate and household demand for credit will be enhanced. In addition, this will also reduce the cost of capital for companies engaging in investment. As a result, investment and consumption increases which in turn will boost the economy. On the other hand, when the inflationary pressure increases, BI will raise the BI rate to reduce the inflationary pressure and slow down the economic activity. The study about the strength of interest rate channel in Indonesia was done by Kusmiarso, et al.(2002). Using VAR analysis and Granger test, they investigate the relationship between the policy rate and real sector variables. They also observe the behavior of banking markets in responding to policy rate, involving several micro factors on banks, namely the interbank O/N rate, deposit rate, and credit rate. The study emphasizes the observation on the period before and after the 1997 crisis. Before the crisis, empirical evidence from VAR analysis shows that the interbank rate was the main determinant of real deposit rate and real investment credit rate. However, real credit rate did not strongly influence investment growth. Investment growth, instead, appeared to rely heavily on the high access to foreign borrowing. The same case also occurred with consumption growth as it was weakly affected by changes in real deposit rate. This could happen due to the stable and relatively low real deposit rate. Study also reveals that changes in the policy rate were transmitted to the loan rate within a faster period than to the deposit rate. It took three months for the loan rate and six months for the deposit rate. This behavior was plausible since deposit rate represent banks’ cost while the loan rate represents banks’ revenue. During this period, the investment loan rates were responsive to a change in the interbank rate due to the boom in the economy and the high need for fund from the business sector. 29 For the post-crisis period, the real deposit rate and real investment credit rate were less responsive to the interbank rate than the pre-crisis period. An increase in the interbank rate did have an influence on the one-month deposit real interest rate, but with a smaller magnitude that the three-month deposit real interest rate. In the mean time, the increase of interbank rate initially resulted in a negative growth of consumption for the same period. The real investment credit rate, however, did not adjust with the same magnitude as the change in the deposit rate. This occurred because generally agents in the money market are more sensitive to higher loan rate than higher deposit rate. A higher loan rate will likely to induce higher debtor fault and non-performing loan, and thus increasing the risks of the banks in lending money. However, unlike the pre-crisis period, this period showed that the investment (consumption) growth has been strongly affected by the real investment credit rate (real deposit rate). 30 Bibliography Alamsyah, H., Joseph, C., Agung, J., & Zulverdy, D. (2001). Towards Implementation of Inflation Targeting in Indonesia. Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, 309‐324. Ammer, J., & Freeman, R. T. (1995). Inflation targeting in the 1990s: The experiences of New Zealand, Canada, and the United Kingdom. Journal of Economics and Business, 165‐192. Ball, L., & Sheridan, N. (2005). Does Inflation Targeting Matter? In B. S. Bernanke, & M. Woodford, The Inflation Targeting Debate. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. Bank of England. (2005). The Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy. Retrieved December 2012, from Bank of England: www.bankofengland.co.uk Batini, N., & Laxton, D. M. (2007). Under What Conditions Can Inflation Targeting Be Adopted? The Experience From Emerging Markets. Central Bank of Chile, 467‐506. Bernanke, B. S., & Mishkin, F. S. (1997). Inflation Targeting: A New Framework for Monetary Policy? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 97‐116. Bernanke, B. S., Laubach, T., Mishkin, F. S., & Posen, A. S. (1999). Inflation Targeting Lessons from the International Experience. New Jersey: Princeton University Press. BI. (n.d.). Monetary. Retrieved December 2011, from Bank Indonesia: http://www.bi.go.id/web/en/Moneter/ Boediono. (1998). Merenungkan Kembali Mekanisme Transmisi Moneter di Indonesia (Revisiting Monetary Transmission Mechanism in Indonesia). Buletin Ekonomi Moneter dan Perbankan Vol. 1, No. 1, 1‐4. Bondt, G. D. (2002). Retail Bank Interest Rate Pass‐Through: New Evidence at the Euro Level. European Central Bank, Working Paper No. 136. . Brash, D. T. (2000, February 9). Inflation Targeting in New Zealand, 19882000. Retrieved February 2012, from Reserve Bank of New Zealand: http://www.rbnz.govt.nz/speeches/0086932.html Capistrán, C., & Ramos‐Francia, M. (2007). Does Inflation Targeting Affect the Dispersion of Inflation Expectations? Documento de Investigación 2007–11, Dirección General de Investigación Económica, Banco de México. Carrera, C. (2008). Rational Expectations and Credibility: The Case of Peru . Chortareas, G., Stasagave, D., & Sterne, G. (2000). Does it Pay to be Transparent? International Evidence from Central Bank Forecasts. Bank of England. Cottarelli, C., & Kourelis, A. (1994). Financial Structure, Bank Lending Rates and the Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy. IMF Working Paper. Debelle. (1997). Inflation Targeting in Practice. IMF Working Papers. Dincer, N. N., & Eichengreen, B. (2007). Central Bank Transparency: Where, Why, and with What Effects? NBER Working Paper . ECB . (2000, June). Monetary Policy Transmission in the Euro Area. ECB Monthly Bulletin, pp. 43‐58. Eijffinger, S. C., & Geraats, P. M. (2006). How transparent are central banks? European Journal of Political Economy, 1‐22. Freedman, C., & Laxton, D. (2009). Why Inflation Targeting? IMF Working Paper. Freeman, R. T., & Willis, J. L. (1995). Targeting Inflation in the 1990s: Recent Challenges. International Finance Discussion Papers. 31 Friedman, B. M. (2004). Why the Federal Reserve Should Not Adopt Inflation Targeting. International Finance, 129‐136. Geraats, P. M. (2008). Trends in monetary policy transparency. Bank of Canada Economic Conference Presentation. Ottawa. Gigineishvili, N. (2011). Determinants of Interest Rate Pass‐Through: Do Macroeconomic Conditions and Financial Market Structure Matter? IMF Working Paper. Goeltom, M. (2008). The Transmission Mechanisms of Monetary Policy in Indonesia. BIS Papers No. 35, 317‐340. Gropp, R., Sørensen, C. K., & Lichtenberger, J. (2007). The Dynamics of Bank Spreads and and Financial Structure. ECB Working Papers. Gürkaynak, R. S., Levin, A. T., & Swanson, E. T. (2006). Does Inflation Targeting Anchor Long‐Run Inflation Expectations? Evidence from Long‐Term Bond Yields in the U.S., U.K., and Sweden. Working Paper Series 20062009, Federal Reserves of San Fransisco. Gürkaynak, R. S., Levin, A. T., Marder, A. N., & Swanson, E. T. (2007). Inflation Targeting and the Anchoring of Inflation Expectations in The Western Hemisphere. In F. S. Mishkin, & K. and Schmidt‐Hebbel, Monetary Policy under Inflation Targeting. Banco Central de Chile. Hammond, G. (2010). State of the Art of Inflation Targeting. Centre for Central Bank Studies, Handbook No. 29, Bank of England. Kahn, G. A., & Parrish, K. (1998). Conducting Monetary Policy with Inflation Targets. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review, 5‐32. Kamin, S., Turner, P., & Van ‘t dack, J. (1998). The Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy in Emerging Market Economies: An Overview. BIS policy papers no.3, 8‐67. Kamin, S., Turner, P., & Van‘t dack, J. (1998). The Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy in Emerging Market Economies: An Overview. BIS policy papers no.3, 8‐67. Koder, S., Leber, A., & Mantik, W. (2010). Has Inflation Targeting Prove a Success in Industrialized Countries? Universiteit Van Amsterdam. Korhonena, I., & Wachtel, P. (2005). A note on exchange rate pass‐through in CIS countries. Research in International Business and Finance. Kurihara, Y. (2010). Has Inflation Targeting Been Effective? International Journal of Business. Kusmiarso, B., Sukawati, E., Pambudi, S., Angkoro, D., Prasmuko, A., & Hafidz, I. S. (2002). Interest Rate Channel of Monetary Transmission in Indonesia. In P. Warjiyo, & J. Agung, Transmission Mechanisms of Monetary Policy in Indonesia (pp. 33‐108). Jakarta: Bank Indonesia. Kutner, K. N., & Posen, A. S. (1999). Does Talk Matter After All? Inflation Targeting and Central Bank Behavior. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report. Leuvensteijn, M. v., Sørensen, C. K., Bikker, J. A., & Rixtel, A. A. (2008). Impact of Bank Competition on the Interest Rate Pass‐Through in the Euro Area. Tjalling C Koopmans Research Institute, Discussion Paper Series. Levin, A. T., Natalucci, F. M., & Piger, J. M. (2004). The Macroeconomic Effects of Inflation Targeting. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 51‐80. Lim, G. C. (2009). Inflation Targeting. The Australian Economic Review, 110‐118. Lin, S., & Ye, H. (2007). Does Inflation Targeting Really Make a Difference? Evaluating the Treatment Effect of Inflation Targeting in Seven Industrial Countries. Journal of Monetary Economics, 21‐33. 32 Loayza, N., & Schmidt‐Hebbel, K. (2002). Monetary Policy Functions and Transmission Mechanism: An Overview. Retrieved December 2011, from Banca Central: http://www.bcentral.cl/Estudios/banca‐central/pdf/v4/001_020Gallego.pdf Lopes, F. L. (1998). The Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy in a Stabilizing Economy: Notes on the Case of Brazil. In The Transmission of Monetary Policy in Emerging Market Economies (pp. 65‐ 72). BIS Policy Papers No. 3. Mihov, I., & Rose, A. K. (2008, April 24). Is Old Money Better Than New? Duration and Monetary Regimes. Retrieved February 2012, from Economics: The Open‐Access, Open‐Assessment E‐Journal: http://www.economics‐ejournal.org/economics/journalarticles/2008‐13. Mishkin, F. S. (1996). Understanding Financial Crises: A Developing Country Perspective. In M. Bruno, & B. Pleskovic, Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics 1996 (pp. 29‐62). Washington D.C: World Bank. Mishkin, F. S. (2000). Inflation Targeting in Emerging Market Countries. NBER Working Paper Series. Mishkin, F. S. (2009). The economics of Money, Banking, and Financial Markets (Chapter 23). Pearson. Mishkin, F. S., & Savastano, M. (2000). Monetary Policy Strategies for Latin America. NBER Working Paper. Mishkin, F. S., & Schmidt‐Hebbel, K. (2007). A Decade of Inflation Targeting in the World: What Do We Know and What Do We Need to Know? In F. S. Mishkin, Monetary Policy Strategy. Cambridge: M.I.T Press. Mohanty, M. S., & Turner, P. (2008). Monetary Policy in Emerging Market Economies: What is New? In Transmission Mechanisms for Monetary Policy in Emerging Market Economies (pp. 1‐60). BIS Papers No. 35. Mojon, B. (2000). Financial Structure and the Interest Channel of the ECB Monetary Policy. ECB Working Paper. Moreno, R. (2008). Monetary Policy Transmission and the Long‐Term Interest Rate in Emerging Markets. BIS Papers , 61‐80. Neumann, M. J., & Hagen, J. v. (2002). Does Inflation Targeting Matter. Federal Reserves of St. Louis Review, 127‐148. Roger, S. (2010). Inflation Targeting Turns 20. Finance and Development, 46‐49. Rose, A. K. (2007). A Stable International Monetary System Emerges: Bretten Woods, Reversed. Journal of International Money and Finance. Sander, H., & Kleimeier, S. (2004). Interest Rate Pass‐through in an Enlarged Europe: the Role of Banking Market Structure for Monetary Policy Transmission in Transition Economies. METEOR Research Memoranda No. 045, University of Maastricht (Netherlands). Sarwono, H. A., & Warjiyo, P. (1998). Mencari Paradigma Baru Manajemen Moneter Dalam Sistem Nilai Tukar Fleksible: Suatu Pemikiran Untuk Penerapannya di Indonesia (Searching for New Paradigm for Monetary Management under Flexible Exchange Rate System). Buletin Ekonomi Moneter dan Perbankan, Vol. 1, No. 1, 5‐23. Schmidt‐Hebbel, K. (2009, October). Inflation Targeting Twenty Years on: Where, Why, Which Results, What Lies Ahead? Retrieved January 2012, from www.economia.puc.cl: http://eco3147.facea.puc.cl/economia_puc/docs/dt_360.pdf Stiglitz, J. E. (2008). The Failure of Inflation Targeting. Retrieved February 2012, from Project Syndicate: http://www.project‐syndicate.org/print_commentary/stiglitz99/English Stone, M. R. (2003). Inflation Targeting Lite. IMF Working Paper. 33 Svensson, L. E. (1997). Inflation forecast targeting: implementing and monitoring inflation targets. European Economic Review, 1111‐1146. Tieman, A. F. (2004). Interest Rate Pass‐Through in Romania and Other Central European Economies. IMF Working Paper. Walsh, C. E. (2009). Inflation Targeting: What Have We Learned? University of California, Santa Cruz. Warjiyo, P., & Agung, J. (2002). Monetary Transmission in Indonesia: An Overview. In P. Warjiyo, & J. Agung, Transmission Mechanisms of Monetary Policy in Indonesia (pp. 7‐26). Jakarta: Bank Indonesia. Warjiyo, P., & Zulverdi, D. (1998). Penggunaan Suku Bunga sebagai Sasaran Operasional Kebijakan Moneter di Indonesia (The Use of Interest Rate as Operational Target of Monetary Policy in Indonesia). Buletin Ekonomi Moneter dan Perbankan, Vol. 1, No. 1, 25‐58. Weber, A. A., Gerke, R., & Worms, A. (2009). Has the Monetary Transmission Process in the Euro Are Changed? Evidence Based on VAR Estimates. BIS Working Papers no. 276. 34 Table 1: Inflation Targeting Countries in the World, 19902008 Notes: Adoption dates are taken from Leyva (2008) Inflation targets are taken from central bank's web pages The middle point of the target is reported when the inflation target is defined as a range If the inflation targeting adoption date is July or later of any year t, the annual date reported is year t+1 E=emerging, I=industrial, S=stationary, and C=converging Source: ShmidtHebbel (2009, p.21) 35 Table 2: Measures of Inflation Deviations from Targets and Inflation Deviations in IT Countries, from IT Starting Quarter through 2008IV Notes: Sample comprises inflation targets and inflation rates from the start of IT in each country until the fourth quarter of 2008 Half-life of an inflation deviation are defined as the number of periods that a given inflation deviation from target takes to converge to one-half its initial value Half-lives are computed asumming that the best autoregressive process for inflation deviations for each country is an AR(1) MAE=Mean absolute error 36 MSE=Mean squared error RMSE=Root mean squared error Source: Shmidt-Hebbel (2009, p.27) 37 Figure 1: Central Bank Transparency Index for Country Groups by Monetary Policy Regimes, 19982006 Note: Transparency index ranges from 0 (least transparent) and 15 (most transparent). Source: Geraats (2008), based on data by Dincer and Eichengreen (2007). Figure 2: Central Bank Transparency Index for Industrial and EME IT Country Groups, 19982005 Note: Transparency index ranges from 0 (least transparent) and 15 (most transparent). Source: Geraats (2008), based on data by Dincer and Eichengreen (2007). 38