Download The Foreign Exchange Market

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Reserve currency wikipedia , lookup

Foreign-exchange reserves wikipedia , lookup

Foreign exchange market wikipedia , lookup

Bretton Woods system wikipedia , lookup

International monetary systems wikipedia , lookup

Fixed exchange-rate system wikipedia , lookup

Exchange rate wikipedia , lookup

Currency intervention wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
In yesterday’s lesson we saw that the market for loanable funds shows us how financial capital flows into or out of a nation’s financial account. Goods and services also flow, but this flow is tracked as balance of payments into and out of the current account. We’ve also learned that a county’s balance of payments on the current account plus its balance of payments on the financial account add up to zero: a country that receives net capital inflow (positive financial account) must run a matching current account deficit, and a country that generates net capital outflow (negative financial account) must run a matching current account surplus
account surplus.
So given that the financial account reflects the movement of capital and the current account reflects the movement of goods and services, what ensures that the balance of payments really does balance? That is, what ensures that the two accounts actually offset each other?
The answer lies in the role of the exchange rate, which is determined in the foreign exchange market.
1
The foreign exchange market is, in fact, not located in any one geographic spot. Rather, it is a global electronic market that traders around the world use to buy and sell currencies.
2
For example, at that time US$1 exchanged for €.93, so it took €.93 o buy $1 Similarly, it took US$1.08 for €1. These two numbers reflect the same rate of exchange between the euro and the US dollar: 1/1.08= .93
When discussing movements in exchange rates, economists use specialized terms to avoid confusion.
Suppose for example that the value of €1 went from $1 to $1 25 which means that the
Suppose, for example, that the value of €1 went from $1 to $1.25, which means that the value of US$1 went from €1 to €0.80 (because 1/1.25=.80). In this case, we would say that the euro appreciated and the US dollar depreciated.
Movement in exchange rates affect the relative prices of goods, services, and assets in different countries. For example, suppose the rice of an American hotel room is $100 and the price of a French hotel room is €100. If the exchange is €1=$1, these hotel rooms have the same price. If the exchange rate is €1.25=$1, the French hotel room is 20% cheaper $
than the American hotel room. If the exchange rate is €0.80=$1, the French hotel room is 25% more expensive than the American hotel room.
3
If I want euros, I demand them. And in order to acquire euros, I must supply dollars to the exchange market. So when Americans demand more euros, they must supply more dollars.
The unit on the x‐axis is the quantity of US dollars supplied and demanded. The unit on the y‐axis is the price of US dollars, measured in euros per dollar.
Note: If you have trouble remembering what goes over what, an easy way to remember how to label the y‐axis
how to label the y
axis is to think of the notation typically used: (foreign currency)/dollar. is to think of the notation typically used: (foreign currency)/dollar
The dollar goes in the denominator or “below” the “/”. The dollars are also the unit on the x‐axis, which is “below” the graph. Think: “What goes below goes below.” If it’s the market for dollars, dollars are on the x‐axis and in the denominator.
Why does the Demand for dollars slope downward?
• As the price of a dollar falls (its value depreciates) it takes fewer euros to buy one dollar
• Consumers in Europe will find US goods to be less expensive
• US exports to Europe will rise, and more dollars will be demanded to pay for those goods
Why does the Supply of dollars slope upward?
• As the price of a dollar rises (its value appreciates) one dollar buys more euros
• Consumers in the US will find European‐made goods to be less expensive
US imports from Europe will rise, and more dollars will be supplied to pay for those
• US imports from Europe will rise, and more dollars will be supplied to pay for those goods
4
The equilibrium exchange rate is €.95 euros per US dollar.
Now, suppose the demand for US dollars increases. Maybe European consumers have more money to spend and some of that additional income is being spent on financial investment in America. The payments from those European citizens will flow into the US financial account. (Draw a rightward shift of the D curve)
As the demand for dollars shifts to the right, the equilibrium price of dollars rises and the As
the demand for dollars shifts to the right the equilibrium price of dollars rises and the
dollar appreciates. It will now cost more than €.95 to buy one US dollar. Because the US dollar has appreciated against the euro, American consumers will increase purchases of goods and services from Europe. More US dollars will be supplied and will flow out of the US current account. Because the quantity of dollars demanded and supplied is the same at the equilibrium exchange rate, the increased quantity of dollars demanded must be equal to the increased quantity of dollars supplied.
This tells us that any increase in the US balance of payments on the financial account is exactly offset by a decrease in the US balance of payments on the current account.
5
The price of imported goods depends on the exchange rate for foreign currencies, but also on the aggregate price level of those nations. To take account of the effects of differences in inflation rates, economists calculate real exchange rates: exchange rates adjusted for international differences in aggregate price levels.
Ex: Suppose that the exchange rate we are looking at is the number of Mexican pesos per US dollar
US dollar.
Let Pus and Pmex be indexes of the aggregate price levels in the United States and Mexico, respectively. Ex. 1: There is no difference in aggregate price levels between the US and Mexico in the base year. Real exchange rate = 12.5 x (100/100) = 12.5 pesos per dollar
Ex. 2: Suppose the Mexican economy has suffered 10% aggregate inflation and Pmex = 110
Real exchange rate = 12.5 x (100/110) = 11.4 pesos per dollar So in real terms, even though the exchange rate hasn’t changed, inflation in Mexico means that each US dollar will buy fewer pesos and thus fewer Mexican goods.
(To distinguish it from the real exchange rate, the exchange rate unadjusted for aggregate (To
distinguish it from the real exchange rate, the exchange rate unadjusted for aggregate
price levels is sometimes called the nominal exchange rate.)
6
7
The purchasing power parity between two countries’ currencies is the nominal exchange rate at which a given basket of goods and services would cost the same amount in each country.
Suppose, for example, that a basket of goods and services that cost $100 in the US costs 1,000 pesos in Mexico. Then the purchasing power parity in 10 pesos per US dollar: at that exchange rate, 1,000 pesos = $100, so the market basket costs the same amount in both countries.
countries
8
9