* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download The Impact of Sovereign Ratings on Eurozone SMEs Credit Rationing
United States housing bubble wikipedia , lookup
Federal takeover of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac wikipedia , lookup
Merchant account wikipedia , lookup
Financialization wikipedia , lookup
Household debt wikipedia , lookup
Syndicated loan wikipedia , lookup
Public finance wikipedia , lookup
Global saving glut wikipedia , lookup
Interest rate ceiling wikipedia , lookup
First Report on the Public Credit wikipedia , lookup
Securitization wikipedia , lookup
Credit rating agencies and the subprime crisis wikipedia , lookup
M PRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Impact of Sovereign Ratings on Eurozone SMEs Credit Rationing Michael Demoussis and Konstantinos Drakos and Nicholas Giannakopoulos University of Patras, Athens University of Economics and Business, University of Patras 2016 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/76364/ MPRA Paper No. 76364, posted 22 January 2017 17:10 UTC The Impact of Sovereign Ratings on Eurozone SMEs Credit Rationing Michael Demoussis, Konstantinos Drakos, and Nicholas Giannakopoulos† Abstract In this study we investigate whether sovereign credit ratings have any discernible impact on credit rationing in Euro zone countries. We utilize firm-level data from the Survey on the Access to Finance of SMEs for the period 2009-2013 conducted by the ECB. A negative association between the rating of sovereign creditworthiness and credit rationing is identified, while credit rationing varies substantially even among countries with the highest quality of sovereign bonds. Credit rationing is lower in sovereigns with high quality ratings and higher in sovereigns near default. These results remain intact when fundamental firm characteristics (e.g. firm’s age and size, sector of economic activity, financial situation etc.) are taken into consideration. This indicates that the interconnection of sovereign debt risk with domestic credit market outcomes is robust. Keywords: Credit rationing; Firms; Sovereign debt; Euro zone JEL Classification: E51; H63; G2; C35 Professor, Department of Economics, University of Patras, Greece. Corresponding author. Email: [email protected], Associate Professor, Department of Accounting and Finance, Athens University of Economics and Business, Greece. † Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, University of Patras, Greece. 1 1. Introduction The presence of asymmetric information between lenders and borrowers, and more importantly the inability of market participants to overcome them, leads to an equilibrium outcome known as credit rationing, where lenders may find it optimal to cut off credit rather than increase loan rates, since the latter may drive off the loan market all but the least creditworthy applicants or elicit riskier behavior from borrowers (Jaffee and Russell, 1976; Stiglitz and Weiss, 1981). The extant empirical literature has shown that smaller and informationally more opaque businesses are typically more harshly hit by credit rationing, due to the amplified adverse selection and moral hazard problems that characterize the lender (bank)-borrower (firm) relationship (Berger and Udell, 1998; Ang, 1991). In practice, quantity (non-price) rationing by lenders can take one of two alternative forms: (i) partially fulfilling loan requests, what is called Type-1 rationing, or (ii) rejecting loan requests altogether, known as Type-2 rationing (Keeton, 1979). In the Stiglitz and Weiss (1981) environment borrowers are credit rationed if they are unable to finance externally, at the current market loan rate, investment projects with positive net present values. However, to fully gauge the borrower-lender relationship one has to also take into account the potential borrowers who choose not to apply, the so-called “discouraged” borrowers, who may arise due to various application costs and/or a self-rationing mechanism (Jappelli, 1990; Mushinski 1999; Kon and Storey, 2003; Chakravarty and Yilmazer, 2008; Han et al., 2009; Brown et al., 2011; Drakos and Giannakopoulos, 2011; Freel et al. 2012; Popov, 2013; Ferrando and Mulier, 2015; Colea and Sokolyk, 2016). Credit rationing may exert detrimental effects on firm investment, employment and survival prospects, especially for small and financially opaque firms (Ang, 1991; Hu and Schiantarelli, 1994; Jensen and McGuckin, 1997; Berger and Udell, 1998; Audretsch and Elston, 2 2002; Chodorow-Reich, 2014; Duygan-Bump, et al., 2015). Despite the extensive literature on the within-country determinants of credit rationing in the euro area (Becchetti et al., 2011; Rottmann and Wollmershaüser, 2013; Kremp and Sevestre, 2013; Farihna and Felix, 2015), there is an apparently limited literature on the phenomenon regarding Euro zone SMEs as a whole (Casey and O’Toole, 2014; Holton et al., 2015; Ferrando et al., 2015).i The latter studies although they provide some empirical evidence regarding the effects of macroeconomic conditions on credit rationing they do not explicitly take into account the potential impact of sovereign risk ratings. The link between sovereign’s ability to repay its debts and the supply of credit in the business sector has recently gained increasing attendance in academia, the financial sector and policy makers. For example, Popov and Horen (2015) analyze the syndicated bank lending channel during the Euro area sovereign debt crisis and found that banks with significant exposures to sovereign debt issued by countries whose access to international bond markets became impaired (Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, and Spain) was on average lower by 21.3 per cent than lending by banks without a significant exposure. In addition, Adelino and Ferreira (2016) show that banks with ratings at the sovereign bound (around default) reduce their lending significantly more than otherwise similar banks whose ratings are not at the sovereign bound following a sovereign downgrade. In the present study, we utilize firm-level data from the Survey on the Access to Finance of SMEs (SAFE, hereafter), covering the period between 1st half of 2009 and October 2012-March 2013, which is a database administered by the European Central Bank in order to exploit the cross-country variation in sovereign bond ratings, which encapsulate the effects of several country-specific macroeconomic fundamentals (e.g., GDP per capita, GDP growth, external debt etc.), as well as other qualitative macroeconomic idiosyncrasies (Cantor and Parker, 1996; Beirne and Fratzscher, 2013). 3 The rationale for conducting the present study relies on the fact that sovereign debt risk is interconnected with domestic banking sector risk (Arteta and Hale, 2008; Gennaioli et al., 2014; Correa et al., 2014). From this point of view to the extent that banks maintain a large exposure to home country sovereign bonds, this interconnection could bring about losses on these portfolios which are expected to weaken their balance sheets (Arezki et al., 2011). In addition, a downgrade of home sovereign’s creditworthiness would erode the collateral value of sovereign bonds that banks usually pledge for wholesale funding, but also for borrowing from the central bank. Moreover, sovereign rating downgrades tend to precede domestic banks' downgrades, given banks' high vulnerability to sovereign distress, compared to domestic firms in other sectors, as well as, by reducing the benefits that banks derive from implicit and explicit government guarantees (Committee on the Global Financial System, 2011). All the above are expected to manifest themselves on a relatively impaired bank access to funding and a higher cost when obtaining it. This has certainly been the case for banks from the peripheral euro area countries for which there is ample evidence that they face higher wholesale and deposit funding costs. Moreover, while the mix of bank funding in the major Euro zone countries has remained rather intact compared to the pre-crisis period, for banks in peripheral countries the funding composition has changed significantly, with customer deposits declining as a share of total assets and increased dependence on central bank liquidity. Hence, it is obvious that these developments are bound to adversely affect bank lending policies in the form of tighter lending terms and conditions and possibly higher rates of credit rationing. It is clear that the Euro zone encompasses countries with sovereign debt problems of varying intensity, and even a cursory look at the raw data shows that for the group of countries with more acute sovereign debt difficulties credit rationing has increased considerably. In contrast, 4 credit rationing seems to have actually eased in Euro zone countries with a perceived sustainable sovereign debt. Perhaps this is a facet of the “flight-to-safety” phenomenon. Thus, as far as credit rationing is concerned, the Euro zone is an amalgamation of countries with heterogeneous profiles. A similar picture emerges in the Euro zone as highlighted by Drakos (2013) who argues that bank lending terms and conditions have become tighter for Greece, Ireland, Portugal and Spain compared to the rest of Euro zone member states. Thus, the presence of the sovereign debt crisis allows -if not compels- the augmentation of credit rationing determinants with potential factors, over and above those that one would employ under normal conditions. In particular, one may advocate that the sovereign debt crisis, at least on a theoretical basis, exerts a detrimental and unambiguous -in terms of direction- impact on credit rationing. In addition, this potential impact may well be non-uniform across countries, given their heterogeneous degrees of involvement in the sovereign debt crisis. The channel via which the sovereign debt crisis may affect firms' credit rationing is indirect and necessarily passes through its impact on banks' loan decision-making process (Jimenez et al., 2012; Bofondi et al., 2013), since after all this process shapes credit rationing. From a methodological point of view the use of matched loan applications and contracts is an ideal research design for studying credit rationing (Banerjee and Duflo, 2014; Kirschenmann, 2016). However, matched data at the firm-level are not available for the majority of Euro zone countries and thus the examination of the effect of the sovereign debt crisis is impossible in terms of exploiting the relevant cross-country variation. In contrast, the use of survey-based dataset is expected to shed more light on this issue. For instance, Casey and O’Toole (2014) use the SAFE dataset (2009-2011) to investigate whether bank lending-constrained SMEs are more likely to use or apply for alternative external finance including trade credit, informal lending, loans from other 5 companies, market financing (issued debt or equity) and state grants. Holton et al. (2015) study the determinants of SMEs’ credit access by combining firm micro data from the ECB’s SAFE survey (2009-2011) with macroeconomic variables focusing on simultaneous crises in the real economy (e.g., gross domestic product and domestic demand), the financial/sovereign market and the effects of private sector indebtedness. Lastly, Ferrando et al. (2015) utilize selected waves of the SAFE dataset (2009-2014) to investigate the effect of sovereign stress and of unconventional monetary policy on small firms’ financing patterns during the euro area debt crisis. Utilizing the SAFE dataset, we define, in the present study credit rationing at the firm-level taking into account the fact that a specific firm may have not applied for a bank loan due to sufficient internal funds. In order to measure country risk we utilize country-level data (eleven Euro zone member states) regarding the sovereign bond ratings by the three most popular rating agencies (Standard & Poor’s, Moody’s and Fitch). The alphanumerical rating corresponds to the rating of the last month of each of the SAFE wave while for analytical purposes it has been transformed to a numerical variable following Mondes et al. (2016, Table 1). For estimation purposes we adopt probit models with sample selection in order to estimate the impact of firmspecific attributes, country-specific effects and time effects on rationing, conditional on firm’s demand for bank loans. As a first step we provide evidence on the determinants of credit rationing at the country level and then we proceed by estimating the effects of sovereign bond ratings on credit rationing for the Euro zone as a whole. Our results indicate that credit rationing exhibits a rather heterogeneous profile across Euro zone SMEs. For example, credit rationing is increasing for young and small firms, for those of single ownership, with lower turnover and deteriorated credit history, with limitations in the availability of credit and for those operating in the services sector. While credit rationing remains stable across the examined period for the Euro zone as a 6 whole, we found that there are significant differences across countries. With regard to risk ratings we found that credit rationing varies significantly amongst firms in the Euro zone, while a negative association between sovereign rating and credit rationing has been uncovered. These indirect effects encompass time invariant differences regarding sovereign credit ratings and changes pertaining to the downgrading of a sovereign’s creditworthiness. The contribution of the present study to the relevant literature is twofold. First, it performs a detailed analysis of credit rationing for Euro zone SMEs and second, it explores the link between sovereign credit rating and credit rationing during the sovereign debt crisis period. In addition, it complements the work of Casey and O’Toole (2014), Holton et al. (2015), and Ferrando et al. (2015) who utilize the SAFE dataset to analyze several aspects of credit constraints in Euro zone SMEs and incorporate macroeconomic variables at the country level to capture possible heterogeneous effects. Our study, in addition, utilizes the widely publicized sovereign risk ratings in order to investigate whether country risk can be associated with higher rationing prevalence. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data and provides the definitions of the variables utilized in the study. We also provide descriptive statistics comparing cross sectional aspects. In Section 3 we present the econometric specification and the empirical strategy for modeling credit rationing. Estimation results and sensitivity analysis are discussed in Section 4. The paper concludes with Section 5 which contains a brief summary of the major findings. 2. Data sources and summary statistics The evidence on the access to finance of enterprises in the European Union was rather scarce due to lack of comparable, timely, and frequent data for SMEs. To fill this gap, the European Central Bank (ECB) and the European Commission (EC) has decided in 2008 to collaborate on designing 7 the Survey on Access to Finance of Enterprises (SAFE)ii which is a cross-sectional survey repeated every six months in order to assess the latest developments in the financing conditions (i.e., financial situation, financing needs and access to financing) for firms in the euro area. The first round of SAFE conducted between 17 June and 23 July 2009 and refer to the financial developments that took place during the 1st half of 2009. Given the onset of the sovereign debt crisis in Euro zone coincides with the 1st round of available micro data on credit market outcomes, we use, in the present study, firm-level data from the 1st round (1st half 2009) of the SAFE database up until the 8th round (October 2012 - March 2013). Since the survey is conducted twice a year (every six months), our sample consists of eight waves. The survey basically covers micro, small and medium-sized firms, based on the level of employment, but also includes a small percentage of large firms (not used in the econometric analysis that follows). Industry-wise, firms belong to the Mining and Manufacturing, Construction, Wholesale or Retail Trade, Transport and Other Services sectors while country-wise Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Netherlands, Portugal and Spain are continuously covered. The initial sample includes information on 53,771 firms and after the exclusion of the sample of large firms we remain with 49,618 valid observations which are allocated in the examined period as follows: 5,129 (1st half 2009), 4,786 (2nd half 2009), 4,906 (March-September 2010), 6,941 (September 2010-February 2011), 6,968 (April-September 2011), 6,969 (October 2011-March 2012), 6,959 (April-September 2012) and 6,960 (October 2012-March 2013). Since the number of firms for each time-country pair varies, the appropriate population weights (provided by the SAFE database) have been applied. 2.1. Measuring credit rationing 8 As discussed earlier, non-price credit rationing may be observed in equilibrium as a result of informational asymmetries between lenders and borrowers. In our analysis we will use the broadest definition of credit rationing (Type 1 and 2) and also take into account discouraged borrowers (firms that did not apply for credit, even though they needed it). The SAFE dataset includes appropriate questions for the identification of credit rationing (questions Q7A.A and Q7B.A of the SAFE questionnaire). In particular, using only valid information (excluding cases with DK/NA answers on Q7A.A and Q7B.A, reducing the working sample size to 48,386 firms) we define the credit rationing variable in the form of a dummy indicator; taking the value 0 when a firm is not rationed, and the value of 1 when rationed, identified as follows: (a) a firm applied for credit and its application was rejected, (b) a firm applied for credit and its demand was partially satisfied, (c) a firm did not apply for credit because of fear of rejection (discouraged borrowers). We should point out that those firms stating that they refused to accept the bank’s loan offer because the interest rate was thought to be too high are not considered to be rationed, since rationing is conditional on the ongoing interest rate (Stiglitz and Weiss, 1981). For analytical purposes we exclude from the analysis those firms that did not apply for bank loans for other reasons and the remaining observations count to 37,394 firms. However, those firms that did not apply for a bank loan because they have sufficient internal funds are considered to be a specific subsample (22,387 observations) that may provide evidence on the self-selection mechanism of firms regarding the demand for bank loans. In order to avoid problems of selectivity biases arising from the fact credit rationing is most likely conditional on the absence of sufficient internal funds (Drakos and Giannakopoulos, 2011) we appropriately include this subsample in our empirical analysis. Given these selection criteria our effective sample contains 15,006 firms of which 6,919 were subjected to rationing (Table 1). Looking at Figure 1 we note that credit rationing 9 in the Euro zone is characterized by remarkable stability (around 46 per cent) and it varies substantially both, between Euro zone countries and within specific countries. [Insert Table 1 here] [Insert Figure 1 here] 2.2. Sovereign bond credit ratings The most popular sovereign bond ratings reviews are conducted and reported by Standard & Poor’s (www.standardandpoors.com), Moody’s (www.moodys.com) and Fitch (www.fitchratings.com). As a rule, sovereign bond ratings are presented in an alphanumerical mode and capture the whole set of sovereign’s bond quality (from the highest quality to default). However, when ratings are included in typical regression analysis most analysts transform the alphanumerical ratings into numerical values (Cantor and Parker, 1996; Reinhart, 2002; Alfonso et al., 2012; Baum et al., 2016; Mondes et al., 2016). In the present study we follow the scaling presented in Mondes et al., (2016) which ranges from 1 (default) to 23 (highest quality). It is worth noting that as far as credit ratings are concerned, the triple-A group of countries (Austria, Finland, Germany, Netherlands) exhibits remarkable stability while this is not the case for the non-triple-A countries. In the examined period, the majority of the Euro zone countries witnessed downgrading of their creditworthiness at least once. For example, according to Moody’s, France lost its Aaa rating in November of 2012 while Belgium and Spain were downgraded once moving from Aa1 to Aa3 and Aa2, respectively. Italy was also downgraded once albeit by three notches, moving from Aa2 to A2. Portugal was downgraded twice, starting from Aa3 in 2009 and ending at A3 in the 1st semester of 2011. Greece's credit rating was downgraded three times and while it was assessed as A2 in 2009, it reached B1 in the 1st semester of 2011 and C in the 1st semester of 2012. Finally, Ireland started as a triple-A country and then experienced a sequence of four downgrades and 10 ended up rated as Baa3 in the 2nd semester of 2011. A visual display of the relative position of the creditworthiness of Euro zone countries at the beginning (January 2009) and the end (January 2013) of the examined period is presented in Figure 2. [Insert Figure 2 here] Furthermore, the relationship between credit rationing and Moody’s ratings is negative (see Figure 3) indicating that as rating deteriorates (improves) credit rationing increases (decreases). According to the raw data, credit rationing in triple-A countries stood at 32.9 per cent, in Ba1 countries at 66.2 per cent and in Greece (the only C country) at 84.4 per cent. Also, credit rationing is not stable across time. For instance, credit rationing for Ba1 countries ranges from 54.0 per cent in wave 6 to 81 per cent in wave 7. Furthermore, credit rationing on average for triple-A countries is continuously decreasing after the second half of 2009. [Insert Figure 3 here] 2.3. Firm-specific heterogeneity Given that -in the presence of informational asymmetries- price (loan rate) is not an effective credit allocation mechanism, lenders must resort to some observed borrower characteristics in order to reach a decision on the fate of the loan application. It should be clear that rationing is negatively linked to the capacity of market forces to circumvent information asymmetries. The empirical literature on the demand and supply of credit at the firm level identifies a wide range of explanatory variables that might affect credit rationing, conditional on the demand for bank loans. These variables typically include firm size, ownership, legal status, financing needs (short-term and longterm), availability of internal resources, interest expenses, financial and non-financial risk indicators, such as leverage, profitability, firm’s age, firm’s rating and firm’s ability to provide collateral (Freel et al., 2012; Kremp and Sevestre, 2013; Rottmann and Wollmershäuser, 2013; 11 Farinha and Felix, 2015; Carbo-Valverde et al., 2016; Kirschenmann, 2016). The SAFE database includes information on a variety of firm-specific (borrower) characteristics which could be useful for the construction of variables that are usually employed in empirical studies as credit rationing determinants. In particular, we utilize indicators for basic firm characteristics (ageiii, firm sizeiv, ownership status and sector of economic activity) and information on the direction of change of firm’s financial conditions and performance (turnover, profits, credit history, net interest expenses, debt to assets ratio)v. Missing observations on any of these variables are deleted and the final working sample counts to 30,555 firms. The total number of firms that are not subject to selfselection is 13,377 and the remaining 17,718 firms did not applied for bank loan because of sufficient internal funds. Summary statistics for the utilized variables are present at Table 2, separately for the rationed and non-rationed sub-samples. We observe that rationed firms (compared to not rationed) are younger and smaller in size, single owned, have lower probabilities of increased turnover and profitability, have lower chances of improved credit history, face increased net interest expenses and higher debt to assets ratio and lower credit availability. Lastly, firms in manufacturing seem to face less rationing while those in the construction sector are considered to be more rationed. [Insert Table 2 here] 3. Empirical strategy In this section we present the adopted empirical strategy in order to identify the effects of sovereign bond ratings on credit rationing. Initially, we estimate country specific credit rationing regressions in an attempt to understand the factors that explain the within-country credit rationing variation. Then we proceed with estimates at the Euro zone level and we focus on the impact of sovereign bond ratings on credit rationing. 12 3.1. The determinants of credit rationing In order to estimate rationing elasticities with respect to firm specific attributes we employ models of the form: 𝑅𝑖𝑡 = 𝛽𝑋𝑖𝑡 + 𝑓𝑡 + 𝜀𝑖𝑡 (1) where, 𝑅𝑖𝑡 is the credit rationing indicator for firm 𝑖 observed in period 𝑡, 𝑋𝑖𝑡 is a set of observed characteristics of firm 𝑖 (e.g., firm’s age, firm’s size, sector of economic activity, etc.), 𝑓𝑡 are unrestricted intercepts for different time periods, and 𝜀𝑖𝑐𝑡 is an error term. One potential source of bias in the estimation of the credit rationing equation relates to the selective nature of the “credit approval” procedure. Essentially, one needs to keep in mind that in our identification process of the credit rationed firms, those firms which have sufficient internal funds do not participate in the credit approval procedure. In other words, a firm with sufficient internal funds who did not apply for a loan, could not be classified as rationed or not-rationed. Therefore, if there were common factors influencing the demand for a bank loan and the credit rationing mechanism, then the estimated effect of these factors on rationing -without taking into account firms that did not need a loan would be biased. Thus, equation (1) is a probit model with sample selection (Cameron and Trivedi, 2005) where the selection equation relates to whether a firm reports that the reason for not applying for a bank loan is the sufficiency of its internal funds. 3.2. Credit rationing and sovereign bond ratings In order to estimate rationing elasticities with respect to sovereign bond ratings we employ models of the form: 𝑅𝑖𝑐𝑡 = 𝛼𝛢𝑐𝑡 + 𝛽𝑋𝑖𝑐𝑡 + 𝑑𝑐 + 𝑓𝑡 + 𝜀𝑖𝑐𝑡 (2) 13 where, 𝑅𝑖𝑐𝑡 is the credit rationing indicator for firm 𝑖 observed in country 𝑐 in period 𝑡, 𝛢𝑐𝑡 is the sovereign rating in country 𝑐 in period 𝑡, 𝑋𝑖𝑐𝑡 is a set of observed characteristics of firm 𝑖 (e.g., firm’s age, firm’s size, sector of economic activity, etc.), 𝑑𝑐 and 𝑓𝑡 are unrestricted intercepts for different country and time periods, and 𝜀𝑖𝑐𝑡 is an error term. In equation (2) we assume that the effect of rating on rationing in the Euro zone is linear. Alternative assumptions (up to fourth-order polynomials) will also be utilized later. The realization that the sovereign debt rating variable in equation (2) has no "𝑖" subscript has two important implications. The first refers to its effect on credit rationing (fixed effect) and the second to the estimated standard error. Specifically, firms located in the same country may share some common components of variance not entirely attributable either to their measured characteristics (𝑋𝑖𝑐𝑡 ) or to the sovereign debt rating (𝛢𝑐𝑡 ). In this case, the error components 𝜀𝑖𝑐𝑡 will be positively correlated across firms from the same country, and the conventional formula for the estimated standard error of the sovereign debt rating effect will be significantly downward biased. This means that the rationing elasticities are far less precisely estimated than their typical t-ratios would suggest. To overcome this problem we correct for common variance components within groups of firms by clustering the standard errors at country and time levels (Moulton, 1990). The inclusion of year and country dummies in equation (2) is of great importance. For instance, the implicit assumption underlying a possible exclusion of country dummies is that credit rationing responds to the "transitory" and "permanent" components of sovereign credit rating with the same intensity. In contrast, the inclusion of country-specific fixed effects allows the permanent component of credit rationing to have an arbitrary correlation with the permanent component of sovereign bond ratings and, in addition, uses only the deviations (transitory component) of credit rationing and sovereign ratings from their respective average values, to estimate the rationing 14 elasticity. For the Euro zone this matters, because average sovereign bond ratings across memberstates are negatively correlated with the average credit rationing rates (see Figure 3 where credit rationing is decreasing as ratings deteriorate). This correlation pertains to both, permanent and transitory components of credit rationing and sovereign ratings. As a result the Euro zone rationing elasticity tends to be larger when country dummies are excluded. If country dummies did not exerted an effect on the estimated rationing elasticities, then one could assert that "permanence" in the geographic patterns of sovereign rating dominates. This exercise serves the purpose of uncovering econometric evidence for the presence (or absence) of transitory shocks regarding the effect of sovereigns' creditworthiness on credit rationing. 4. Empirical results 4.1 Cross-country credit rationing estimates Table 3 reports the estimation results (corrected for sample selection) regarding the impact of the explanatory variables on credit rationing for each country separately. Three sources of heterogeneity are controlled for: (a) firm-specific attributes and sectoral dummies (proxies for the demand side), (b) firm’s perception regarding banks’ willingness to provide loans (proxy for for supply side) and (c) time-period effects (exogenous shocks). With the exception of Austria, Finland, Greece and Portugal, the age of the firm appears to be a significant correlate and in particular as the age of the firm increases the probability of rationing decreases. The size of the firm is also important (except Finland) and has a negative effect on credit rationing. In Germany, Ireland and Italy, single ownership of the firm is associated with increased rationing. Changes in firms' turnover does not seem to play a role in credit rationing with the exception of Greece, Ireland and Italy. In the cases of Greece and Italy firms with increased turnover report lower credit 15 rationing while in Ireland there is a weak evidence (at the 10 per cent level of statistical significance) of a positive correlation between increased turnover and credit rationing. Firm profitability is correlated with rationing only for the case of Greece. The credit history of a firm seems to be inversely related to credit rationing in the case of Austria and Spain. Firms with increased net interest expenses are more rationed in Belgium, Finland, France, Greece, Italy and Spain. When the debt to assets ratio increases the probability of rationing is higher in Belgium and Spain and lower in the case of Finland. When the credit availability is improved the likelihood of credit rationing decreases in all countries with the exception of Austria where the effect is not different from zero in statistical terms. With regard to the effects of the sector of economic activity we found that credit rationing is higher in manufacturing firms in Austria and France and in the construction sector in Italy and Spain. In contrast lower rationing is observed in wholesale and retail trade firms in Ireland and Netherlands. Regarding the time effects, we observe that -on average- credit rationing has increased since the 1st half of 2009 in France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Netherlands and Spain but this time effect is of different magnitude and not linear in all cases. The correlation between the two equations (whether a firm has sufficient internal funds and whether a firm is rationed) is statistically significant and according to the Wald test the null hypothesis regarding the exclusion of all explanatory variables in the credit rationing equation is rejected in the case of Belgium, France, Ireland and Netherlands.vi In addition, there are substantial differences in the predicted probability of rationing across countries independently of the rating in sovereign risk. For example, significant differences in the predicted probability of rationing appear to be present in triple-A countries (.236 in Austria, .182 in Finland, .310 in Germany, and .682 in the Netherlands). Thus, credit rationing differences have been observed even among countries with 16 the highest quality of sovereign bonds during the recent sovereign debt crisis. Overall, credit rationing varies substantially in the Euro zone, and moreover it exhibits different time paths in the examined period. This implies that country risk, captured through the sovereign debt risk ratings is expected to exert a negative effect on credit rationing over and above the firm-specific attributes of Euro zone SMEs. [Insert Table 3 here] 4.2. The impact of sovereign bond ratings on credit rationing Table 4 presents the estimation results (marginal effects) of four alternative model specifications regarding the impact of sovereign credit rating on credit rationing. In Column 1 we present our benchmark model which refers to the empirical model described by equation (2) for the pooled sample of Euro zone SMEs without controlling for the effects of the sovereign bond rating. Columns 2, 3 and 4 include estimates for the full specification of equation (2) which takes into account the ratings of the Standard & Poor’s, Moody’s and Fitch, respectively. With regards to the results presented in Column 1 we observe that firms older than 10 years have 9.5 percentage points higher probability of credit rationing compared to firms aged 10 years or less. In addition, the probability of credit rationing is higher for small firms (i.e., with 10-49 employees) and medium firms (i.e., those with 50-249 employees) by 12.3 and 17.6 percentage points, respectively (compared to micro firms, i.e., with 1-9 employees). When the owner of the firm is a single person the probability of rationing is higher by 4.7 percentage points compared to firms with more than one owners (firms, businesses, family enterprises etc.). For firms with improved credit history over the past 6 months the probability of credit rationing is lower by 3.2 percentage points compared to those with unchanged/deteriorated credit history. Firms with increased net interest expenses have 17 6.9 percentage points higher probability of credit rationing relative to firms with unchanged/decreased net interest expenses. When the firm considers that the credit availability regarding bank’s willingness to provide loans is improved over the past 6 months the probability of credit rationing is 26.0 percentage points lower than firms with unchanged/deteriorated credit availability. In addition, firms have 3.2 percentage points lower probability of credit rationing in the wholesale/retail trade sector compared to firms operating in the services sector. Credit rationing seems to incorporate significant time and country effects throughout the examined period. Using the first quarter of 2009 as the reference period, we found that credit rationing is increasing in subsequent semesters, reaching a peak in the period April 2012September 2012. In addition, credit rationing seems to be higher for firms operating in all countries (using Austria as the reference group) with the exception of Finland. However, the magnitude of the country-effects varies across countries with Ireland, Netherlands and Greece to witness the highest extent of credit rationing. To the extent that the country risk factor (i.e., sovereign debt ratings) is positively correlated with country and time indicators we expect that its inclusion in the empirical models will result in lower estimates of these indicators. The inclusion of the Standard & Poor’s rating (Column 2) indicates that firms operating in countries with high quality ratings face lower probabilities of credit rationing. For instance, when the rating increases by one point in the scale 1 to 23, then the probability of credit rationing for the typical firm in the Euro zone decreases by 2.0 percentage points. It should be noted that in this model specification (compared with the benchmark model presented at Column 1) the effects of firm-specific variables remain practically intact, both in magnitude and statistical significance. However, differences appear in the estimated effects of the time and country indicators. We observe that the inclusion of the Standard and Poor’s rating resulted in smaller estimated time 18 effects for the period April 2011-March 2013 while for the period January 2009-Febraury 2011 these effects are the same as those presented in Column 1. This implies that the behavior of credit rationing in the Euro zone exhibits a time variation independent of the effect of sovereign rating only for a specific sub-period (January 2009-Febraury 2011) while afterwards (April 2011-March 2013) credit rationing seems to be correlated with specific time effects. The inclusion of the sovereign debt rating is associated with significant reductions in the effects of the country indicators. For example, the magnitude of the country effects is reduced in the case of Spain, Greece, Ireland and Portugal but continue to exert a statistically significant impact on credit rationing. In the case of Belgium and Italy the effects have also been reduced but now they are not statistically different than zero while the effects of Germany, Finland, France and Netherlands remain unchanged. Thus, credit rationing (a) in Austria, Belgium and France appears to be exclusively due to firm-specific attributes and sovereign debt ratings, (b) in Greece, Ireland, Portugal and Spain due to firm-specific attributes, sovereign debt ratings and country specific idiosyncrasies and (c) in Germany, Finland, France and Netherlands due to firm-specific attributes and country specific idiosyncrasies. Pretty much the same results were obtained when we utilized the Moody’s and Fitch ratings (Columns 3 and 4, respectively). Overall, our results suggest that credit rationing encompasses two distinct effects regarding the impact of sovereign ratings on credit rationing: a permanent and a transitory one. Permanent differences are captured by country dummies while transitory differences (i.e., short-run deviations of the rating variable from its longrun mean) by the autonomous effect of the rating variable on credit rationing. [Insert Table 4 here] 4.3. Predicted probabilities of credit rationing for types of sovereign bonds 19 Table 4 presents estimated probabilities of credit rationing, conditional on the firm’s need for bank loans for different types of sovereign bond ratings (all three rating agencies are considered). In this case, we adopt equation (2) and instead of using numerical ratings we utilize 5 groups of sovereign ratings (Alfonso et al., 2012, Table 1) i.e., “highest/high quality”, “strong payment capacity”, “adequate payment capacity”, “likely to fulfil obligations” and “high/very high credit risk/near default/ default”. The obtained results suggest again that credit rationing is higher for firms operating in countries with increased credit risk for any of the three rating agencies. The estimated conditional probabilities are very close regarding the Moody’s and Fitch ratings while the credit rationing probabilities seem to be lower for the ratings of Standard & Poor’s and in particular for the cases of high credit risk and near default. Overall, the obtained results indicate rather clearly that firm-specific credit rationing is higher for firms operating in countries with bonds of speculative grade. [Insert Table 5 here] 5. Conclusions The objective of the present study was to investigate credit rationing across firms in Euro zone countries and its relation to sovereign credit ratings, and to explain the observed credit rationing differentials between all possible pairs of Euro zone countries. Towards this end, we utilized firmlevel data, drawn from the European Central Bank Survey on the Access to Finance of SMEs covering the period between the 1st half of 2009 and October 2012-March 2013. Given our capacity to identify directly whether a firm is credit rationed or not, we were able to compare the degree of credit rationing amongst firms in the Euro zone and to test whether the existing differences are attributed to firm, country and time specific sources. According to our results, credit 20 rationing varies substantially between Euro zone countries. Incorporating in the econometric analysis of credit rationing the potential impact of sovereign ratings, an unambiguous negative association has been uncovered. This relationship is found to be robust under different model assumptions regarding the relationship between the demand for bank loans and credit rationing. However, this association is non-linear and indirect. In particular, credit rationing is higher for firms operating in countries that are rated lower in the scale of sovereign bond ratings and increasing for firms operating in sovereigns who have been subjected to downgrading, reflecting country-related idiosyncratic reasons. The present study enriches the relevant literature, which suggests that that the ongoing sovereign debt crisis in the Euro zone has affected credit markets and primarily the supply of credit in periphery countries through the bank balance-sheet channel (Jimenez et al., 2012; Bofondi et al., 2013). Nevertheless, credit rationing differences have been observed even among countries with the highest quality of sovereign bonds during the recent sovereign debt crisis indicating that credit rationing may be affected by bank balance-sheet risk valuations unrelated to sovereign debt. The findings of the present paper regarding the correlations between credit rationing and country, time and firm specific attributes should not be interpreted as causal ones. For instance, the casual effect of a major event in the credit market, cannot be ascertained with the data at hand since there are certain time specific events (and/or country-specific) that occurred in the examined period and may have led to changes in the path of credit rationing. Such events are associated with a country's deterioration of credit ratings, and might include the launch of a bailout program and/or austerity policies, bank recapitalizations and reforms, etc. These events or a subset of them could be observed concurrently (running on a common trend) making the task of isolating and thus 21 identifying their impact on credit rationing difficult or impossible. Future research should focus further on these identification issues. According to our results, the incidence of credit rationing in the Euro zone is partly associated with country specific idiosyncrasies which can be captured by credit rating assessments. Thus, from a macroeconomic point of view observed credit rationing at a given point in time could be an equilibrium outcome. However, this outcome encompasses significant informational asymmetries which can play an important role in the re-allocation of credit within Euro zone firms. For example, firms of different size face different access to the credit market. Thus, differences in the distribution of firm size within the Euro zone are associated with differences in credit rationing. From a policy perspective, a reduction of credit rationing differences between countries in the Euro zone will require the convergence of firm characteristics which however is not feasible in the short term -if at all- and thus differences in credit rationing are expected to be a permanent phenomenon. In any case, fundamental firm characteristics (e.g. firm’s age and size, sector of economic activity, financial situation etc.) are able to explain the observed credit rationing differentials amongst firms in the Euro zone. In addition, domestic credit market outcomes are interconnected with sovereign debt risk. 22 Acknowledgments This paper uses data from the EC/ECB Survey on the access to finance of SME's for which a confidentiality declaration has been signed. 23 References Adelino, M. and Ferreira, A.M. (2016), “Bank ratings and lending supply: evidence from sovereign downgrades”, Review of Financial Studies, doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhw004. Afonso, A. Furceri, D. and Gomes, P. (2012), “Sovereign credit ratings and financial markets linkages: application to European data”, Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 31(3), pp. 606-638. Ang, J. (1991), “Small business uniqueness and the theory of financial management”, Journal of Small Business Finance, Vol. 1, pp. 1-13. Arteta, C. and Hale, G. (2008), “Sovereign debt crises and credit to the private sector”, Journal of International Economics, Vol. 74(1), pp. 53–69. Arezki, R. Candelon, B. and Sy, A. (2011), “Sovereign rating news and financial markets spillovers: evidence from the European debt crisis”, IMF Working Paper 11/68, International Monetary Fund. Audretsch, D. and Elston, J. (2002), “Does firm size matters? Evidence on the impact of liquidity constraints on firm investment”, International Journal of Industrial Organization, Vol. 20, pp. 116. Banerejee, A.V. and Duflo, E. (2014), “Do firms want to borrow more? Testing credit constraints using a directed lending program”, Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 81, pp. 572–607. Baum, F.C. Schäfer, D. and Stephan, A. (2016), “Credit rating agency downgrades and the Eurozone sovereign debt crises”, Journal of Financial Stability, Vol. 24, pp. 117–131. Becchetti, L. Garcia M.M. and Trovato, G. (2011), “Credit rationing and credit view: Empirical evidence from an ethical Bank in Italy”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 43, pp. 12171245. Beck, T. Degryse, H. De Haas, R. and Van Horen, N. (2014), “When arm's length is too far: Relationship banking over the business cycle” CentER Discussion Paper Series 42. Berger, A. and Udell, G. (1995), “Relationship lending and lines of credit in small business finance”, Journal of Business, Vol. 68(3), pp. 351-381. Beirne, J. and Fratzscher, M. (2013), “The pricing of sovereign risk and contagion during the European sovereign debt crisis”, Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 34, pp. 60–82. Bofondi, M. Carpinelli, L. and Sette, E. (2013), “Credit supply during a sovereign debt crisis”, Banca D' Italia, Working Paper No. 909. 24 Boocock, G. and Woods, M. (1997), “The evaluation criteria used by venture capitalists: evidence from a UK venture fund”, International Small Business Journal, Vol. 16, pp. 36-57. Brown, M., Ongena, S. Popov, A. and Yesin, P. (2011), “Who needs credit and who gets credit in Eastern Europe?” Economic Policy, Vol. 26(65), pp. 93–130. Cameron, A.C. and Trivedi, P.K. (2005), Microeconometrics: Methods and Applications. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Cantor, R. and Packer, F. (1996), “Determinants and impact of sovereign credit ratings”, FRBNY Economic Policy Review, October, pp. 37-54. Carbo-Valverde, S. Rodríguez, F. and Udell, G. (2016), “Trade credit, the financial crisis and firms access to finance”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 48, pp. 113–143. Casey, E. and O'Toole, C.M. (2014), “Bank lending constraints, trade credit and alternative financing during the financial crisis: Evidence from European SMEs”, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 27, pp. 173–193. Chakravarty, S. and Yilmazer, T. (2009), “A multistage model of loans and the role of relationships”, Financial Management, Vol. 38(4), pp. 781-816. Chodorow-Reich, G. (2014), “The employment effects of credit market disruptions: Firm-level evidence from the 2008-09 financial crisis”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 129, pp. 1-59. Colea, R. and Sokolyk, T. (2016), “Who needs credit and who gets credit? Evidence from the surveys of small business finances”, Journal of Financial Stability, Vol. 24, pp. 40-60. Correa, R. Lee, K-H. Sapriza, H. and Suarez, A.G. (2014), “Sovereign credit risk, banks’ government support, and bank stock returns around the world”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 46, pp. 93-121. Committee on the Global Financial System. (2011), “The impact of sovereign credit risk on bank funding conditions”, Bank for International Settlements, Paper No 43. Cressy, R. (1996), “Are business startups credit rationed?”, Economic Journal, Vol. 106, pp. 12531270. Diamond, D. (1991), “Monitoring and reputation: the choice between bank loans and directly placed debt”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 99, pp. 688-721. Drakos, K. and Giannakopoulos, N. (2011), “A microeconometric analysis of credit rationing in transition countries”, Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 30, pp. 1779-1790. Drakos, K. (2013), “Bank loan terms and conditions for Eurozone SMEs”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 41, pp. 717–732. 25 Duygan-Bump, B. Levkov, A. and Montoriol-Garriga, J. (2015), “Financing constraints and unemployment: evidence from the Great Recession”, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 75, pp. 89–105. Farihna, L. and Felix, S. (2015), “Credit rationing for Portuguese SMEs”, Finance Research Letters, Vol. 14, pp. 167–177. Ferrando, A. and Mulier, K. (2015), “The real effects of credit constraints: evidence from discouraged borrowers in the euro area”, European Central Bank WP 1842. Ferrando, A. Popov, A. and Udell F.G. (2015), “Sovereign stress, unconventional monetary policy, and SME access to finance”, European Central Bank WP 1820. Freel, M. Carter, S. Tagg, S. and Mason, C. (2012), “The latent demand for bank debt: characterizing discouraged borrowers”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 38, pp. 399–418. Gennaioli, N. Martin, A. and Rossi, S. (2014), “Sovereign default, domestic banks and financial institutions”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 69(2), pp. 819-866. Gertler, M. and Gilchrist, S. (1994), “Monetary policy, business cycles and the behavior of small manufacturing firms”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 109, pp. 309-340. Gilchrist, S. and Himmelberg, D. (1995), “Evidence on the role of cash flow for investment”, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 36, pp. 541-572. Han, L. Fraser, S. and Storey, D.J. (2009), “Are good or bad borrowers discouraged from applying for loans? Evidence from US small business credit markets”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 33(2), pp. 415–424. Holton, S. Lawless, M. and McCann, F. (2014), “Firm credit in the euro area: a tale of three crises”, Applied Economics, Vol. 46, pp. 190-211. Hu, X. and Schiantarelli, F. (1994), “Investment and financing constraints: a switching regression approach using US firm panel data”, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 80, pp. 466-479. Hubbard, G. (1990), “Capital-market imperfections and investment”, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 36, pp. 193-225. Jaffee, D. and Russell, T. (1976), “Imperfect information, uncertainty, and credit rationing”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 90(4), pp. 651-666. Jappelli, T. (1990), “Who is credit constrained in the U.S. economy?”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 105, pp. 219-234. 26 Jensen, J. and McGuckin, R. (1997), “Firm performance and evolution: empirical regularities in the US microdata”, Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol. 6, pp. 25-47. Jimenez, G. Ongena, S. Peydro, J-L. and Saurina, J. (2012), “Credit supply and monetary policy: identifying the bank balance-sheet channel with loan applications”, American Economic Review, Vol. 102(5), pp. 2301-2326. Keeton, W. (1979), Equilibrium Credit Rationing, Garland Press, New York. Kirschenmann K. (2016), “Credit rationing in small firm-bank relationships”, Journal of Financial Intermediation, Vol. 26, pp. 68-99. Kremp, E. and Sevestre, P. (2013), “Did the crisis induce credit rationing for French SMEs?”, Journal of Banking & Finance, Vol. 37, pp. 3757-3772. Kon, Y. and Storey, D. (2003), “A theory of discouraged borrowers”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 21(1), pp. 37-49. Merton, R. (1974), “On the pricing of corporate debt: The risk structure of interest rates”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 29(2), pp. 449-70. Montes, G. Oliveira, D. and de Mendonça, H.F. (2016), “Sovereign credit ratings in developing economies: New empirical assessment”, International Journal of Finance & Economics, DOI: 10.1002/ijfe.1551. Moulton, B. R. (1990), “An illustration of a pitfall in estimating the effects of aggregate variables in micro units”, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 72(2), pp. 334-338. Mushinski, D. (1999), “An analysis of offer functions of banks and credit unions in Guatemala”, Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 36(2), pp. 87-111. Petersen, M.A. and Rajan, R. (1994), “The benefits of lending relationships: Evidence from small business data”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 49, pp. 3-37. Popov, A. (2013), “Monetary policy, bank capital, and credit supply: A role for discouraged and informally rejected firms”, European Central Bank WP 1593. Popov, A. and Van Horen, N. (2015). “Exporting sovereign stress: Evidence from syndicated bank lending during the Euro area sovereign debt crisis”, Review of Finance, Vol. 19, pp. 1825-1866. Popov, A. and Udell, G. (2012), “Cross-border banking, credit access, and the financial crisis”, Journal of International Economics, Vol. 87, pp. 147-161. Reinhart, C. (2002), “Default, currency crises, and sovereign credit ratings”, World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 16(2), pp. 151-170. 27 Rottmann, H. and Wollmershäuser, T. (2013), “A micro data approach to the identification of credit crunches”, Applied Economics, Vol. 45, pp. 2423-2441. Stiglitz, J. and Weiss, A. (1981), “Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information”, American Economic Review, Vol. 71, pp. 393-410. Vijverberg, C. (2004), “An empirical financial accelerator model: Small firms’ investment and credit rationing”, Journal of Macroeconomics, Vol. 26, pp. 101-129. 28 Source: SAFE (First half 2009-October 2012-March 2013). Figure 1 Credit rationing in Euro zone and by country across survey periods 29 Source: Standard & Poor's. Source: Moody's. Source: Fitch. Figure 2 Sovereign bond ratings in Euro zone (2009 and 2013) 30 Source: SAFE (First half 2009-October 2012-March 2013) and ratings from the websites of Standard & Poor’s, Moody’s and Fitch. Notes: The correlation coefficient between credit rationing and sovereign bond ratings for Standard & Poor’s, Moody’s and Fitch is -.601, -.650 and -.647, respectively. Figure 3 Credit rationing and Moody's ratings in Euro zone SMEs 31 Table 1. Summary statistics on credit rationing Number of firms Frequency (%) Did not apply for a bank loan Did not apply because of sufficient internal funds 22387 Rationed firms Did not apply because of possible rejection (discouraged) 3103 44.8 Applied and partially satisfied 2327 33.6 Applied but was rejected 1489 21.5 A: Total 6919 100.0 Not Rationed firms Applied and got everything 7772 96.1 Applied but refused because cost too high 315 3.9 B: Total 8087 100.0 Credit rationed firms: [A/(A+B)] 46.1 Source: SAFE (First half 2009-October 2012-March 2013). Notes: Numbers are based on the responses in questions Q7A and Q7B of the SAFE questionnaire referring to bank loan (new or renewal). 32 Table 2. Distribution of firm-specific attributes between not rationed and rationed firms in Euro zone Variables Not rationed Rationed Firm’s age Age less than 10 years 24.11 32.75 Age 10 years or more 75.89 67.25 Firm-size From 1 employee to 9 employees 33.42 53.15 From 10 employees to 49 employees 33.73 27.56 From 50 employees to 249 employees 32.84 19.29 Ownership A natural person, one owner only 24.65 29.35 Other entities 75.35 70.65 Turnover Turnover increased 37.99 26.43 Turnover unchanged/decreased 62.01 73.57 Profits Profits increased 23.81 15.91 Profits unchanged/decreased 76.19 84.09 Firm’s credit history Credit history improved 24.46 14.96 Credit history unchanged/deteriorated 75.54 85.04 Net interest expenses Net interest expenses increased 43.39 55.53 Net interest expenses unchanged/decreased 56.61 44.47 Debt to assets ratio Debt to assets ratio increased 33.69 40.29 Debt to assets ratio unchanged/decreased 66.31 59.71 Banks’ willingness to provide a loan (Credit availability) Improved 16.34 4.11 Unchanged/deteriorated 83.66 95.89 Sector of economic activity Manufacturing 19.79 15.96 Construction 10.69 13.90 Whole sale/retail trade 19.59 19.29 Services 49.92 50.85 Observations 7240 6137 Source: SAFE (First half 2009-October 2012-March 2013). Notes: Other entities include Public shareholders, Family or entrepreneurs, Other firms or business associates, Venture capital firms or business angels, Other. Data have been weighted using population weights. 33 Table 3. Determinants of credit rationing Austria Belgium Finland France Germany Greece -.046 -.127** -.111 -.137*** -.138*** -.043 (.050) (.051) (.083) (.031) (.036) (.057) Firm size: 10-49 employees -.088 -.145*** -.037 -.150*** -.169*** -.069 (.057) (.045) (.051) (.035) (.037) (.057) Firm size: 50-249 employees -.186*** -.158 .004 -.221*** -.256*** -.160** (.057) (.057) (.063) (.037) (.037) (.064) Single owner .055 .032 .015 .020 .054* -.075 (.045) (.049) (.058) (.028) (.029) (.060) Turnover increased -.027 -.057 -.007 -.043 .001 -.138** (.045) (.055) (.048) (.029) (.031) (.067) Profits increased -.055 -.015 -.029 -.028 .009 .168** (.047) (.060) (.054) (.033) (.034) (.083) Credit history improved -.091** -.002 -.035 -.007 -.048 .076 (.046) (.052) (.074) (.034) (.030) (.071) Net interest expenses increased .075 .082* .146** .137*** .015 .161** (.047) (.048) (.063) (.026) (.029) (.047) Debt to assets ratio increased .037 .085* -.078* .017 .006 .056 (.050) (.046) (.042) (.025) (.033) (.053) Credit availability improved -.084 -.266*** -.168*** -.242*** -.179*** -.536*** (.063) (.042) (.051) (.030) (.034) (.129) Manufacturing .127** -.017 .024 .095*** -.005 -.014 (.060) (.058) (.065) (.032) (.031) (.065) Construction .052 -.003 .002 -.041 .028 -.060 (.075) (.062) (.069) (.039) (.042) (.095) Whole sale/retail trade -.062 .023 -.045 -.044 -.037 -.042 (.045) (.050) (.064) (.028) (.035) (.058) 2nd half 2009 .115 .247** -.041 .060 .103** .208 (.127) (.120) (.187) (.043) (.045) (.146) March 2010- September 2010 -.043 .043 .033 .154*** .112** .320** (.107) (.124) (.212) (.051) (.047) (.127) September 2010- February 2011 .023 -.071 .055 .151*** .194*** .273*** (.090) (.093) (.184) (.049) (.047) (.101) April 2011- September 2011 -.073 .032 -.121 .221*** .111** .245** (.090) (.097) (.172) (.047) (.053) (.112) October 2011- March 2012 -.063 -.008 .007 .164*** .007 .315*** (.090) (.095) (.174) (.047) (.051) (.103) April 2012- September 2012 -.060 -.047 -.077 .184*** .016 .413*** (.094) (.093) (.174) (.045) (.053) (.110) October 2012- March 2013 .029 .022 .001 .213*** -.085* .461*** (.097) (.094) (.176) (.048) (.044) (.102) Wald-test (Rho=0) 1.96 2.92* .38 5.41** .35 .01 [p-value] [.162] [.087] [.533] [.020] [.554] [.941] Predicted probability (conditional) .236 .330 .182 .334 .310 .684 Number of firms (total) 1817 1990 1615 4835 4322 1588 Number of firms (uncensored) 1254 1195 1229 2572 2758 594 Number of firms (censored) 563 795 386 2263 1564 994 Source: SAFE (First half 2009-October 2012-March 2013). Notes: Reported estimates are conditional marginal effects drawn from probit models with sample selection. The dependent variable is the dummy indicator as presented in Table 1. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Reference groups: Firm size 1-9 employees, Services sector and 1st half 2009. Sampling weights have used. Statistical significance: *<.10, **<.05, ***<.01. Age more than 10 34 Table 3 (continued). Determinants of credit rationing Ireland Italy Netherlands Portugal Spain Age more than 10 -.091* -.066* -.096** -.070 -.087*** (.054) (.035) (.048) (.059) (.026) Firm size: 10-49 employees -.094* -.118*** -.142*** -.168*** -.079*** (.053) (.032) (.050) (.056) (.026) Firm size: 50-249 employees -.173*** -.113*** -.196*** -.088 -.068** (.066) (.033) (.061) (.064) (.027) Single owner .080* .090** .059 .008 -.013 (.045) (.039) (.047) (.073) (.030) Turnover increased .106* -.058 -.079* -.026 -.032 (.058) (.036) (.047) (.059) (.034) Profits increased -.049 .054 -.026 -.064 .020 (.061) (.047) (.049) (.074) (.043) Credit history improved -.075 .016 -.034 -.024 -.074** (.060) (.042) (.045) (.076) (.035) Net interest expenses increased .060 .081** -.007 -.013 .043* (.046) (.031) (.040) (.048) (.025) Debt to assets ratio increased -.014 .038 -.031 -.057 .064*** (.056) (.029) (.039) (.050) (.024) Credit availability improved -.402*** -.276*** -.421*** -.155* -.292*** (.080) (.040) (.064) (.088) (.044) Manufacturing .031 .004 -.054 -.009 .015 (.053) (.031) (.063) (.053) (.029) Construction .055 .096** .014 -.036 .087*** (.077) (.049) (.055) (.073) (.031) Whole sale/retail trade -.097** -.020 -.095* -.028 .011 (.044) (.038) (.055) (.059) (.028) 2nd half 2009 .015 .108** .201** -.127 .054 (.216) (.052) (.089) (.109) (.039) March 2010- September 2010 -.045 .078 .123 -.026 -.015 (.199) (.056) (.096) (.100) (.042) September 2010- February 2011 .290* .114** .196** -.007 .014 (.160) (.051) (.083) (.085) (.044) April 2011- September 2011 .347** .064 .244*** .160* -.046 (.162) (.055) (.082) (.084) (.045) October 2011- March 2012 .219 .227*** .132 .103 .029 (.160) (.056) (.093) (.095) (.043) April 2012- September 2012 .266* .244*** .275*** .148 .059 (.159) (.052) (.077) (.105) (.045) October 2012- March 2013 .326** .153*** .105 .012 .124*** (.158) (.055) (.086) (.094) (.043) Wald-test (Rho=0) 18.3*** 1.40 13.09*** 2.60 .14 [p-value] [.001] [.237] [.001] [.107] [.703] Predicted probability (conditional) .645 .462 .682 .522 .557 Number of firms (total) 1723 4455 1907 1430 4873 Number of firms (uncensored) 1051 2157 1372 745 2251 Number of firms (censored) 672 2298 535 685 2622 Source: SAFE (First half 2009-October 2012-March 2013). Notes: Reported estimates are conditional marginal effects drawn from probit models with sample selection. The dependent variable is the dummy indicator as presented in Table 1. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Reference groups: Firm size 1-9 employees, Services sector and 1st half 2009. Sampling weights have used. Statistical significance: *<.10, **<.05, ***<.01. 35 Table 4. Sovereign bond ratings and credit rationing [1] [2] [3] [4] Standard & Poor’s -.020*** (.005) Moody’s -.021*** (.005) Fitch -.022*** (.006) Age more than 10 -.095*** (.012) -.095*** (.012) -.095*** (.012) -.096*** (.012) Firm size: 10-49 employees -.123*** (.013) -.123*** (.013) -.124*** (.013) -.124*** (.013) Firm size: 50-249 employees -.176*** (.019) -.175*** (.018) -.176*** (.018) -.175*** (.018) Single owner .047*** (.012) .047*** (.012) .046*** (.012) .047*** (.012) Turnover increased -.041*** (.014) -.041*** (.014) -.041*** (.014) -.041*** (.014) Profits increased .008 (.016) .008 (.016) .008 (.016) .007 (.016) Credit history improved -.032** (.012) -.030** (.012) -.029** (.013) -.030** (.012) Net interest expenses increased .069*** (.015) .067*** (.015) .068*** (.015) .067*** (.015) Debt to assets ratio increased .022 (.014) .022 (.014) .022 (.014) .022 (.014) Credit availability improved -.260*** (.016) -.259*** (.016) -.258*** (.016) -.259*** (.016) Manufacturing .014 (.011) .012 (.011) .012 (.011) .013 (.011) Construction .032 (.021) .033 (.021) .034 (.022) .034 (.021) Whole sale/retail trade -.032** (.012) -.033** (.012) -.032** (.013) -.032*** (.012) 2nd half 2009 .086** (.033) .088** (.037) .088** (.037) .086** (.040) March 2010- September 2010 .076** (.031) .074** (.032) .070** (.033) .066* (.034) September 2010- February 2011 .115*** (.039) .113*** (.039) .101** (.039) .103** (.041) April 2011- September 2011 .097*** (.037) .085** (.036) .072* (.039) .084** (.038) October 2011- March 2012 .112*** (.035) .082** (.039) .053 (.039) .072* (.042) April 2012- September 2012 .140*** (.035) .079** (.039) .063 (.041) .079** (.039) October 2012- March 2013 .102*** (.048) .039*** (.051) .008 (.054) .033 (.054) Belgium (BE) .077** (.039) .059 (.038) .044 (.038) .055 (.038) Germany (DE) .107** (.044) .115*** (.038) .109*** (.036) .110*** (.039) Spain (ES) .257*** (.033) .207*** (.034) .202*** (.035) .209*** (.034) Finland (FI) -.063* (.034) -.059* (.036) -.062* (.036) -.064* (.036) France (FR) .054* (.029) .058* (.030) .053* (.032) .058* (.032) Greece (GR) .398*** (.042) .161** (.071) .122* (.067) .154** (.072) Ireland (IE) .437*** (.048) .375*** (.050) .306*** (.053) .323*** (.053) Italy (IT) .133*** (.048) .046 (.039) .061* (.032) .053 (.038) Netherlands (NL) .405*** (.033) .412*** (.033) .408*** (.034) .408*** (.033) Portugal (PT) .240*** (.040) .102*** (.051) .102** (.050) .114** (.053) Wald-test (Rho=0) 3.79* 6.51** 8.20*** 7.43** [p-value] [.051] [.010] [.001] [.006] Predicted probability (conditional) .420 .420 .420 .420 Number of firms (total) 30555 Number of firms (uncensored) 17178 Number of firms (censored) 13377 Source: SAFE (First half 2009-October 2012-March 2013) and ratings from the websites of Standard & Poor’s, Moody’s and Fitch. Notes: Reported estimates are conditional marginal effects drawn from probit models with sample selection. The dependent variable is the dummy indicator as presented in Table 1. Standard errors in parentheses corrected for clustering at country and survey period levels. Firm size 1-9 employees, Services sector, 1st half 2009 and Austria (AT). Sampling weights have used. Statistical significance: *<.10, **<.05, ***<.01. 36 Table 5. Predicted probability of credit rationing across types of sovereign bond ratings Predicted probability Standard error Standard & Poor’s Highest/High quality .406 .018 Strong payment capacity .386 .036 Adequate payment capacity .517 .040 Likely to fulfil obligations .513 .080 High/Very High/Near Default/Default .625 .064 Moody's Highest/High quality .383 .012 Strong payment capacity .515 .031 Adequate payment capacity .550 .054 Likely to fulfil obligations .610 .048 High/Very High/Near Default/Default .756 .065 Fitch Highest/High quality .386 .013 Strong payment capacity .521 .027 Adequate payment capacity .596 .038 Likely to fulfil obligations .590 .053 High/Very High/Near Default/Default .792 .056 Source: SAFE (First half 2009-October 2012-March 2013) and ratings from the websites of Standard & Poor’s, Moody’s and Fitch. Notes: Predicted probabilities are drawn from probit models with sample selection. The dependent variable is the dummy indicator as presented in Table 1. The grouping of sovereign bond ratings (5 categories) is based on Alfonso et al. (2012, Table 1). The set of independent variables include those presented on Table 4. Standard errors in parentheses corrected for clustering at country and survey period levels. Sampling weights have used. Statistical significance: *<.10, **<.05, ***<.01. 37 Endnotes i Of course there are many cross-county studies from non-euro Central and Eastern European countries (e.g., Popov and Udell, 2012; Beck et al., 2014; Popov, 2015). ii http://www.ecb.europa.eu/stats/money/surveys/sme/html/index.en.html iii Firm age is usually viewed as an indicator of its quality, since longevity sends a signal for survival ability and quality of management, as well as, the accumulation of reputational capital (Diamond, 1992). Moreover, the information gap is relatively smaller for older firms given their longer track record (Petersen and Rajan, 1994; Cressy, 1996). iv A number of explanations have been proposed for small firm disadvantages in loan markets. For instance, their higher relative probability of failure (Jensen and McGuckin, 1997), fixed costs in assessing application for finance and proportionately higher monitoring costs (Boocock and Woods, 1997). In addition, smaller firms may have lower collateral relative to their liabilities than larger ones, and unit bankruptcy costs are likely to decrease with size (Gertler and Gilchrist, 1994; Hu and Schiantarelli, 1994; Gilchrist and Himmelberg, 1998; Audretsch and Elston, 2002; Vijverberg, 2004). v The firm’s investment opportunity set may also affect the likelihood of rationing (Hubbard, 1990). We control for the investment opportunity set by using sales growth, fixed assets growth, and profitability. We expect firms with higher investment opportunity set to face lower probability of rationing. In the context of the Merton (1974) optionpricing model, leverage is used as an inverse proxy of firm credit quality because more levered firms, ceteris paribus, face a greater likelihood of insolvency. In addition, leverage could exacerbate moral hazard problems since highly levered borrowers may have a greater incentive to substitute high risk assets for low risk ones after a loan. In addition, more profitable firms or firms with higher cash flow are expected to be able to borrow more from banks since they are more likely to have the means to service their debt. vi We have also estimated models in which we exclude the firm’s perception regarding the willingness of the banks to provide loans (during the last 6 months) from the credit rationing equation in order to facilitate the requirement of the exclusion restriction in the probit models with selection. However, the results are identical as those presented in the text. 38