Download Problem Set 2 – Some Answers FE405 1.

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Modern Monetary Theory wikipedia , lookup

Pensions crisis wikipedia , lookup

Fear of floating wikipedia , lookup

Business cycle wikipedia , lookup

Quantitative easing wikipedia , lookup

Full employment wikipedia , lookup

Fiscal multiplier wikipedia , lookup

Monetary policy wikipedia , lookup

Inflation wikipedia , lookup

Phillips curve wikipedia , lookup

Interest rate wikipedia , lookup

Stagflation wikipedia , lookup

Inflation targeting wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Problem Set 2 – Some Answers
FE405
1. What are the advantages and disadvantages of an inflation rate of 3% as compared
with one of zero per cent per annum? Would you advocate the replacement of the
inflation target by a price level target?
ANSWER: Advantages of 3% cf. zero: this allows for real wage cuts without nominal
wage cuts and may be necessary in the face of sectoral shocks in the labor market.
Nominal wage cuts are hard to achieve. If a negative real interest rate is required, this
requires some positive inflation since the nominal interest rate cannot be less than zero.
Advantages of zero cf. 3%: the usual discussion of shoe leather costs and distortions if
tax thresholds are not indexed. Potential for confusion between relative price changes
and inflation (and hence misallocation): this is usually related to the fact that inflation is
more variable when it is higher.
2. How can the central bank diagnose what kind of shock has disturbed the economy?
ANSWER: The CB can look at the path of inflation/unemployment. A positive aggregate
demand shock will trigger an increase in employment and in inflation, while a positive
aggregate supply shock will trigger a fall in inflation. Using the 3-equation model, only
aggregate demand shocks lead to immediate changes in output. Inflation or supply
shocks lead to changes in inflation but not in output until the CB responds. This helps to
distinguish between, for example, a negative aggregate demand shock and a positive
supply shock: in both cases inflation falls but only in the first does output change, in this
case, it falls. From the data on inflation and output it will be difficult for the CB to
distinguish between a temporary and a permanent aggregate demand shock.
It will need to make use of other indicators. Similarly it will be difficult to distinguish
between an inflation shock and a supply shock initially. However, more information will
be revealed as the CB implements its policy. These issues can be discussed by going
through the above examples.
3. Compare the response of an inflation-targeting central bank to a permanent negative
aggregate supply shock with that to a permanent negative aggregate demand shock.
ANSWER: The main difference is that while a negative supply shock will rise the ERU
the aggregate demand shock does not. Therefore in the case of the supply shock the CB
has to change its MR to be consistent with the new lower equilibrium value of output;
diagrammatically, the MR line shifts to the left. After the shock inflation raises and
therefore the CB has to increase the interest rate in order to achieve its inflation target.
In the case of an aggregate demand shock activity will be depressed and inflation will
fall, therefore the CB has to lower interest rates in order the expand demand and return
to the inflation target.
4. Suppose there are two regions of the economy, in one of which the WS curve is quite
steep and in the other, the WS is quite flat. Why might this be so? Compare the
Problem Set 2 – Some Answers
FE405
implications for inflation and unemployment of a common positive temporary aggregate
demand shock. How should the central bank respond?
ANSWER: One explanation could be that the WS curve is convex, i.e. it is rather flat at
high unemployment rates and rather steep at low unemployment rates. This would be
consistent with the observation that unemployment is very different in the two regions. A
convex WS curve is plausible, reflecting the weak disinflation effect of a rise in
unemployment when it is already high. (For simplicity, assume that the PS curve is
common to both regions.) Since the central bank sets the interest rate for the country as
a whole, its response will be to raise the interest rate by less than is optimal in the region
with the steep WS curve and by more than is optimal in the other region.
5. Write down the Taylor Rule in terms of the real interest rate. Holding the output gap
constant, does a rise in inflation by x percentage points call for a rise in the nominal
interest rate of more than, less than or by just x percentage points? Explain.
ANSWER: r0 -rS = 0.5(π0 -πT )+0.5(y0 -ye). Since a rise in inflation by x percentage points
will raise the nominal interest rate by x, then in order for the real interest rate to rise by
0.5x , the nominal interest rate will have to rise by x + 0.5x = 1.5x, i.e. by 1.5 times x
percentage points.
6. The central bank faces a short-run trade-off between inflation and unemployment (a)
if inflation expectations are backward-looking or (b) if inflation expectations are rational
but are formed before the central bank chooses its optimal inflation-output pair. Explain
each of these cases. What difference does it make whether (a) or (b) holds?
ANSWER: If expectations are backward looking what matters for the Phillips curve is
past inflation and therefore even if a different level of inflation is announced and even if it
is credible it does not make any difference for the inflation path (see discussion in the
chapter). On the other hand if expectations are rational (based on the information set
available at the time of the decision and not allowing for systematic mistakes) there is a
fundamental role for announcements and credibility.
However in both cases there is always a trade-off in the short-run between inflation and
unemployment since once the public has fixed its expectations the CB can always reach
a lower loss if it trades some extra inflation for a higher output (assuming that the target
output is higher than the equilibrium one); graphically it can be seen in Fig. 5.13.
7. Explain what is meant by the statement that a government that is determined to reduce
inflation may have a problem in achieving this outcome because of a lack of credibility.
ANSWER: There are a number of ways of approaching this question. One is to discuss it
in terms of time inconsistency. Although the government may ‘be determined’ to reduce
inflation, the question is whether lower inflation - say, its new target - is consistent with
its preferences. If not, then it will be not able to achieve the target because wage and
price setters will figure out that it is aiming for unemployment below equilibrium with the
Problem Set 2 – Some Answers
FE405
implication that were they to reduce inflation expectations to the target, the government
would choose to exploit the short-run trade off. In the knowledge of this, the private
sector will not adjust their expectations and a fall in inflation to the target will not occur.
Another approach is to take the case where the government has not only adopted a low
inflation target but has also realized that it can only achieve this if it reduces its output
target to the equilibrium level. It announces this to the public. However, perhaps
because of long experience, the public is skeptical of the government’s claims and they
do not alter their expectations. The government will now choose to impose a deflationary
policy, i.e. they will raise the interest rate. The reason is that given their new
preferences, the MR line has shifted to the left and given the Phillips curve, their
preferred output level is lower. They will therefore be prepared to reduce output and
thereby prove to the public that their utility is higher at lower output. This is a method of
establishing credibility.
8. Is there a trade-off between stabilizing inflation and stabilizing the real side of the
economy? Explain.
ANSWER: Let us assume that the economy is subject to random inflation shocks.
We can then compare two central banks, both of which have the same inflation target
and the same form of loss function (as studied in Chapter 5). However, one places a
high weight on minimizing inflation fluctuations (β > 1) and the other places a high weight
on minimizing output fluctuations (β < 1). The average amplitude of output fluctuations
around the equilibrium will be greater in the β > 1 case (flatter MR line) but inflation will
be stabilized more effectively. In the β < 1 case, the economy is kept quite close to
equilibrium output but inflation is more unstable.
9. Explain the logic of the balanced budget multiplier result. Investigate whether this
result continues to hold if
(a) the money supply is kept constant (rather than the interest rate)?
(b) there is a proportional income tax (rather than a lump sum tax)?
(a) BBM does not hold here because the increase in g leads to a rise in the interest rate
so some investment is crowded out. Hence the increase in y is less than in the case of a
constant i so Δy < Δg = Δt.
(b) It still holds, however there is the need to specify whether the increase in spending is
balanced at the initial or final level of income. As long as the LM is positively sloped.
BBM does hold in this case if Δt is the change in tax revenue from the initial to the new
equilibrium. It is the change in g − t that affects disposable income in the new equilibrium
— since g = t, there is no change in disposable income and therefore Δy = Δt = Δg.
Hence the BBM holds. Since Δy = Δt it is clear that tyΔy < Δt so it is necessary for the tax
rate to be increased to t’y, i.e. ty < t’y < t + Δy/y .
10. What is meant by Ricardian equivalence? Does it imply that high public debt is no
cause for concern? How would you test for its existence?
Problem Set 2 – Some Answers
FE405
ANSWER: The Ricardian equivalence named after David Ricardo states that: the way
government debt is financed (through bonds or taxes) does not matter since we will
always have to repay it. If a government finances its debt through issuing bonds it should
be the case that the extra resources available will be spent by the agents in the
economy, however if the equivalence holds agents will save exactly enough to repay the
debt back since they correctly understand that in the future taxes will be raised to
finance the previously contracted debt. In other words, if the consumer is maximizing
their discounted utility and that of their heirs subject to a present value constraint, a
change in the timing of tax does not affect the constraint and therefore does not affect
the consumption plan. No, it does not imply that high public debt is no cause for concern.
High public debt can generate an important series of consequences unrelated to
Ricardian equivalence: seignorage temptations, high country specific risk, impossibility
of implementing any further fiscal spending, etc... Evidence would be a tax cut,
unaccompanied by any other change, that changes private consumption. See also
Question E in Chapter 7 on consumption. Note that if the tax cut is taken to indicate a
change in the government’s future expenditure plans that will require lower taxes in the
future, consumers will reevaluate their present value constraint, feel richer and increase
consumption. This is consistent with Ricardian equivalence: the key is whether or not the
change in fiscal policy affects the present value constraint.
11. Explain in words what is meant by the prudent fiscal policy rule. What is the main
reason for ‘tax smoothing’? Under this rule, how should a government react in the
following scenarios:
(a) defence spending is cut for the foreseeable future due to the end of the Cold War
(b) the government compensates farmers following a disease outbreak
(c) the Treasury releases a report forecasting that the cost of the tax-funded health service
will treble within 20 years
(d) the government decides to contribute troops to a war that it expects to be over in a
matter of weeks.
ANSWER: A prudent fiscal policy rule is to set the share of tax in GDP at a constant
level equal to the permanent or long-run level required to satisfy the solvency constraint.
The main argument for tax smoothing is pretty similar to that for consumption smoothing
of a household. If the cost (distortions) of a tax rise is increasing in the amount raised
then it is optimal for the government to smooth its tax revenue collection over time. (a)
This is a fall in permanent spending, therefore the tax rate should be lowered. (b) No
reaction, it is a temporary event and therefore no adjustment to the tax rate would be
required. A temporary increase in borrowing will ensue. (c) This is a permanent (almost
surely) change in the amount of government spending and therefore it requires an
increase in the tax share. (d) Same as (b).
12. Under what circumstances might policy-makers wish to reduce the ratio of public
debt to GDP? What factors should influence the policy adopted to achieve such a reduction.
Problem Set 2 – Some Answers
FE405
ANSWER: The following arguments highlight reasons why a high level of public debt can
impose costs on the economy. Higher public debt implies a higher interest rate, which
dampens investment with the result that the capital stock is lower. (This argument
assumes that there is not full Ricardian equivalence, in which case, higher public debt
would be mirrored by lower private sector debt). A higher interest rate in turn increases
the likelihood that the interest rate exceeds the growth rate, which opens up the
possibility of an ever-increasing debt ratio unless the primary surplus is sufficiently large.
Higher public debt may increase concern from home and abroad about the government
honoring the debt. This may increase worries that the government will be tempted to
monetize the debt or default on it. Distortionary taxation to service the debt is also costly
to the economy. Reducing the debt ratio: there are two cases to consider — where
r < γy and r > γy. In the first case, there is a stable path for the debt ratio and this is
consistent with a primary deficit. In order to reduce the debt ratio, the government lowers
the primary deficit and the economy will adjust to the lower stable debt ratio (diagrams in
chapter). Adjustment will take place automatically. However, things are more
complicated in the second case. A primary surplus will be necessary to prevent the debt
ratio from rising further in this case. Moreover because the path is unstable, the
government will first have to increase the surplus somewhat so that the economy begins
to move to the south-west with the debt ratio falling. Once the debt ratio has fallen to the
desired level, the government must then reduce the surplus in order to hold the debt
ratio constant. (See the discussion in the chapter about cold turkey and gradualism in
the choice of strategies.)