* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Exchange rates under sticky prices: The Dornbusch (1976
Balance of payments wikipedia , lookup
Ragnar Nurkse's balanced growth theory wikipedia , lookup
Real bills doctrine wikipedia , lookup
Modern Monetary Theory wikipedia , lookup
Foreign-exchange reserves wikipedia , lookup
2000s commodities boom wikipedia , lookup
Okishio's theorem wikipedia , lookup
Money supply wikipedia , lookup
Monetary policy wikipedia , lookup
Nominal rigidity wikipedia , lookup
Interest rate wikipedia , lookup
Exchange rates under sticky prices: The Dornbusch (1976) overshooting model (Obstfeld and Rogoff, 1996, chapter 9) Some stylized facts: 1) Exchange rates (s) are more volatile than prices or relative prices (p/p*) 2,6 2,4 2,2 2 1,8 1,6 1,4 1,2 1 0,45 BP/USD exchange rate 0,4 BP/US relative prices 0,35 0,3 0,25 0,2 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2) Exchange rate changes (log[st/st-1]) are more volatile than inflation differentials (log[pt/pt-1]- log[pt*/p*t-1]) 30 15 0 -15 Inflation differential US-UK Exchange rate changes USD-BP -30 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 ⇒ The volatility of the real exchange rate (log[s+p*-p]) is similar to that of the nominal exchange rate An important note: In the monetary model prices and exchange rates should display close comovements – unless the shocks in the economy are real (i.e. in competitiveness)... BUT: REAL EXCHANGE RATES ARE LESS VOLATILE UNDER FIXED THAN UNDER FLOATING RATES: SO, REAL SHOCKS ARE NOT A PROBABLE CAUSE OF VARIABILITY!! We need exchange rates to be more volatile than prices under a floating rate setup. A solution is offered by the Dornbusch (1976) sticky price model. Basic characteristics: - sticky prices - no microfoundations (i.e. no current account and welfare issues) included Building blocks of the Dornbusch (1976) sticky price model. (small capital letters denote variables in logs – except of the interest rate) - Uncovered Interest Parity (UIP) • S = st +1 − st = it +1 − i * S - Money demand function and monetary sector equilibrium mt − pt = φy t − ηit +1 - Real exchange rate determination (PPP need not always hold!) qt = st + p * − pt - Domestic output determination y td = y + δ ( st + p * − pt − q ) y = ‘natural’ rate of output q = ‘equilibrium’ real exchange rate consistent with full employment Note: A rise in e or p* relative to p that triggers domestic demand can be justified by: - shifting demand from foreign tradables to domestic non-tradables - the country has monopoly power in the tradable sector - Price level determination: Inflation-expectation augmented Phillips curve: inflation = excess demand + expected inflation (or productivity growth) • P = pt +1 − pt = ψ ( y td − y ) + ( pt +1 − pt ) P where pt ≡ ( st + p * − q ) . By the last definition and since p* and pt +1 − pt = ψ ( y td − y ) + (et +1 − et ) q are constant: Conceptual solution of the model Market clearing: - Asset market clears always - Goods market may not clear Under fully flexible prices, we would have yd = y = y and q= q . BUT: Under sticky prices, the price level is pre-determined (responds slowly) ⇒ Unanticipated shocks lead to excess demand or supply Graphical solution of the model Substituting in the money demand and the price eqs we have (if p* = mt= m ): y = i* and • Goods market: Q = qt +1 − qt = −ψδ (qt − q ) with ψδ<1 Q Asset market: s (1 − φδ )qt (φδq + m ) S = st +1 − st = t − − S η η η • S Q& = 0 S& = 0 φδq + m q q q& = 0 line: vertical at q , as the adjustment in the goods market is independent of nominal factors s& = 0 line: upward sloping if φδ<1 ⇒ The system is saddle path stable Steady-state solution of the system: Q& = 0 and S& = 0 ⇒ q =e −m ⇔ p=m In the steady state, all monetary variables are determined independently of real variables, i.e. there is full dichotomy between the real and the financial sector of the economy. Question: What happens after a monetary policy change (an increase in the money supply)? In the long-run (steady-state) a rise in the money supply from m = m ′ will lead to an analogous rise in the price level and the exchange rate, i.e. m − m ′ = p − p′ = s − s ′ BUT: in the short-run, prices are sticky. S& ′ = 0 S Q& = 0 S& = 0 s0 s′ s q q0 q The rise from m = m ′ moves the S& = 0 locus upwards to S& ′ = 0 . But: prices are sticky and the price level remains at p . So, the exchange rate moves (jumps) to point (s0 , q0) on the new saddle path. In the transition period we have s 0 > s ′ and the exchange rate overshoots its long-run level. Logic behind overshooting: The money balance equation states that m − pt = φy t − ηit +1 ⇒ so a rise in real money balances (m – p), since p is fixed. m raises Proof by contradiction: 1) If s jumped to δ ( s ′ − s ) = δ (m ′ − m ) s′ (no overshooting), the output would rise by ⇒ Money demand would rise by φδ (m ′ − m ) . Assuming that φδ<1 ⇒ rise in money demand < rise in money supply ⇒ (it < i*) to restore equilibrium, which would imply an appreciation of st via UIP (contradiction!) 2) If s jumped by less than (m ′ − m ) , i.e. ( s ′ − s ) < (m ′ − m ) , then: it would have to fall and st to appreciate, i.e. move away from the steady state (contradiction!) THEREFORE: 3) OVERSHOOTING IS THE ONLY POSSIBILITY, I.E. ( s ′ − s ) > (m ′ − m ) TO ACCOUNT FOR THE FALL IN i DUE TO THE DISEQUILIBRIUM IN THE MONEY MARKET AND THE EXPECTED APPRECIATION. - Note: By the differential equation for the exchange rate, the larger η (interest rate elasticity of money demand), the larger the fall in i needed to restore equilibrium, and thus the larger the expected appreciation and overshooting. The case for undershooting - Overshooting depends critically on the condition φδ<1 - If δ (the response of output to exchange rate depreciation) and/or φ (income elasticity of money demand) are large, then we may have φδ>1 and the S& = 0 locus may downward sloping S Q& = 0 φδq ′ + m s′ φδq + m S& ′ = 0 S& = 0 q q An unanticipated rise in m raises s by less than proportionately (undershooting) - Note: In both cases (overshooting and undershooting) the dynamics of real variables (output, real exchange rate) are the same. The nominal depreciation implies a real depreciation (with sticky prices), aggregate demand rises and output is above its steady state value y . Fiscal policy The model can be extended to evaluate the effects of fiscal policy. In such a case, the determination of output is given by: y td = y + δ ( st + p * − pt − q ) + g where g = domestic public expenditure. The equation of motion for q is now: • Q = qt +1 − qt = −ψδ (qt − q ) + g Q Graphical solution of the model S Q& ′ = 0 Q& = 0 S& = 0 s s′ φδq + m q′ q q Steady-state result of a rise in government expenditure: - real exchange rate appreciation (the exchange rate falls from s to s ′ ) - exports are reduced by the amount of the rise in government expenditure The nominal exchange rate s jumps to the new saddle path (reducing exports), and continues to appreciate; there is no overshooting. The rise in demand triggers the price mechanism, and as p rises, the real exchange rate continues to appreciate further towards a new equilibrium, thereby further reducing exports. - Note: This ‘crowding-out’ result in the composition of output is similar to that of the Mundell-Fleming model.