Download + docx - Harvard University

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Economic growth wikipedia , lookup

Modern Monetary Theory wikipedia , lookup

Washington Consensus wikipedia , lookup

Post–World War II economic expansion wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Bias in Official Fiscal Forecasts: Can Private Forecasts Help?
Jeffrey Frankel and Jesse Schreger
Harvard University
Preliminary draft, June 16, 2013
The authors acknowledge support from the Smith Richardson Foundation and the Weatherhead
Center for International Affairs, though views and findings are ours alone. We thank Marco
Martinez del Angel for capable research assistance.
Abstract
Government forecasts of GDP growth and budget balances are more over-optimistic
than private sector forecasts, in a sample of 31 countries. When official forecasts that are
especially optimistic relative to private forecasts ex ante, they are more likely to be overoptimistic relative to realizations ex post. Euro area governments made during the period
1999-2007 assiduously and inaccurately avoided forecasting deficit levels that would
exceed the 3% Stability and Growth Pact threshold; private sector forecasters were not
subject to this crude bias. Three important implications. First, the severe recessions that
began in 2008 do not explain the findings of optimism bias. Second, the over-optimism
seems specifically designed so as to “game” checks on budget deficits, rather than by
politicians’ desire to “talk up” the economy in general. Third, the budget-making process
could be improved by using private-sector forecasts.
JEL classification numbers:
[TBD]
Keywords: [TBD]
1
Introduction
Excessive public debts and deficits are among the most widely discussed of
macroeconomic problems. Why do countries find it so hard to get their deficits under control?
There are many theories, most having to do with short horizons on the part of politicians1 and
dispersion of political power.2 But we believe that systematic patterns in the errors that official
budget agencies make in their forecasts also play an important role.
To take an egregious example, the official Greek forecast in 2000 said that the fiscal
deficit would fall below 2% of GDP one year in the future, fall below 1% of GDP two years into
the future, and convert to a surplus three years into the future. (Figure 1). The subsequent
budget deficit actually fell into the range of 4-5%, well above the 3% of GDP ceiling required by
the Maastricht criterion and the Stability and Growth Pact. Did the Greek government adjust its
overall fiscal policies in response to missing the targets? No, it adjusted its forecasts, predicting
steady progress toward budget balance in the future. This pattern also describes the forecasts
reported by the government in 2001, and every year for the next ten years: always overly
optimistic, and the more so the longer the horizon.
The same pattern extends qualitatively to most other industrialized countries. Having a
fiscal rule like the Stability and Growth Pact does not seem to help. In fact it worsens the bias
toward overoptimistic forecasting. Most euro countries, even when they ran deficits that
For example, Alesina and Tabellini (1990a, b), Grilli, Masciandaro, and Tabellini (1991) and Roubini and
Sachs (1989a,b).
1
Lane (2003). Other explanations for budget deficits abound as well. Surveys include Alesina, Perotti and
Tavares (1998) and Persson and Tabellini (2002).
2
2
exceeded 3% of GDP, continued to forecast future budget deficits that would fall under that
threshold, every year until the crisis of 2010 hit (and in some cases even then).
Previous research (Frankel, 2011; Frankel and Schreger, 2013) studies forecasts of real
growth rates and budget balances made by official government agencies among 24 countries [or
up to 34 in some cases, mostly over the period 1999-2011]. In general, the forecasts are found:
(i) to have a positive average bias, (ii) to be more biased in booms, (iii) to be even more biased at
the 3-year horizon than at shorter horizons.
This over-optimism in official forecasts can help
explain excessive budget deficits: if rapid growth is expected, retrenchment is treated as
unnecessary. Many believe that better fiscal policy can be obtained by means of rules such as
ceilings for the deficit or, better yet, the structural deficit. But we also find: (iv) countries subject
to a budget rule, in the form of euroland’s Stability and Growth Path, make official forecasts of
growth and budget deficits that are even more biased. This effect may help explain frequent
violations of the SGP.
The question becomes how to overcome governments’ tendency to satisfy fiscal targets
by wishful thinking rather than by action. One possibility is a rule whereby the government
must use in its fiscal planning process forecasts coming from the private sector or some other
independent body that is insulated from political pressures or the temptations of wishful thinking.
(Chile instituted such a system in 2000. This presumably explains why its budget forecasts have
not been overly optimistic, even in booms.3)
Canada too has avoided optimism bias (and in fact has been too pessimistic on average), perhaps because it
too uses independent forecasts. With the years 2010 and 2011 added to the sample, several countries as well
are no longer over-optimistic on average at the one-year horizon, though they still are at the two-year
horizon.
3
3
When governments are overly optimistic, subsequent realized budget deficits turn out to
be larger than projected and realized surpluses are smaller. If no one used the forecasts for
anything, then these mistakes would not matter even though they are systematic. But the
forecasts of the budget or economic agency within each government are used as the basis for
fiscal planning. If the forecast is for a strong budget, tax parameters and spending policies are
likely to be eased accordingly. Thus the excessive optimism in forecasts can help explain
excessive deficits in practice. (Returning to the case of Chile, its avoidance of overly optimistic
forecasts may explain why it was able to take advantage of the 2000-2008 boom to run a surplus,
when so many other countries did not.)
The present paper seeks further progress on these issues by expanding the data set
in crucial ways. [It extends the sample period.] Most importantly, it brings data on private
sector forecasts together with the official government forecasts. The resulting extension of
the analysis helps answer two important questions. First, might the earlier findings of
over-optimism be explained by one major historical event, the severe global financial crisis
and recession that began in 2008 and which everyone underestimated? More generally,
when the time sample is short, results based on ex post realizations can be too sensitive to
particular historical outcomes. Private sector forecasts offer an alternative standard by
which to judge the performance of official forecasts and less sensitive to historically
volatile ex post outcomes. Second, if the reform proposal is that governments should use
in the budget-making process independent projections such as those by private forecasters,
what better way to test it than to see if private forecasters suffer from optimism bias as
badly as the government forecasters?
We have three main results, for a sample of 31 countries during sample periods that
usually go up to 2012. . First, official forecasters are more over-optimistic than private
sector forecasters on average at the two-year horizon for budget balances and at the one
and year horizon for real GDP forecasts. Second, the difference between the official
forecast and the private forecast is positively correlated with the difference between the
4
official forecast and the ex post realization, that is, the prediction error. Third, while euro
area governments were very reluctant to forecast violations of the 3% deficit/GDP cap in
the Stability and Growth Pact during the period 1999-2007, private sector forecasters were
not. Together, these results suggest that incorporating private sector forecasts into the
budget process could help countries stick to fiscal rules by identifying over-optimism ex
ante rather than just ex post.
Related Literature
Our work builds on a moderately large literature that tries to understand bias in
government forecasts. Jonung and Larch (2006) demonstrate that European Union
countries have overly optimistic forecasts and propose independent budget forecasting as
a remedy. Debrun et. al. (2009) survey the literature on the performance of independent
fiscal agencies. Merola and Perez (2012) compare the forecasts of European governments
in their Stability and Convergence Programs (SCPs) to the forecasts made by the European
Commission (EC); they find that the forecasts made by the EC are no better than those
made by national governments and are affected similarly by political economy factors, such
as over-optimism in budget years. Beetsma et. al. (2012) also analyze the sources of
national budget forecast errors from national SCPs and find that political factors,
specifically upcoming elections, play a role in explaining government over-optimism. Pina
and Venes (2011) also point to the importance of upcoming elections in over-optimism.
Beetsma et. al. break the budget forecasts into an implementation error, the difference
between the initial projection in the budget and the preliminary figures calculated at the
end of that fiscal year, and the revision error, or the difference between the preliminary
measure and the final statistic. The authors find that implementation errors are driven by
overly optimistic expenditure projections, whereas revision errors are driven by overly
optimistic revenue forecasts. Frankel (2011) shows across a cross-section of countries
that government forecasts are overly optimistic in booms. Frankel and Schreger (2013)
find that euro area countries are much less likely to forecast a breach of the 3% limit but
are no less likely actually to breach the limit. Pina and Venes (2011) find a similar result.
Boylan (2008) examines the forecasting behavior of individual US state
governments and finds an election year bias. Bischoff and Gohout (2010) undertake a
5
similar exercise for West German States. Beetsma et. al. (2013) study budget forecasting
in the Netherlands from 1958-2009 and find that the plans are on unbiased on average.
Muhleisen et. al. (2005) compare the forecasting of Canada to that of other
developed economies and find that countries with fiscal rules and strong budgetary
institutions are more successful in their budget forecasting. Poplawski-Ribeiro and Rulke
(2011) use the same private sector forecast data that we do here, and examine whether
adoption of the SGP leads private, national and EC forecasts to converge and find mixed
results.
Data on Private Forecasts
In this paper, we use three types of data: government forecasts from national
budgets, private sector forecasts, and realizations from international organizations and
national sources. 4 The most important respect in which we seek to improve on earlier
research is the use of the private sector forecasts.
Our private sector forecasts come from Consensus Economics. Every month,
Consensus Economics surveys a number of private sector forecasters for their one- and twoyear ahead forecasts about a number of macroeconomic variables. Here, we examine
forecasts of real GDP and the budget balance. Consensus more commonly polls private
sector forecasters on Real GDP growth than the budget balance, limiting the size of our
budget balance sample and leading to different country and years coverage across the
variables.
In addition for many countries private forecasters forecast the size of the budget
balance in terms of local currency, rather than as a percentage of GDP. In these cases, we
create a private sector forecast for the deficit/GDP ratio by first estimating the implied
private sector forecast for the level of nominal GDP. We take the previous year’s nominal
GDP and multiply it by (1+Real GDP Growth Rate Forecast)*(1+Inflation rate forecast).
Unfortunately, GDP deflator forecasts are unavailable and so we use CPI inflation for
the inflation rate. For the two-year ahead nominal GDP forecasts, we multiply our one year
Realizations for budget balances come from Eurostat for European countries and the IMF or World Bank for
the others. Additional details on data sources can be found in the appendix.
4
6
ahead estimate by one plus the two-year ahead Real GDP Growth Rate Forecast and one
plus the two-year ahead inflation rate. We then divide the budget balance forecast (in
levels) by our estimated nominal GDP forecasts. In the case of countries where the fiscal
year differs from the calendar year but only private sector calendar year GDP growth and
inflation forecasts are available, we collect official forecast data on the level of the budget
deficit and divide both the official and private sector forecasts by realized GDP. Although
this means that these countries are treated slightly differently than the others, within each
country the treatment is identical across private and official forecasts, minimizing the
potential bias. The annual variation in the level of GDP is much smaller than the variation in
the level of the budget deficit. [The countries with fiscal years other than the calendar year
are Australia, Canada, New Zealand, the United States and the UK.]
In order to make sure our private and official forecasts are comparable, we match
the two forecasts by the date the forecast was made. Every month, Consensus releases two
sets of forecasts for the two upcoming years. The forecasts are not for a fixed horizon, but
rather forecast a given variable for a given year. For instance, in the January 2003 release
of Consensus Economics, respondents will forecast French real GDP growth for the 2003 and
2004 calendar years. In February 2003, the same variables will be forecast, but now
instead of being 12 and 24 month forecasts, they are 11 and 23 month forecasts. In
contrast, our government forecasts are made only once a year in the official budget
document. We match private and official forecasts so that there is at most a 3 month gap
between their forecast dates. 77.7% of our matches are exact to the month, 15.0% differ by
one month, 6.4% differ by two months, and 0.9% differ by 3 months for budget deficit
forecasts. For real GDP growth rate forecasts, 71.4% of matches are exact, 19.2% differ by
one month, 8.8% differ by two months, and 0.6% differ by 3 months. Only one observation
is used per country-year, and no matches with a horizon difference greater than 3 months
are used. There still is the possibility that the forecasts were not made at the same time, as
the official forecast date is the date that the budget was released whereas the private
forecast date is the date that Consensus polled the firms. There is presumably a lag
between when government forecasts are actually made and when the budget is released.
Table 1 summarizes the dataset. Each column shows the first and last year we have
a matched private forecast, government forecast and realization. The data set is an
7
unbalanced panel with a different set of countries having Real GDP and budget balance
forecasts.
What are the differences between private and official forecasts?
Having constructed a dataset combining the private and official forecasts, we then
turn to understanding how the two sets of forecasts differ. Here, we only use the mean
private forecast in the Consensus dataset and compare it to the single official forecast. In
Table 2, we present the means, standard deviation and number of observations for dates
where we were able to match the Consensus and Official data, as well as having data on the
realization. For several countries, the 2012 realizations were not available at the time of
writing. More information can be found in the data appendix.
In Table 2A, we compare the one- and two-year ahead budget balance forecasts and
actual outcomes. At the one year horizon, mean actual budget deficits are roughly the same
size as Consensus and Official forecasts. At the two year horizon, however, budget balances
show larger deficits than forecast in either Consensus or Official forecasts, but Consensus
forecasts are closer to the realizations. The standard deviation of actual budget balances is
larger than the Consensus or Official forecasts. The same pattern is found for Real GDP
growth rate forecasts at both one- and two-year horizons in Table 2B.
In Table 3, we run two-sided t-tests for equality of means across the various
forecasts and realizations. We restrict all of our tests to a common sample by variable but
the sample differs across variables, as can be seen in the number of observations. In Table
3A, we see that the mean one-year ahead ex post Consensus budget balance forecast error,
ex post Official budget balance forecast error, and the difference between the three
forecasts are not significantly different than zero.
At the two year horizon, however, both Official and Consensus forecasts are
significantly over-optimistic ex post. However, while Official forecasts were ex post overoptimistic by 0.66% of GDP on average, Official forecasts are on average 0.17% more
optimistic than Consensus forecasts. This criterion of over-optimism is even more highly
significant statistically than judging official forecasts against the standard of ex post
8
outcomes. Given how bad were the ex post outcomes after the global financial crisis, this is
an important finding. Because the comparison of official forecasts with private forecasts
makes no use of ex post data, it is immune from the possibility that our results are driven
by one record-breaking recession. [Intuitively, it is harder to excuse the authorities from
under-estimating the severity of the recession to the extent that private forecasters did not
make the same mistake. ]
Table 3B conducts the corresponding t-tests for Real GDP growth rate forecasts. At
the one year horizon, Consensus forecasts do not have statistically significant ex post errors
(point estimate of 0.18%), but Official forecasts have a mean over-optimism of 0.32%. In
addition, official forecasts are significantly more optimistic than private sector forecasts,
with a mean difference of 0.14%. The differences are larger at the two-year horizon, with
ex post official forecasts errors of 1.15%, private forecast errors of 0.99%, and a mean
difference between the two of 0.16%, all of which are significant at the 1% level.
Figures 2 and 3 plot the data for the example of Italy, comparing private and official
forecasts with the actual realizations. While private and official forecasts co-move strongly,
government forecasters consistently predict smaller deficits and faster growth. In sample,
both private and official forecasts proved themselves to be generally over-optimistic, but
private forecasts less so.
Can private forecasts be used to predict when official forecasts will
prove to be over optimistic?
In this section, we want to see if we can use private forecasts to improve on the
performance of predictions made by the official agencies. In other words, is the ex ante
discrepancy between private and official forecasts positively correlated with the
discrepancy between official forecasts and the realized outcome, that is, the ex post
prediction error? In Table 4, we see that the answer is yes.
We define the Government-Consensus Budget Balance disagreement (Gov-Con) and
the government i-year ahead forecast error (BBEgt+i)
Gov-Con BBt+i =BB_Govt+i – BB_Cont+i
BBEgt+i =BB_Govt+i –BBt+i
9
where BB_Govt+i denotes the i-year ahead government budget balance forecast (as a % of
GDP) made in year t, BB_Govt+i denotes the i-year ahead Consensus budget balance forecast
made in year t, and BBt+i denotes the actual budget balance in year t+i. In Table 4, we regress
one- and two-year ex post official forecast errors on this variable and various combinations
of country and year fixed effects and find that contemporary disagreement between private
and official forecasters is a useful measure for predicting when government forecasts will
prove over-optimistic. In our baseline specification (columns 1 and 2) without any fixed
effects, for every 1% that the government forecasts are more optimistic than private
forecasts at the one year horizon, we find an ex post government error of 0.93%. At the two
year horizon, the point estimate is 0.61%. One way to read this is that when government
forecasts are unusually optimistic relative to private forecasters, government forecasts on
average are also unusually optimistic relative to the ex post outcome. With only a constant
and the difference between private and official forecasts in the equation, we have an Rsquared of 18% at the one year horizon and an R-squared of 4% at the two year horizon.
When we include year fixed effects, the results are further strengthened (columns 5 and 6),
meaning that in a given year, those countries that made forecasts more relatively more
optimistic than private sector forecasts have larger ex post budget deficits than those
countries that did not. However, the result is not as strong within country, as the addition
of country fixed effects reduces the significance level at the one-year horizon and the the
point estimate and all significance at the two-year horizon.
This same relationship is illustrated graphically in Figures 4 and 5. In the scatter
plot, each marker indicates the mean of a country. However, the regression line is not a
fitted line through these country means. Rather, the regression line is weighted by
country-year, as in the pooled OLS in columns 1 and 2 of Table 4. Only countries with 4 or
more observations are included.
In Table 5, we run similar regressions as in Table 4 but examine real GDP forecast
errors. We replace Gov-Con BB with an equivalent measure defined for real GDP growth
rates, and similarly for growth rate forecast errors GDPEg
Gov-Con GDPt+i =GDP_Govt+i – GDP_Cont+i .
GDPEgt+i =GDP_Govt+i –GDPt+i
10
Despite economically significant point estimates at the one-year horizon and occasional
statistical significance, the results are not as clear as for budget balances in Table 4.
[Figures 6 and 7 plot the equivalent figures for Real GDP growth forecast
disagreement and ex post real GDP forecasts errors. The results are fairly inconclusive.]
Can private forecasts be used to make fiscal rules move effective?
Finally, we turn to whether private forecast rules can potentially make fiscal rules
more effective. Frankel and Schreger (2013) demonstrate that the extra bias among euro
area countries took the specific form of rarely forecasting that their budget would breach
the 3% threshold enshrined in the Stability and Growth Pact during the period 1999-2007,
after which point the financial crisis had pushed them too far past the threshold to keep up
the pretense. This was in spite of the fact that their actual budget balances displayed no
such discontinuity at 3%.5
In Figure 8, we replicate these results from Frankel and Schreger (2013) while
checking whether the private sector forecasters made a similar sort of error [in those
country-years where we also have Consensus data]. In the middle panel, we reproduce the
figure for official forecasts as in our earlier work. In the upper left hand graph, we create
the analogous figure for Consensus data and find no discontinuity at 3%. In other words, if
the national governments had been using private sector forecasts to determine when their
countries were likely to breach the 3% requirements of the SGP, they could not have used
wishful thinking to respond to warnings from the EC. In Figure 9, we also produce the
same figures at the one-year horizon. Although the euro area forecasts do not have the
dramatic discontinuity at 3%, one can still see a large cluster of forecasts immediately to
the right of the 3% threshold that is absent from the Consensus Forecasts.
These results sharpen the evidence on bias in official forecasts. They confirm that
the existence of a fiscal rule such as the Stability and Growth Pact does nothing to solve the
problem of over-optimism, and may even make it worse. They may also shed some light
on the motives of governments. The findings of over-optimism in the literature could have
By only including forecasts made through 2007, the two-year ahead figure covers forecasts of budget
deficits through 2009 and the one-year ahead figure covers forecasts through 2008. After the start of the
financial crisis, budget balances became much larger and European countries began deficits in excess of the
3% threshold.
5
11
been explained in a number of ways. One obvious hypothesis is that national leaders seek
to convince their voters that their country’s generic economic performance is good, either
for the political purpose of winning votes or for the economic purpose of boosting
consumer and business confidence. There may be psychological explanations as well. But
the finding of a threshold of 3% among the euro country forecasts suggests a narrower
explanation, that they were in effect gaming the rules of the European Commission’s
excessive deficit procedure under the SGP.
Conclusion
In this paper we document three main findings. First, confirming earlier findings,
official forecasts are more over-optimistic than private forecasts. Second, the ex ante
discrepancy between private and official forecasts is positively correlated with the
discrepancy between official forecasts and the realized outcome, that is, with the ex post
prediction error. Private sector forecasts can improve on official forecasts.. Third, private
sector forecasts predicted euro area countries would breach the 3% limit in the Stability
and Growth Pact, usually accurately, even though government agencies did not forecast
breaching the limit.
The evidence is mounting that over-optimism in official forecasts may play a key
role in delivering excessive budget deficits. In the first place, we see that the severe
recessions that began in 2008 are not driving the finding by themselves. In the second
place, we see that euro governments refrained from forecasting deficits over the 3 per cent
SGP threshold, even when private forecasts and actual deficits were both above this level.
Apparently the optimism bias is not just an example of politicians’ general tendency to
look on the bright side. There is an important possible implication for reform proposals:
Tightening fiscal rules will not help limit budget deficits, if forecasts remain subject to
gaming the rules or (more charitably) to wishful thinking. Giving independence to the
agencies that make the forecasts used in the budget-making process or even using leading
private forecasts directly may be more likely to help.
12
References
Beetsma, Roel, and Massimo Giuliodori, “Fiscal Adjustment to Cyclical Developments in the OECD: An Empirical
Analysis Based on Real-time Data,” Oxford Economic Papers, 2010, 52 (3), 419–441.
Beetsma, Roel, Benjamin Bluhm Massimo Giuliodori and Peter Wierts, “From Budgetary Forecasts to Ex Post
Fiscal Data: Exploring the Evolution of Fiscal Forecast Errors in the European Union,” Contemporary Economic
Policy, Forthcoming.
Beetsma, Roel, Massimo Giuliodori Beetsma and Peter Wierts, “Planning to Cheat: EU Fiscal Policy in Real Time,”
Economic Policy, 2009, 24, 753–804.
Beetsma, Roel, Massimo Giuliodori Mark Walschot Peter Wierts , “Fifty Years of Fiscal Planning and
Implementation in the Netherlands,” European Journal of Political Economy, Forthcoming.
Bischoff, Ivo, and Wolfgang Gohout, “The Political Economy of Tax Projections,” International Tax and Public
Finance, 2010, 17 (2), 133–150.
Boylan, Richard T., “Political Distortions in State Forecasts,” Public Choice, 2008, 136, 411–427.
Bruck, Tilman and Andreas Stephan, “Do Eurozone Countries Cheat with their Budget Deficit Forecasts,” Kyklos,
2006, 59 (1), 3–15.
Frankel, Jeffrey, “Over-optimism in Forecasts by Official Budget Agencies and its Implications,” Oxford
Review of Economic Policy, 2011, 27 (4), 536–562.
Frankel, Jeffrey, and Jesse Schreger, “Over-optimistic Official Forecasts and Fiscal Rules in the Eurozone,” Review
of World Economics, 2013, 149 (2), 247–272.
Jonung, Lars, and Martin Larch, “Improving Fiscal Policy in the EU: The Case for Independent Forecasts,”
Economic Policy, 2006, 21 (47), 491–534.
Muhleisen , Martin, Stephan Danninger, David Hauner, Kornelia Krajnyak and Bennett Sutton, “How Do Canadian
Budget Forecasts Compare With Those of Other Industrial Countries?,” IMF Working Paper, April 2005, (05/66).
Merola, Rossana, and Javier J. Perez, “Fiscal Forecast Errors: Governments vs Independent Agencies?” Working
Paper, 2012.
Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria, “Good, Bad or Ugly? On the Effects of Fiscal Rules with Creative Accounting,”
Journal of Public Economics, 2003, 88 (1-2), 377–394.
Pina, Alvaro M., and Nuno M. Venes, “The Political Economy of EDP Fiscal Forecasts: An Empirical Assessment,”
European Journal of Political Economy, 2011, 27, 534–546.
Poplawski-Ribeiro, Marco, and Jan-Christoph Rulke, “Fiscal Expectations Under the Stability and Growth Pact:
Evidence from Survey Data,” IMF Working Paper, March 2011, (11/48).
Teresa, Javier J. Perez, Mika Tujula Leal and Jean-Pierre Vidal, “Fiscal Forecasting: Lessons From the Literature
and Challenges,” Fiscal Studies, 2008, 29 (3), 347–386.
Wyplosz, Charles, “Fiscal policy: Institutions versus Rules,” National Institute Economic Review, 2005, 191, 64–78.
Xavier, David, Hauner Debrun and Manmohan S. Kumar, “Independent Fiscal Agencies,” Journal of Economic
Surveys, 2009, 23 (1), 44–81.
13
Appendix A: Data (To be written)
14
Tables
Table 1A: Data Coverage
country
Australia
Austria
Belgium
Canada
Chile
Cyprus
Czech Republic
Denmark
Estonia
Finland
France
Germany
Greece
Hungary
Ireland
Italy
Latvia
Lithuania
Mexico
Netherlands
New Zealand
Norway
Poland
Portugal
Slovakia
Slovenia
South Africa
Spain
Sweden
UK
USA
BB 1Y
1993-2012
BB 2Y
1994-2011
1995-2012
1994-2009
2002-2012
2005-2012
2006-2012
2008-2012
2009-2012
1999-2012
1999-2011
2000-2012
2000-2012
2005-2012
2006-2012
1999-2012
2008-2012
2008-2012
1995-2009
2000-2012
2009-2012
2009-2012
2005-2009
1997-2011
2011-2011
2005-2012
1998-2011
2011-2012
2008-2012
2012-2012
2009-2012
2011-2012
2000-2012
1994-2012
2012-2012
2006-2012
1995-2012
GDP 1Y
GDP 2Y
1999-2012
1999-2012
1990-2012
1994-2008
2005-2011
2005-2012
1999-2011
2006-2011
1999-2011
1999-2011
1999-2011
2000-2011
2005-2012
1999-2011
1999-2012
2005-2012
2005-2012
2000-2012
1999-2011
2000-2012
2000-2012
1991-2010
2002-2012
2005-2011
1999-2010
2005-2012
2005-2012
1998-2012
1999-2011
1999-2012
1998-2012
1992-2012
2006-2011
2006-2012
2000-2011
2007-2011
2001-2011
2000-2011
2000-2011
2001-2012
2006-2012
2000-2011
2000-2012
2006-2012
2006-2012
2005-2012
2000-2011
2006-2011
2000-2011
2006-2012
2006-2012
1999-2012
2000-2011
2000-2012
1999-2012
1992-2012
Notes: Each cell indicates the first and last year we have a matched private and official forecast as well as
the relevant realization. GDP1Y indicates one year ahead real GDP forecasts, GDP2Y indicates two year
ahead real GDP forecasts, BB 1Y indicates one year ahead budget balance forecasts, and BB 2Y
indicates two year ahead budget balance forecasts.
15
Table 2A: Summary Statistics for Budget Balance Forecasts
One Year Ahead
Consensus
Official
Actual
-1.92
-1.83
-1.86
Mean
3.01
3.03
3.47
SD
205
205
205
Obs.
Mean
SD
Obs.
Two Years Ahead
Consensus
Official
-1.83
-1.66
2.43
2.25
138
138
Actual
-2.32
3.13
138
Table 2B: Summary Statistics for Real GDP Growth Forecasts
One Year Ahead
Consensus
Official
Actual
Mean
2.48
2.62
2.30
SD
1.97
1.96
3.51
Obs.
350
350
350
Two Years Ahead
Consensus
Official
Actual
Mean
2.87
3.03
1.88
SD
1.31
1.34
3.56
Obs.
289
289
289
Notes: Consensus indicates the mean private sector forecast from Consensus Economics. Official
indicates the government forecast in their official budget document. Actual indicates the realization of the
Budget Balance and Real GDP growth in Tables 2A and 2B, respectively. SD denotes standard deviation
and Obs. denotes observations.
16
Table 3A: t-Tests for Equality of Means for Budget Balance, Common Sample
One Year Ahead
Mean
SD
P-Value
Obs.
Official Minus Consensus
0.09
0.06
0.17
205
Official Forecast Error
0.03
0.14
0.82
205
Consensus Forecast Error
-0.06
0.13
0.66
205
Official Minus Consensus
Official Forecast Error
Consensus Forecast Error
Two Years Ahead
Mean
0.17**
0.66***
0.49**
SD
0.07
0.21
0.21
P-Value
0.02
0.00
0.02
Obs.
138
138
138
Table 3B: t-Tests for Equality of Means for Real GDP Growth, Common Sample
One Year Ahead
Mean
SD
P-Value
Obs.
Official Minus Consensus
0.14***
0.03
0.00
350
Official Forecast Error
0.32**
0.13
0.01
350
Consensus Forecast Error
0.18
0.12
0.16
350
Official Minus Consensus
Official Forecast Error
Consensus Forecast Error
Two Years Ahead
Mean
0.16***
1.15***
0.99***
SD
0.03
0.21
0.21
P-Value
0.00
0.00
0.00
Obs
289
289
289
17
Table 4: Government-Private Disagreement over Budget Balance and Official Budget Balance Forecast Errors
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
VARIABLES
BBEgt+1
BBEgt+2
BBEgt+1
BBEgt+2
BBEgt+1
BBEgt+2
BBEgt+1
BBEgt+2
Gov-Con BBt+i
Constant
Observations
R-squared
Country FE
Year FE
Countries
0.934**
(0.349)
-0.0499
(0.156)
0.608**
(0.227)
0.560***
(0.191)
205
0.177
No
No
20
138
0.040
No
No
17
0.873*
(0.461)
-0.0191
(0.191)
0.296
(0.306)
-0.113
(0.162)
0.888***
(0.296)
-1.568***
(0.0752)
205
138
205
0.280
0.181
0.445
Yes
Yes
No
No
No
Yes
20
17
20
Robust standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
0.678***
(0.223)
-0.782***
(0.0290)
0.821*
(0.402)
-1.551***
(0.102)
0.343
(0.248)
-0.825***
(0.0323)
138
0.485
No
Yes
17
205
0.535
Yes
Yes
20
138
0.601
Yes
Yes
17
Notes: The LHS variable in every column is the Official Budget forecast Error. 1Y indicates the one year ahead error and 2Y
indicates the two year ahead error. Gov-Con BB is the official forecast budget balance minus the Consensus forecast of the budget
balance.
18
Table 5: Government-Private Disagreement over GDP Growth Rates and Real GDP Growth Rate Forecast Errors
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
VARIABLES
GDPEgt+1 GDPEgt+2 GDPEgt+1 GDPEgt+2
GDPEgt+1 GDPEgt+2 GDPEgt+1 GDPEgt+2
Gov-Con GDPt
Constant
Observations
R-squared
Country FE
Year FE
Countries
1.146*
(0.572)
0.156
(0.120)
0.143
(0.507)
1.131***
(0.170)
350
0.078
No
No
29
289
0.000
No
No
27
1.194*
(0.657)
0.0824
(0.0903)
-0.0762
(0.633)
0.714***
(0.0744)
0.695*
(0.350)
1.062***
(0.0227)
0.600
(0.405)
4.508***
(0.394)
0.716*
(0.396)
1.060***
(0.0257)
0.525
(0.582)
4.581***
(0.567)
350
289
350
289
350
289
0.115
0.070
0.561
0.619
0.589
0.659
Yes
Yes
No
No
Yes
Yes
No
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
29
27
29
27
29
27
Robust standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Notes: The LHS variable in every column is the Official Real GDP Forecast Error. 1Y indicates the one year ahead error and 2Y
indicates the two year ahead error. Gov-Con GDP is the official forecast real GDP growth rate minus the Consensus forecast of the
real GDP growth rate.
19
Figure 1: Greek Over-Optimism
Notes: Data from Greece’s Stability and Convergence Programs.
20
Figure 2: Italian Budget Balance Forecasts
One-Year Ahead
Two-Years Ahead
Notes: Year is year being forecast.
21
Figure 3: Italian Real GDP Growth Forecasts
One-Year Ahead
Two-Years Ahead
Notes: Year is year being forecast.
22
Figure 4: Budget Balance forecasts, One-Year Ahead
Figure 5: Budget Balance forecasts, Two-Years Ahead
Notes: Only countries with more than 4 observations are included.
23
Figure 6: Real GDP Growth forecasts, One-Year Ahead
Figure 7: Real GDP Growth forecasts, Two-Years Ahead
Notes: Only countries with more than 4 observations are included.
24
Figure 8: Budget Balance Forecasts and Realizations in the Eurozone, Two-Years ahead, Through 2009
Figure 9: Budget Balance Forecasts and Realizations in the Eurozone, One-Year ahead, Through 2008
25