
Every prime of the form 4k+1 is the sum of two perfect squares
... y. If p divided both x and y it would follow that m0 p was divisible by p2 which is not possible by the restrictions on m0 . Thus we can choose integers c, d so that x1 = x − cm0 , y1 = y − dm0 , |x1 | ≤ m0 /2, |y1| ≤ m0 /2 and x21 + y12 > 0. What we have done is to choose cm0 to be a nearest multip ...
... y. If p divided both x and y it would follow that m0 p was divisible by p2 which is not possible by the restrictions on m0 . Thus we can choose integers c, d so that x1 = x − cm0 , y1 = y − dm0 , |x1 | ≤ m0 /2, |y1| ≤ m0 /2 and x21 + y12 > 0. What we have done is to choose cm0 to be a nearest multip ...
ON FINITE SUMS OF RECIPROCALS OF DISTINCT
... formally distinct sums in Pr_χ are separated by a distance of more than σ and hence, each element π of Pr-± gives rise to a half-open interval [TΓ, π + σ) which is disjoint from any other interval [TΓ', TΓ' + σ) for TΓ Φ τr'eP r _!. Therefore Ac(S) = \Jnepr-.x\.π9π + σ) is the disjoint union of exac ...
... formally distinct sums in Pr_χ are separated by a distance of more than σ and hence, each element π of Pr-± gives rise to a half-open interval [TΓ, π + σ) which is disjoint from any other interval [TΓ', TΓ' + σ) for TΓ Φ τr'eP r _!. Therefore Ac(S) = \Jnepr-.x\.π9π + σ) is the disjoint union of exac ...
Chapter 2 Review
... Alternate Interior Angle Theorem Alternate Exterior Angle Theorem Same-side Interior Angle Theorem Same-side Exterior Angle Theorem Solve. 1. Consider the conditional statement, “If Micah’s average score is 92 or greater, then he will receive an A.” a. What is the hypothesis, p? ...
... Alternate Interior Angle Theorem Alternate Exterior Angle Theorem Same-side Interior Angle Theorem Same-side Exterior Angle Theorem Solve. 1. Consider the conditional statement, “If Micah’s average score is 92 or greater, then he will receive an A.” a. What is the hypothesis, p? ...
Brouwer fixed-point theorem

Brouwer's fixed-point theorem is a fixed-point theorem in topology, named after Luitzen Brouwer. It states that for any continuous function f mapping a compact convex set into itself there is a point x0 such that f(x0) = x0. The simplest forms of Brouwer's theorem are for continuous functions f from a closed interval I in the real numbers to itself or from a closed disk D to itself. A more general form than the latter is for continuous functions from a convex compact subset K of Euclidean space to itself.Among hundreds of fixed-point theorems, Brouwer's is particularly well known, due in part to its use across numerous fields of mathematics.In its original field, this result is one of the key theorems characterizing the topology of Euclidean spaces, along with the Jordan curve theorem, the hairy ball theorem and the Borsuk–Ulam theorem.This gives it a place among the fundamental theorems of topology. The theorem is also used for proving deep results about differential equations and is covered in most introductory courses on differential geometry.It appears in unlikely fields such as game theory. In economics, Brouwer's fixed-point theorem and its extension, the Kakutani fixed-point theorem, play a central role in the proof of existence of general equilibrium in market economies as developed in the 1950s by economics Nobel prize winners Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu.The theorem was first studied in view of work on differential equations by the French mathematicians around Poincaré and Picard.Proving results such as the Poincaré–Bendixson theorem requires the use of topological methods.This work at the end of the 19th century opened into several successive versions of the theorem. The general case was first proved in 1910 by Jacques Hadamard and by Luitzen Egbertus Jan Brouwer.