
Lecture 5 and 6
... d) for all U ∈ U0 and x ∈ E there is an ε > 0, so that λx ∈ U , for all λ ∈ K with |λ| < ε , e) if (E, T ) is Hausdorff, then for every x ∈ E, x (= 0, there is a U ∈ U0 with x (∈ U , f ) if E is locally convex, then there is for all U ∈ U0 a convex V ∈ U0 , with V ⊂ U , i.e. 0 has a neighborhood bas ...
... d) for all U ∈ U0 and x ∈ E there is an ε > 0, so that λx ∈ U , for all λ ∈ K with |λ| < ε , e) if (E, T ) is Hausdorff, then for every x ∈ E, x (= 0, there is a U ∈ U0 with x (∈ U , f ) if E is locally convex, then there is for all U ∈ U0 a convex V ∈ U0 , with V ⊂ U , i.e. 0 has a neighborhood bas ...
11-2 Chords and Arcs
... Theorem 11-5 Within a circle or in congruent circles 1. Chords equidistant from the center are congruent. 2. Congruent chords are equidistant from the center. Note that the two parts of Theorem 11-5 are converses of each other. On p. 591, examine the proof of part 1 of Theorem 11-5 and note these s ...
... Theorem 11-5 Within a circle or in congruent circles 1. Chords equidistant from the center are congruent. 2. Congruent chords are equidistant from the center. Note that the two parts of Theorem 11-5 are converses of each other. On p. 591, examine the proof of part 1 of Theorem 11-5 and note these s ...
MATH 161 SAMPLE FINAL EXAM SOLUTIONS 1. Euclidean geometry
... If f is a non-identity translation then f ◦ f is not the identity (it is a translation with displacement vector twice that of f ,) so this case can’t happen. If f is a rotation then its center of rotation is a fixed point. Finally, if f is a glide reflection that is not a reflection, say f = r` ◦ T~ ...
... If f is a non-identity translation then f ◦ f is not the identity (it is a translation with displacement vector twice that of f ,) so this case can’t happen. If f is a rotation then its center of rotation is a fixed point. Finally, if f is a glide reflection that is not a reflection, say f = r` ◦ T~ ...
SOME FIXED-POINT THEOREMS ON AN ALMOST G
... on had been presented a grand occasions, (see, [2, 6-10]). Along with the above development, many features of the concept of convex sets are extended to some general convexities; for example, convex spaces of Lassonde, C-spaces of Horvath, and others. These general convexities are all subsumed to th ...
... on had been presented a grand occasions, (see, [2, 6-10]). Along with the above development, many features of the concept of convex sets are extended to some general convexities; for example, convex spaces of Lassonde, C-spaces of Horvath, and others. These general convexities are all subsumed to th ...
7.1 Apply the Pythagorean Theorem
... • The theorem says that of I square the legs of a right triangle and add them they will be equal to the hypotenuse squared ...
... • The theorem says that of I square the legs of a right triangle and add them they will be equal to the hypotenuse squared ...
Brouwer fixed-point theorem

Brouwer's fixed-point theorem is a fixed-point theorem in topology, named after Luitzen Brouwer. It states that for any continuous function f mapping a compact convex set into itself there is a point x0 such that f(x0) = x0. The simplest forms of Brouwer's theorem are for continuous functions f from a closed interval I in the real numbers to itself or from a closed disk D to itself. A more general form than the latter is for continuous functions from a convex compact subset K of Euclidean space to itself.Among hundreds of fixed-point theorems, Brouwer's is particularly well known, due in part to its use across numerous fields of mathematics.In its original field, this result is one of the key theorems characterizing the topology of Euclidean spaces, along with the Jordan curve theorem, the hairy ball theorem and the Borsuk–Ulam theorem.This gives it a place among the fundamental theorems of topology. The theorem is also used for proving deep results about differential equations and is covered in most introductory courses on differential geometry.It appears in unlikely fields such as game theory. In economics, Brouwer's fixed-point theorem and its extension, the Kakutani fixed-point theorem, play a central role in the proof of existence of general equilibrium in market economies as developed in the 1950s by economics Nobel prize winners Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu.The theorem was first studied in view of work on differential equations by the French mathematicians around Poincaré and Picard.Proving results such as the Poincaré–Bendixson theorem requires the use of topological methods.This work at the end of the 19th century opened into several successive versions of the theorem. The general case was first proved in 1910 by Jacques Hadamard and by Luitzen Egbertus Jan Brouwer.