* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download A Neokeynesian Balance of Payment Model. Study Case on
Ragnar Nurkse's balanced growth theory wikipedia , lookup
Global financial system wikipedia , lookup
Modern Monetary Theory wikipedia , lookup
Economic growth wikipedia , lookup
Foreign-exchange reserves wikipedia , lookup
Transformation in economics wikipedia , lookup
Rostow's stages of growth wikipedia , lookup
Balance of payments wikipedia , lookup
Exchange rate wikipedia , lookup
A Neokeynesian Balance of Payment Model. Study Case on Romanian Economy Authors: PhD. Professor Mihai Roman PhD. Professor Dumitru Marin Academy of Economic Studies, Bucharest, Romania Abstract Net external debt is now an important problem of world economies. Last periods experience shows that many countries can’t face debt pressure and stops to pay there debts. Authors propose in this paper a dynamic IS-LM-BP Neokeynesian model to analyze external debt sustainability. To verify model hypothesis we use Romania’s economy data during 1990-2003. Model shows that exist budgetary, fiscal and monetary politics to control and influence external debt level. Key words: external debt, real exchange rate, foreign investment, ISLM-BP model 1. Introduction Romanian’s adhesion to E.U. radically affects political, economical and social life. Economically we have advantages and also disadvantages for consumers and producers. The mains advantages are: An increasing concurrence between companies; Decrease of good prices; Financial aids for economical and social restructuring; Easier access to European funds for R&D, restructuring economy and social life, etc. Also, we have disadvantages: an increasing breakdown process of Romanian’s small companies; unemployment increase; a rise of prices for energy, fuel and methane gas; lack of independence for national financial and monetary policy; maximum level of budgetary deficit will be 3%, etc. All this elements will affect also net external debt. The commercial balance continue to be in an increasing deficit so long as Romanian’s companies not apply EU’s rules and not try to increase productivity and efficiency. As consequences the export level will increase and import level will decrease. The capital balance will be in disequilibrium. Other European countries experience shows that an increasing inflows of foreign direct investments and restructuring funds. These elements generate an appreciation of national exchange rates as part of BalassaSamuelson effect. Adopting European currency by new states generates three point of vue: first of them – euro skeptical one – said that we don’t need a such process because of reduced economical performances of new admmited countries, and if this transition will be adopted, then Euro will be a weaker currency; the second one represent the euro-optimistically researchers that said the cost of adopting euro currency by new countries will be small or neglected; third, the euro-pragmatically point of vue said that every country must adopt euro currency only when economical performances are the good one. Analyzing effects of Euro adopting by forerunner states (Greece, Spain or Portugal) we see they did not have problems to join the Economic and Monetary Union. On the other side, the ten new states that joined EU in 2004 seems to have economical difficulties to adopt euro currency because of national currency appreciation, a weaker productivity increase face to other European countries and for particular conditions of every country. In our paper we propose a dynamic IS-LM-BP model to analyze the sustainable growth debt and exchange rate. The mains variables of our model are net external debt, direct foreign investments, domestic and external demand and real exchange rate. Based on these basic variables we try to appreciate the Romanian’s sustainable net external debt and balance of payments instead of Romania’s adhesion to EU in 2007. 2. Literature Some authors like Halpern and Wyplosz1 (2001) analyzing euro adoption shows that real appreciation of national currencies are a consequences of excessive depreciation at the beginning of transition processes at market economy. But recent papers show that real appreciation exchange rate for transition countries are not explained totally by BalassaSamuelson effect2. Other authors verifying empirically and econometrical Balassa –Samuelson effect are Bahmani, Oskooe and Rhee (1996)3, Lafrance and Schembri (2000)4, Drine and Rault (2002)5 or Porter (1998)6. Halpern,L., Wyplosy, C – Economic transformation and real exchange rate in the 2000’s : The Balassa-Samuelson Connection – United Nation Economic Commission for Europe, (UN/ECE), Geneve, sept. 2001 2 Balassa-Samuelson effect analyze exchange rates variations dues on relative productivities differences between exported goods on international markets. 3 Bahmani,Oskooe and Rhee (1996)– Time series Support for Balassa’s Productivity / bias Hypothesis: Evidence for Korea, Review Economics , 4 1 To explain Balassa-Samuelson effect, Paul Krugman7 shows that: different countries workers have different productivities; some sectors are more dynamic like others in R&D processes; sectors with relative unchanged productivities do not export goods; real exchange rates are flexible so that exported good prices are the same like in PPP- theories; exchanges rates modifies depending on exportable goods productivities, but average productivity do not vary in the same proportion; Productivity rise is transformed in supplementary revenue, and as consequences real revenue vary in a small proportion like nominal revenue. Other recent papers shows that exchange rate appreciation is not total explained by Balassa-Samuelson effect, especially for transition countries: De Broek and Slok (2001), Egert (2002) Mikaljed (2002) Flek and all (2003). But exchange rate appreciation cannot be explained by traditional theory of external accumulation (see Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2000, 2002)). Under such hypothesis countries with a large external debt must have a surpluss of trade balance and by consequences a competitive exchange rate and a depreciation tendency, but this hypothesis is not verified for transition countries. 3. The Model8 We consider a small, open economy where we have the next variables, small letters represent variables in logarithmic expression: m – real money supply; p – price level; y – GDP level; R – nominal interest rate (percent); R* - world nominal interest rate (percent); g – government expenses; k – capital stock; c – real consumption level; i – domestic investments; f – foreign direct investments; 4 Lafrance & Schembri (2000)- http://www. bank-banque-canada.ca/publications/review Drine , I, Rault, C.(2002) – Panel data analysis of the Balassa-Samuelson effect hypothesis, Sorbonne University 6 Porter, M.E. (1998)- The Competitive Advantage of Nations, Free Press Publ. 7 Krugman, Paul R. 1996. "Does Third World Growth Hurt First World Prosperity?" Harvard Business Review 72, pp. 113-121 8 This model is an original extension of neokeynesian models dues on Borensztein (1998), Lim (2001) Holland şi Pain (1998)- models describyng capitals effectes on net exports and Blanchard (1981), Bulir A. şi Smidkova K. (2005) (Working paper, FMI, WP/05/27) – who analyze external investition effects on domestic capital and exchange rates. 5 y* - external demand; k - capital dynamics; t – time variable; d – country debt; d - initial country external debt; nx – net commercial balance; e – exchange rate (lei/Euro); ai, i =1,17 model coefficients, that are positive, real numbers, all smaller than one. For our economy, IS-LM equations are: (1) (2) m p a1 y a2 R y a3 k a4 c a5 g a6 y * a7 f a8 e nx (LM) (IS) Real economy is described by IS equation Y C I G NX , where Y – is output, (GDP), C – consumption level, I – investments, G – public expenditures , Nx – net commercial balance (Export minus Import). We suppose also that in real sector output depend non linear on consumption, investments, government expenditure and net commercial balance: Y C a G b I c Nx d , or equivalent in logarithmic form: ln Y a ln C b ln G c ln I d ln Nx . Also, we have hypothesis: H1. The output from current period depends on total capital variation, k . H2. Production function is a neoclassical one: (3) y k . H3. Total capital K has two components: domestic investments, I ,and foreign investments F, so that K = I + F, or in logarithmic expression: (4) k = i + f. H4. Efficiency of domestic capital is equivalent with the efficiency of foreign capital. H5. There exist a direct, positive relationship between production level and investment level. H6. Consumption and government expenses have a direct, positive influence on production level. H7. External demand for domestic goods is estimated by world growth rate. H8. Net commercial balance has a direct influence on production and depends on exchange rate, world demand and the sensitivity coefficient a8. Capital dynamic equations describe two types of countries: in the first one, there exists a capital surplus, so we have tendencies to export capital and the second one that we have a capital deficit so there are capital inflows. Capital dynamics depends on: real interest rate (negative dependency), capital depreciation (negative dependency), debt level d (negative dependency) and time t (positive dependency, time historically verified). We have the capital dynamic equations (5): (5) k k * k a9 t a10 r a11 k a12 d k k * k a13 t a10 r a11 k a12 d For the UE -15 states we have a capital surplus, so that k k * , and for candidate states we have a capital deficit, so that k k * , where k * is the equilibrium level of capital for domestic economy. External debt (private and public) d, depend on: initial level of debt, d , output variation (export rise conduct to debt diminish), government expenses, g, net capital inflows and net commercial balance. (6) d d a14 y a15 f a16 g a17 e nx Remark: All variables in our model (except interest rates) are in logarithmic expression. For the negative variable (like capital flows or net commercial deficit) we consider the positive expression and the influence are described by negative coefficients. (7) Interest rate dynamic equation (or for real exchange rate) is: R R R * , or e r r * 9 In our model p*,R*,g, y*, f, d , t are exogenous variables, and : y, m,R, e, p, d are endogenous variables. 3. Solutions From equation 1 we have: 1 a1 y m p R* 1 a1 k m p R * R R R* (8) a2 a2 Capital dynamic equation is: 1 k k a4 c a5 g a6 y * a7 f a8 e nx (9) a3 Replacing in eq. 5 we obtain: 1 r k a9 t a11 k a12 d a10 1 k a9 t a11 k a12 d a14 y a15 f a16 g a17 e nx a10 1 k a9 t a11 k a12 a14 k a12 d a12 a15 f a12 a16 g a12 a17 e nx a10 So, exchange rate dynamic equation became: e E p * p . If we consider E R we have: e R R * p * p R p R * p * , so e r r * . 9 Real exchange rate is: e E p * p , so we have: (5.10) a4 a a a a c 5 g 6 y * 7 f 8 e nx a9 t 1 k a3 a3 a3 a3 a3 e a3 a10 a11 a12 a14 k a12 a15 f a12 a16 g a12 a17 e nx a12 d a a a8 a a a e 12 14 11 k nx 12 17 a10 a3 a10 a10 a10 a3 a10 a5 a4 a a c 12 16 a3 a10 a10 a3 a10 a7 a a e 12 15 f a10 a3 a10 a6 a a g 12 d y* 9 t R* a10 a3 a10 a10 Matrix form of dynamic equations is: (11) a8 a a nx 12 17 e a10 a3 a10 a8 nx k a3 a 7 a a 12 15 a a a10 3 10 a7 a3 a4 a3 a10 a4 a3 a12 a14 a 11 a10 a3 a10 a10 e k a3 a5 a a 12 16 a10 a3 a10 a5 a3 a12 a10 0 a6 a3 a10 a6 a3 a9 a10 0 f c 1 g d 0 y * t R * or x A x B u e where: x - is the matrix of state derivative variables; k e x - the state- variables matrix; k f c g u d - exogenous variable matrix; y * t R * a8 a a 12 17 nx a10 a 3 a10 A a8 nx a 3 a12 a14 a 11 a10 a 3 a10 a10 - coefficients matrix; a3 a 7 a a 12 15 a a a10 B 3 10 a7 a3 - a4 a3 a10 a4 a3 a5 a a 12 16 a10 a3 a10 a5 a3 a12 a10 0 a6 a3 a10 a6 a3 a9 a10 0 1 0 Exogenous variable coefficient matrix e 0 From system phase diagram, at stationary linear lines, , we find the equilibrium lines 0 k coefficients: a dk (12) 8 nx k 0 de dk de (13) e 0 a8 a3 a12 a17 nx 1 a3 a12 a14 a3 a11 Case I. If we have a positive commercial balance, (nx > 0) then the equilibrium lines coefficients a8 a3 a12 a17 a are positives, and for (14) 8 , the system state diagram is draw 1 a3 a12 a14 a3 a11 in Figure 1. e e 0 I IV E II k 0 III k Figure 1. The points from II and IV zones are characterized by a stable evolution versus equilibrium point E, and the points from I and III zones are in a disequilibrium situation. Case II. If we have a negative commercial balance, then the equilibrium lines coefficients are negatives. Next we analyze the system for different sizes of lines coefficients. II.a) In figure 2 is drawn the situation that coefficient of capital equilibrium line is greater like exchange rate equilibrium line coefficient. (15) a8 nx a8 a3 a12 a17 nx 1 a3 a12 a14 a3 a11 e I e 0 k 0 IV E II III k Figure 2 In this case the points from II and IV zones are in a stable situation and the points from I and III zones are unstable. II.b) Figure 3 shows the situation that the coefficient of capital equilibrium line is smaller like exchange rate equilibrium line coefficient. a8 a3 a12 a17 a8 (16) nx nx 1 a3 a12 a14 a3 a11 e e 0 I k 0 IV E II III k Figure 3 In this case we have a stable situation for every point of our map. Tr A 0 Our system is a stable system if: , respectively if the proper values of A Det A 0 matrix are negatives. From these conditions results the stability and instability zones of our model. The influence on external debt and on balance of payment deficit results from substitution in eq. 6 of previous results. Next we analyze the influence of exogenous variables on commercial balance deficit. In equation 6 exogenous variables coefficients are also the elasticities of external debt depending on output (a14), external demand (a15), government consumption (a16) and commercial balance (a17). (6) d d a14 y a15 f a16 g a17 e nx Differentiating equation 6 we find the multipliers of exogenous factors: (7) d a14 y a15 f a16 g a17 e nx a17 nx e The total effect of exchange rate and external trade volume is: (8) d a17 e nx nx e We analyze some shocks effects on capital stock, exchange rate and debt level. An unexpected shock of direct foreign investments modify also capital stock and external debt shifting the equilibrium point to the right (see Figure 4) so we have an appreciation of national currency, a rise of capital stock and also external debt level. e I e 0 k 0 IV E II III k Figure 4 Currency appreciation is instantaneous, capital stock rise in real time, but external debt variation is delayed. The effect on net export is ambiguous at the first time and depends on exchange rate variation level and capital stock variation level. Also the output level can decrease depending on external efficiency decreasing and on small rise of capital stock. But in the future capital stock continue to rise and this will affect the competitivity diminish due on currency appreciation. This aspect seems to respect the economic growth model of Central and East European transition countries10. An external demand shock also generate a currency appreciation and a capital stock diminish (see Figure 5) and a shock on external debt will appreciate domestic currency and generate a smaller capital flows to outside. e I e' 0 e 0 k' 0 IV E E’ k 0 II III Figure 5. k Shocks effects on external debt To analyze shock influences on debt we use equations 6 and 11. a) direct foreign investment shocks (f) A variation of direct foreign investment affects also capital and exchange rate. The multiplier or direct foreign investments on exchange a 7 e / f a 3 a10 a a12 a15 and on capital is: k / f 7 . a10 a3 From this we have: (9) 10 a7 a7 a a a15 a17 nx 12 15 f a10 a3 a3 a10 d a14 Vezi Bulir A. şi Smidkova K. (2005) -Working paper, FMI, WP/05/27 rate is: We observe that effects of direct foreign investments on external debt are ambiguous and depend on size of different term on equation 19. b) consumption shocks A consumption shock will affect the external debt with the multiplier (20): c If the commercial balance is negative then a rise of consumption generate a rise of external debt, and if the commercial balance is positive, then the effect of consumption rise on external debt is ambiguous. a4 a4 a17 nx a3 a3 a10 d a14 (10) c) budgetary shocks A budgetary shock g affects the external debt by the multiplier: g So the effect of budgetary shock on external debt in ambiguous because of many influences appears inside multiplier. a5 a5 a a a16 a17 nx 12 16 a10 a3 a3 a10 d a14 (11) d) External demand shocks An external demand shock will affect also capital stock and exchange rate: a a6 and k / y* 6 . a3 a10 a3 e / y* From these we have: (12) a6 a3 d a14 a6 a17 nx a3 a10 y * The total effect on external debt is ambiguous because we have a positive effect due on exchange rate and a negative effect due on capital and production rise. 4. Empirical model Data used in our model are from National Institute of Statistics, National Bank, IMF and World Bank during 1990-2003. We estimate model coefficients in E-VIEWS econometrical software. A. LM curve Figure 6 shows the real money supply and real GDP dynamics in Romania in 1990-2003 periods. From this figure we can observe that both indicators have the same shape. Correlation coefficient between m and y is 0.552 that shows a direct, strong link between money supply and GDP dynamics. 03 20 02 20 01 20 00 20 99 19 98 19 97 19 96 19 95 19 94 19 93 19 92 19 19 19 91 1000,00 800,00 600,00 400,00 200,00 0,00 90 bilions lei 1990 Money supply and GDP in Romania during 19902003 period years real money supply Real GDP(bil. Lei 1990 prices) Data sources: National Institute of Statistics, Romania, authors calculus Figure 6. Analyzing dependency between real money supply and interest rate we can observe (see Figure 7) a negative relationship between these variables. The correlation coefficient between real money supply and interest rate is -0.899 consistent with model hypothesis. years real money supply(bil.lei 1990) 03 20 02 20 01 20 00 20 99 19 97 98 19 19 96 19 95 19 94 19 93 19 92 19 19 19 91 600,00 500,00 400,00 300,00 200,00 100,00 0,00 90 billions lei, percents Real money supply and interest rates in Romania during 1990-2003 interest rate (%) Data sources: National Institute of Statistics, Romania, authors calculus Figure 7 Estimating coefficients of LM curve we obtain equation 1’: (1’) m p 0,984 y 0,323 R (LM) In this equation the theoretical hypothesis are verified because we have positive sensitivity of money supply on output (a1 = 0,984 > 0) and negative sensitivity of money supply on interest rate (a2 = 0,323 > 0). B. IS curve Romania’s economy evolution was an oscillatory one during 1990-2003. There were two business cycles (two recession periods between 1990-1992 and 1997-1999, and two growth periods between 1993-1996 and 2000-2004). Figure 8 shows this evolution. 03 20 02 20 01 20 00 20 99 19 98 19 97 19 95 96 19 19 93 94 19 92 19 19 19 19 91 1000 900 800 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 0 90 billions lei 1990 prices GDP, final consumption and government consumption in Romania during 1990-203 years GDP Final Consumption Government consumption Data sources: National Institute of Statistics, Romania, authors calculus Figure 8. Correlation coefficients between GDP and final consumption is 0.817 that indicate a direct, positive and strong relationship between GDP and consumption evolution, and a positive, but week relationship between GDP and government consumption (0.09). This can indicate that budgetary policy in Romania was an inefficient one with small effects on Romania’s economic growth. We have also a positive relationship between GDP and export levels (see Figure 9), correlation coefficient between GDP and exports (estimated by external demand) is 0.303 who respect theoretical model hypothesis. We can observe a short gap between GDP and export level, the export level start to increase one year before GDP increasing period, as a sign of economic restarting growth. 03 02 20 01 20 00 20 99 20 98 19 97 19 96 19 95 19 94 19 93 19 19 92 19 19 19 91 1000,00 800,00 600,00 400,00 200,00 0,00 90 billions lei 1990 GDP and external demand evolution in Romania during 1990-2003 years Real GDP Real external demand Data sources: National Institute of Statistics, Romania, authors calculus Figure 9. In figure 10 we can see the evolution of direct foreign investment during 1990-2003. This evolution is similar to GDP evolution, but is delayed with one year inverse like export influence, respectively the minimum point of this are one year after minimum point of GDP evolution. Also correlation coefficient between GDP and foreign investments is a positive one, 0.465. 03 20 02 20 01 20 00 20 99 19 98 19 97 19 96 19 95 19 94 19 93 19 92 19 19 19 91 200,00 180,00 160,00 140,00 120,00 100,00 80,00 60,00 40,00 20,00 0,00 90 billions lei 1990 Real foreign investitions in Romania 1990-2003 years real foreign direct investitions (bil. lei 1990) Data sources: National Institute of Statistics, Romania, authors calculus Figure 10. Commercial balance has an oscillatory evolution during 1990-2003 years, but in every year was a negative level. Election cycles generate greater deficits, like in 1996 and 2000, but the tendency is to increase the deficit level. Correlation coefficient between output and commercial balance deficit is -.54 that indicates a strong negative relationship between these variables. The relationship between output and capital dynamics was a positive one, but capital growth was much greater like output growth (see Figure 11).Correlation coefficient between output and capital growth was 0.37 that confirm theoretical hypothesis of positivness of a3 coefficient. 12 10 8 6 4 2 03 20 02 20 01 20 00 20 99 19 98 19 97 19 96 19 95 19 94 19 93 19 92 19 19 19 91 0 90 billion lei log. expression ,1990 prices GDP and capital growth in Romania during 1990-2003 years GDP capital growth Data sources: National Institute of Statistics, Romania, authors calculus Figure 11. Estimating IS- coefficients equation we obtain: (2’) y 0 ,005 k 0 ,973 c 0 ,1086 g 0 ,0843 y * 0 ,119 f 0 ,0015 e nx (IS) Both correlation coefficients and estimators of IS-equation confirm theoretical hypothesis of our model. From our model we observe that the bigger contribution to GDP dynamics was due on consumption level, then the direct foreign investment, external demand and government consumption. Commercial balance has a negative influence on GDP growth because of commercial balance deficit. C. Capital dynamics Analyzing capital dynamics we observe a permanent growth of this during 1990-2003. Correlation coefficient between capital level and time was .909 that strongly confirm model hypothesis for transition countries. Correlation coefficient between capital dynamics and interest rate was a negative one, -.334 (classical hypothesis of IS-LM model). Dynamic equation of our model is: (5‘) k 2 ,003 t 0 ,445 r 0 ,686 k 0 ,136 d Capital dynamics depend positively only on time in out equation, and inversely on interest rate, capital level and external debt. D. External debt equation Estimating external debt equation coefficients we obtain positive relationships with direct foreign investments and government consumption and negative relationships with GDP level and net export. (6’) d 0.244 y 0 ,057 f 0 ,337 g 1,031 e nx The magnitude of coefficients shows that the bigger contribution to external debt is due on commercial balance deficit and government consumption, and foreign investment contribute in a small measure to external debt growth. E. Production function Estimating neoclassical production function (3) coefficient we obtains for y k : is equal to 0,737. Synthesis of model coefficients: a1 = 0,984; a2 = 0,323; a3 = 0,005; a4 = 0,973; a5 = 0,1086; a6 = 0,0843; a7 = 0,119; a8 = 0,0015; a9 = 2,003; a10 = 0,445; a11 = 0,686; a12 = 0,136; a14 = 0,228; a15 = 0,602; a16 = 0,286; a17 = 0,374; = 0,737. 5. Model analysis Starting on model equations and coefficients estimations we determine system diagram for Romania’s economy. State variable coefficients A is: a8 a a 12 17 nx a10 a 3 a10 A a8 nx a 3 a12 a14 a 11 a10 a 3 a10 a10 4 ,13 = 1,253 a3 and command variable matrix coefficients B is: 332 ,72 147 ,4 a 7 a a 12 15 a a a10 B 3 10 a7 a3 53,46 437 ,30 23,8 194 ,6 a4 a3 a10 a4 a3 a5 a a 12 16 a10 a3 a10 a5 a3 48 ,70 0 ,305 37 ,88 4 ,501 21,72 0 16 ,86 0 a12 a10 0 a6 a3 a10 a6 a3 a9 a10 0 1 = 0 1 0 Equilibrium line coefficients were in 2003: dk de k 0 a8 dk de e 0 a8 a3 a12 a17 nx = -0.01242 1 a3 a12 a14 a3 a11 nx = - 0.0085 Graphical and analytical analysis shows that Romania’s economy was in 2003 in III zone of case II (a commercial balance in deficit) (see Figure 12). Equilibrium capital coefficient line k 0 is greater like equilibrium exchange rate coefficient line e 0 , (-0,0085 > -0,01242) so we can obtain also a stable situation or an unstable situation. But from Tr (A) = 143,37 > 0, and Det(A) = -192,14, we obtain a positive proper value and a negative proper value of A matrix, and that means an unstable system. In fact, for 2004 and 2005 years we expect a capital rise and an exchange rate appreciation, like a partial confirmation of Balassa-Samuelson effect. e I e 0 k 0 IV E II III k Figure 12 Foreign investment variation influence In our theoretical model foreign investments has an unambiguous influence on external debt (see equation 24), but for Romania we obtain: a a7 a a (24) d a14 7 a15 a17 nx 12 15 f = - 225,985 f a10 a3 a3 a10 This value shows that we have a reduction of external debt for increasing external investments especially due on production increase. Consumption variation influence Consumption growth has always a positive influence on external debt growth, but we are interested on size of influence. For Romania, this influence is very strong (see eq. 25) and that indicate a final consumption rise is strongly oriented versus imported goods, not to domestic goods. (25) a4 a3 d a14 a4 a17 nx a3 a10 c = 1918,358 c Government consumption influence Government consumption has also a strong positive influence on external debt (see eq. 26), even that in theoretical model we have an unambiguous effect. For Romania any budgetary shock generates an important rise of external deficit, so that a reduction of government consumption is a good instrument for debt reduction. External demand shock An external demand shock, in a situation of negative net export, will increase external debt of Romania. (27) a6 a3 d a14 a6 a17 nx a3 a10 y * = 166,205 y* But this influence is less important like others shocks discussed previously. 6. Conclusions Romania’s economy has a complex evolution in last 15 years. There are extended changes at every level of social, political and economical life: over 60% private propriety in economy, 4 different political parties won different elections, but especially existence of two completed business cycles in economy. External debt of Romania, but also for other countries, became an important problem in economical dynamics. Is it possible to control and influence them? IMF papers indicate that the proporttion of externat debt in GDP is important, not absolute size of external debt. More, the debt level is influenced by export proportion in GDP, and sustainable debt depend on this this proportion. For the countries with over 40% export proportion in GDP is possible to obtain a 65% level of sustainable debt in GDP, and for countries with 30-40% export proportion in GDP it is a 53% proportion of sustainable debt in GDP11. Romania’s economy is in the second situation, but the actual proportion of external debt in GDP is around 30%, so it is exists 20-25% possibility to extend actual debt level. In our model we try to explain influence of different shocks on external debt and on exchange rate and how different politics can influence this level. The main conclusion of our analysis is that budgetary politics is not efficient to influence external debt. Fiscal and monetary policies are more efficient for Romanian government instead to control the debt level. References 1. Bahmani,Oskooe and Rhee (1996)– Time series Support for Balassa’s Productivity / bias Hypothesis: Evidence for Korea, Review Economics , 4 2. Balassa-Samuelson effect analyze exchange rates variations dues on relative productivities differences between exported goods on international markets. 3. Bulir A. şi Smidkova K. (2005) Exchange rates in new EU accesion countries: What are we learned from the forerunners, (Working paper, FMI, WP/05/27) 4. Drine , I, Rault, C.(2002) – Panel data analysis of the Balassa-Samuelson effect hypothesis, Sorbonne University 5. Halpern,L., Wyplosy, C (2001) – Economic transformation and real exchange rate in the 2000’s : The Balassa-Samuelson Connection – United Nation Economic Commission for Europe, (UN/ECE), Geneve, sept. 2001 6. Krugman, Paul R. (1996) "Does Third World Growth Hurt First World Prosperity?" Harvard Business Review 72, pp. 113-121 7. Lafrance & Schembri (2000)- http://www. bank-banque-canada.ca/publications/review 8. Porter, M.E. (1998)- The Competitive Advantage of Nations, Free Press Publ. 9. Tiganescu, E., Roman, M. (2005) Macroeconomie. O abordare cantitativa, Ed. Economica, Bucharest 10. *** National Institute of Statistics Bookyear, 2004,2003, 2002. Bulir A. şi Smidkova K. (2005) - Exchange rates in the New EU Accesion Countries : What Have We Learned from the Rorerunners, (Working paper, FMI, WP/05/27), p. 16 11