Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Questions for Test 1 ECO 320 Economics of Development Chapter 1 1. Developing countries share some features (low levels of income, etc.), but they are quite different in many respects. Explain what we mean by “institutions” and how is it that developing countries different in institutional development. How would the differences in the development of institutions make it more difficult to formulate policies for development and theories of development? 2. Is there a fixed set of prerequisites for development? Explain. Chapter 2 3. Comment on the following statement: The level and growth rate of real GDP per capita can be a misleading indicator of development. At the same time, countries that experience sustained increases in real GDP per capita over time will tend to be more developed. 4. Why is an understanding of what “development” means crucial to policy formulation in developing nations? Why do you think a country may have difficulties in agreeing on a rough definition of development? 5. Why do we use “purchasing power parity” measures when comparing incomes across countries? 6. Suppose that you had to explain this graph to someone who is not a “visual learner” – he just doesn’t get pictures. You have to explain every feature of the graph using words. 7. What are the components of the Human Development Index? What are some strengths and weaknesses of the HDI as a comparative measure of human welfare? 8. Discuss the Millennium Development Goals. How can the mere act of adopting these goals as aims of action be beneficial for economic development? Chapter 3 9. What does it mean to say that “factor accumulation” and “productivity growth” are important for development? How are they distinct? 10. Most growth models assume that new investment increases the capital stock, that investment is financed by saving, and that saving comes from income. a. What is the role of depreciation in determining the level of capital stock in the future? What can prevent investment from producing the desired amount of capital? b. What are the mechanisms (public, private) that can turn saving into investment? What could prevent people’s savings from being invested productively for the accumulation of new capital? What other uses could a country give to people’s saving besides capital accumulation? c. Besides income of domestic residents, from where else could saving come? What are ways in which governments could get people to save more (consume less) out of their income? 11. 12. Explain this equation gY WK g K 1 WK g L a . What are the limits to this approach to calculating the factors that contribute to economic growth? An economy is characterized by the following figures. Calculate the economy’s Total Factor Productivity growth rate. gY 3.3% gL 1.7% gK 4.9% WK 0.29 a 13. Discuss the five characteristics of rapidly growing countries identified in the book. 14. “Social and institutional innovations are as important for economic growth as technological and scientific inventions and innovations. Effective institutions are as important as technological efficiency.” What is meant by these statements? Explain your answer. 15. What does “convergence” mean? Which countries have “converged”? 16. Why does agriculture decline as a share of GDP as the country becomes richer? Why are increases in agricultural productivity necessary for structural change? Chapter 4 17. Suppose the capital-output ratio is 3, the depreciation rate of capital is 5% and the gross savings rate is 15%. a. Use the Harrod-Domar growth equation to determine the rate of growth. b. What policies would have to be implemented to change the gross savings rate to achieve 4% growth? What role could be played by foreign aid or private capital inflows? c. What policies would have to be implemented to change the capital-labor ratio (keeping the gross saving rate constant) to achieve 4% growth? 18. Suppose that all countries have the same rate of technological progress, the same depreciation rate, and the same population growth rate. Also assume that the 1/ 3 production function in every country is y f k k d. Use the production function to derive a formula for the ratio of GDP per worker in the steady state that is predicted by the Solow model. e. For each country pair below, calculate the ratio of GDP per worker in the steady state that is predicted by the Solow model. Then calculate the actual ratio of GDP per worker for each pair of countries. For output per worker in 2005 (y), use the 2005 value for “GNI per capita, PPP (current international $)” from the World Development Indicators. For the Investment Rate (s), use the 1975-2003 average for “Gross capital formation (% of GDP).” Country Investment Rate (average 1960-2000) Thailand Bolivia 29.4% 10.1% Country Investment Rate (average 1960-2000) Nigeria Turkey 7.5% 14.9% Country Investment Rate (average 1960-2000) Japan New Zeland 31.1% 21.0% Ratio of y* predicted by Solow model Output per Worker in 2000 Actual ratio of y Difference between predicted and actual Actual ratio of y Difference between predicted and actual Actual ratio of y Difference between predicted and actual $12,086 $7,152 Ratio of y* predicted by Solow model Output per Worker in 2000 $1,906 $15,726 Ratio of y* predicted by Solow model Output per Worker in 2000 $69,235 $40,176 f. For which pairs of countries does the Solow model do a good job in predicting relative income? g. For which pairs does it do a poor job? 19. 20. A country is described by the Solow model, with a production function of y f k k 1/ 2 . Suppose that k is equal to 400. The fraction of output invested is 50%. The depreciation rate is 5%. Is the country as its steady-state level of outputper-worker, above the steady state, or below the steady state? Show how you reached your conclusion. In a country the production function is y f k k . The fraction of output invested, s, is 0.25. The depreciation rate, d, is 0.05. h. What are the steady-state levels of capital per worker, k, and output per worker, y? i. In year 1, the level of capital per worker is 16. In a table like the following one, show how capital and output change over time (the beginning is filled in as a demonstration). Continue this table up to year 8. 1/ 2 Year 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Capital Output Investment Depreciation k 16 16.2 y k sy 1 dk 0.8 4 Change in Capital Stock sy - dk 0.2 j. Calculate the growth rate of output between years 1 and 2. Remember that a growth rate of output is calculated as Yt Yt 1 Yt 1 . k. Calculate the growth rate of output between years 7 and 8. l. How do the answers to parts c and d suggest “convergence”? 21. Consider the article at the bottom of this document (from The Economist) about two East Asian countries. Then answer the following questions. a. How important is the assumption of a diminishing marginal product of capital (as more capital is accumulated for given labor) in the conclusions of the Solow growth model? b. What evidence can we glean from Young's study about the empirical evidence on diminishing returns? c. One of Young's main points has to do with the allocation of capital in the two countries. Singapore's capital has been largely allocated by the government through its huge pension funds, to which all workers must contribute. In Hong Kong, virtually all capital is privately allocated. Governments sometimes have different objectives than private investors. To what extent can this difference explain the difference in the rate of capital accumulation and the productivity of capital in the two countries? d. The article was written in 1992. Considering the following graph, do you think that the article’s predictions have come true? 20% 15% 10% 5% -5% East Asian financial crisis -10% Hong Kong, China Singapore 20 06 20 05 20 04 20 03 20 02 20 01 20 00 19 99 19 98 19 97 19 96 19 95 19 94 19 93 19 92 19 91 19 90 19 89 19 88 19 87 19 86 19 85 19 84 19 83 19 82 19 81 0% 22. In the Fei-Ranis model, the “traditional” sector (e.g., food) has many more workers than it needs (it has a labor surplus) so it can reduce the number of workers without reducing output (there’s “excess population”). This means that average wages are very low, and the “modern” (e.g., manufacturing) sector can hire workers at low wages, taking more workers out of the traditional as the modern sector expands. e. As the modern sector hires more workers, the labor surplus becomes smaller. What happens to wages in the modern sector when the labor surplus disappears? What do you think will happen to modern production, profits, and investment in the modern sector after that point? f. What is likely to happen to wages in the country if the productivity of the food sector improves, lowering food prices? Explain how that should help industrialization. Chapter 5 23. What have we learned about the effects of imposing price and wage controls, of deficit spending, trade tariffs, and subsidies? 24. What have we learned about the effects of government regulation of markets and privately owned industries? 25. What have we learned about government use of fiscal vs. monetary policy in promoting economic growth? 26. Compare the benefits and drawbacks of nationalizing private enterprises and turning them into state-owned industries. 27. Compare the benefits and risks in re-privatizing state-owned industries. WHERE HONG KONG HAS THE EDGE Dateline: FROM OUR HONG KONG CORRESPONDENT The Economist August 22, 1992 ONE of the most momentous and least understood events of this half-century is East Asia's rise from poverty. The high rates of economic growth consistently achieved over decades by the Asian tigers--Hong Kong, Singapore, Taiwan and South Korea--have almost no equal anywhere at any time. Growth theory has trouble explaining this. The difficulty is compounded by the wide divergence in circumstances and economic policies of the four countries. Alwyn Young, a business professor at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, has written a paper* looking at how Hong Kong and Singapore did it. If his analysis is right, it augurs ill for Singapore in the next decade or two. Hong Kong and Singapore started on a similar footing in 1945. Both were city-states, British colonies (with a British legal and administrative system) making their living as trading ports. Neither manufactured much. Both were populated mainly with immigrants from southern China. In 1960 the two territories had roughly the same GDP per head, which over the following quarter-century grew at an astonishing and virtually identical 6% a year in real terms. Both were free traders, allowing foreign goods and money to flow where they would. Both climbed the same industrial ladder, moving up from textiles to plastics to consumer electronics to financial services. There were two crucial differences. First, Hong Kong, its population luckily swollen by sophisticated Shanghainese refugees from Communist China, had a vastly better educated population than Singapore's until well into the 1980s. Second, Hong Kong had a laisserfaire government (to the point of not investing even in needed infrastructure until street riots forced it to); Singapore had an extremely interventionist one. The government decided which industries Singapore should go into and when. Through its Central Provident Fund levies on companies and workers, it compelled private savings of around 40% of GDP. Through state-owned companies and boards the government channelled much of these savings, as well as its large excess of current tax revenues over current spending, into investment it favoured. It welcomed, indeed heavily subsidised, direct investment by foreign multinationals. The sources of growth in the two territories turned out to be startlingly different. Between 1960 and 1985 Hong Kong saved and invested a more or less consistent 20% of GDP. Singapore, which in 1960 invested half as much as Hong Kong, surpassed it in 1967 and has invested a larger share ever since: by the late 1980s Singapore's investment as a share of GDP was more than 40%, more than twice Hong Kong's rate. In the two decades after 1970, Hong Kong's output per worker went up more than 2.5 times, Singapore's a little more than twofold. Not much difference there. However, Hong Kong's output per unit of capital stayed roughly constant over the 20 years; Singapore's was more than halved (see chart). The alarm bells about Singapore's use (or misuse) of capital keep ringing louder. By the mid-1980s Singapore's incremental capital-output ratio--meaning how much extra capital was needed to produce an additional unit of output--was twice Hong Kong's. As you would expect from an ever-increasing use of capital, Singapore's return on capital, which in the early 1960s had been 40%, by the late 1980s had fallen to 11-12%, one of the lowest rates in the world. Most damning of all, Mr Young finds that over the two decades after 1970, 56% of Hong Kong's increase in output per worker came from a rise in ``total factor productivity'' (how much can be produced by combining given units of land, labour and capital). Singapore's total factor productivity fell by 6% over those years: in other words, 106% of Singapore's growth in output came from adding capital. To put it crudely, Hong Kong got richer by becoming a lot more efficient in the way it used people, capital and technology. Singapore became richer by thrusting its hands ever deeper into its citizens' pockets-through taxes, forced savings and subsidies to multinationals--and throwing the money at the problem. Economic-growth buffs will find it interesting that Hong Kong seemed to benefit so much from the better education of its people. For Singapore, however, Mr Young's analysis has a gruesome and more or less immediate practical implication. If he is right, Singapore has very few years of growth left along the old lines: it simply cannot extract much more savings from its people--already the biggest savers in the world--to support its growing craving for capital. Mr Young's cruel comparison is to the Soviet Union, which turned in respectable growth rates from the 1930s to the 1960s by pouring on the capital. Everyone knows what happened after that. *A tale of two cities: Factor accumalation and technical change in Hongkong and Singapore", to be published in the "Macroeconomics Annual" (1992) of the National Bureau of Economic Research.