Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
AJAE Appendix for “Brand-Supermarket Demand for Breakfast Cereals and Retail Competition” Benaissa Chidmi and Rigoberto A. Lopez Date: July 2006 Note: The material contained herein is supplementary to the article named in the title and published in the American Journal of Agricultural Economics (AJAE). Appendix: Estimation Procedure The integral in equation (5) does not have a closed formula and cannot be solved analytically. It must be solved numerically by simulation methods. The basic idea is to choose parameters that minimize the distance between the predicted and observed market shares. To this end, the estimation objective is to (A1) Min s ( p, x, ) S , where s (.) denotes predicted market shares (from equation 5) and S denotes observed market shares. However, this approach implies a costly non-linear minimization procedure because most parameters enter (A1) in a non-linear manner. To avoid this difficulty, Berry (1994) suggests inverting the market share function giving the mean utility valuation (see equation 4) that equates the predicted market shares with observed market shares s( . ; 2 ) S. , where 2 ( , , , ) is a vector of parameters that enter the indirect utility function non-linearly. Once the mean utility valuation is obtained (from a standard logit model, for example), the next step is to define the error term as the deviation from that mean. That is, (A1) j j (S j ; 2 ) ( pj xj ). (A2) The error is then interacted with instruments to form the objective function to minimize using the generalized methods of moments (GMM) estimation. More specifically, following Nevo (2000), the estimation steps are: Step 1: Prepare the data to use for the estimation. The data are of two categories: (1) the market data, including market shares, prices, product characteristics, advertising and promotion, and (2) the distributions of consumer characteristics, including demographic characteristics D and the unobserved consumer characteristics that enter in the random part of the indirect utility. Step 2: Given starting values for distributions of D and 2 , the mean valuation utility and the draws from the , compute the predicted market shares. Nevo (2001) propose using the smooth estimator that makes use of the extreme value distribution on f ( ) to integrate ’s analytically. The predicted market shares are then approximated by (A3) s j ( p , x, , ; 2) 1 n n sij i 1 1 n exp( n j ij ) , J i 1 1 exp( m im ) m 1 where n is the number of draws from the distributions of D and per time period. In our case, n=100 per time period or 3,500 for all 35 periods in the sample. Step3: The computation of the predicted market shares will allow computing the mean utility valuation that equates the predicted market shares with observed market shares. This is an iterative step and is solved numerically due to the non-linearity of the inversion of the equation s( . ; 2 ) S. . BLP (1995) suggest using the contracting mapping theorem, which yields: t 1 (A3) t ln(S ) ln(s( p, x, ; 2 (A4) ), where s (.) is the predicted market shares computed by equation A3 and T is the smallest integer such that T T 1 is smaller than some tolerance level. Step 4: The error term is computed using the equation X 1 1 , where is the mean utility valuations computed in the previous step; X 1 is a matrix that regroups the variables that enter the indirect utility function linearly, including the observed product characteristics and the price; and 1 ( , ) is the vector of parameters that enter linearly in the indirect utility function. The error term is then interacted with the instruments to form the objective function to be minimized using the GMM estimation (A3) ( )' ZA 1 Z ' ( ) , f (A5) where ( 1, 2 ) is the vector of parameters to be estimated; Z is a matrix of instruments; and A is a consistent estimate of E[ Z ' which are the parameters reported in Table 1. ' Z ] . The solution to A5 yields * References Berry, S. T. 1994. “Estimating Discrete-Choice Models of Product Differentiation.” Rand Journal of Economics 25(2):242-262. Berry, S., J. Levinsohn and A. Pakes. 1995. “Automobile Prices in Market Equilibrium.” Econometrica 63(4):841-890. Nevo A. 2000. “A Practitioner’s Guide to Estimation of Random Coefficients Logit Models of Demand,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 9, No. 4, pp.513-548. _____. 2001. “Measuring Market Power in the Ready-To-Eat Cereal Industry.” Econometrica 69(2): 307-342.