* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download del11 Philippopoulos 16784773 en
Economics of digitization wikipedia , lookup
History of macroeconomic thought wikipedia , lookup
Steady-state economy wikipedia , lookup
Rostow's stages of growth wikipedia , lookup
Fei–Ranis model of economic growth wikipedia , lookup
Heckscher–Ohlin model wikipedia , lookup
Fiscal multiplier wikipedia , lookup
Economic calculation problem wikipedia , lookup
Production for use wikipedia , lookup
Microeconomics wikipedia , lookup
CESifo-Delphi Conferences on EMU: The way forward Municipal Hall “Melina Merkouri”, Hydra Island 23-24 September 2011 Public providers, or private providers, of public goods? A general equilibrium study Apostolis Philippopoulos, George Economides and Vangelis Vassilatos Public providers, or private providers, of public goods? A general equilibrium study September 1, 2011 George Economides*, Apostolis Philippopoulos, and Vangelis Vassilatos* Abstract: This paper studies the difference between public production and public finance of public goods in a dynamic general equilibrium model. By public production, the public good is produced by the government itself using public employees and goods purchased from the private sector as inputs. By public finance, the public good is produced by cost-minimizing private providers with the government financing their costs. When the model is calibrated to match fiscal data from the UK economy, we find that a switch from public production to public finance has substantial aggregate and distributional implications. Public providers cannot beat private providers in terms of aggregate efficiency. The key policy message is that there are Pareto benefits from a mix of reforms that combines: (i) a transition to costminimizing private providers that allows the government to achieve efficiency savings (ii) redistributive transfers that compensate those previously working as public employees (ii) a reduction in distorting income taxes made affordable by efficiency savings. Keywords: Public goods, growth, welfare. JEL classification: H4, D9, D6. Acknowledgements: We thank Kostas Angelopoulos, Fabrice Collard, Saqib Jafarey, Jim Malley, Dimitris Papageorgiou, Evi Pappa, Hyun Park and Heraklis Polemarchakis for discussions and comments. We also thank seminar participants at Bilgi University, Istanbul. Any remaining errors are ours. * Athens University of Economics and Business. Athens University of Economics and Business, and CESifo. Corresponding author: Apostolis Philippopoulos, Department of Economics, Athens University of Economics and Business, 76 Patission street, Athens 10434, Greece. Tel: 0030-210-8203357, fax: 0030-2108203301, email: [email protected] 1. Introduction Concerning the provision of public goods and services, an important distinction is between public production and public finance. In the former case, the goods are produced by the government itself. In particular, the government hires public employees and purchases final goods from the private sector to produce public goods and services. In the latter case, public goods and services are produced by private firms, the so-called private providers, with the government financing the cost of production of an agreed-upon quantity. Examples of public goods and services that can belong to either category include hospitals, television and radio, schools, prisons, environmental protection, most services provided by local authorities, etc. The issue of public goods provision has attracted increasing interest in both academic and policy circles. In academia, production and finance are two distinct ways of public goods provision. For instance, in their early classic textbook, Atkinson and Stiglitz (1980, p. 482) emphasize that “the two are often confused, though both logically and in practice they are distinct”.1 In policy, there is a big debate nowadays on the role of the state and, in particular, the idea of opening up public services to new providers. For instance, in the UK, reforms are designed to encourage “any qualified provider of public goods” (The Observer, 22.05.2011, p. 7) and “across much of the public sector, from health and education to local authorities and prisoner rehabilitation, the provision of public services is increasingly being contracted out to private suppliers” (The Economist, January 22nd, 2011, p. 41). But, at the same time, the British Deputy PM, Nick Clegg, questions private sector involvement saying that the real issue is about “diversifying providers” and that this does not extend to a belief “that private providers are inherently better than publicsector providers” (The Guardian, 10 February 2011, p. 15). What are the implications of switching from public production to public finance? Can public providers beat private providers? Is this switch good for the general interest and bad for public employees? If yes, is there a mix of reforms that can be good for both private and public employees? The present paper tries to answer the above questions. To the best of our knowledge, so far there has not been an attempt to study, and quantify, the differences between public production and public finance in a dynamic general equilibrium setup. We fill this gap by 1 There is a rich taxonomy of public goods and services depending on the way of provision, financing and distribution. See e.g. Cullis and Jones (1998, chapter 5). 1 studying issues of both efficiency and redistribution, where efficiency has to do with per capita output and welfare, while redistribution refers to differences in income and welfare between private and public employees. When one studies reforms, efficiency gains need to be traded-off against distributional implications. We build upon the neoclassical growth model. We first model the case of public production. Following a growing macroeconomic literature (see e.g. Ardagna, 2007), there are two distinct groups of households: those that work in the private sector and those that are employed in the public sector. The latter (called public employees), together with goods purchased from the private sector, are used as inputs in the government production function. Calibrating the model to match the tax-spending data of the UK economy over 1990-2010, we solve it and specify, among other variables, the time-path of public goods as induced by the existing tax-spending policy mix. Then, using this “status quo” solution as a point of departure, we study what would change if, other things equal, the same time-path of public goods were produced by private firms, the so-called private providers. These firms produce the amount of public goods ordered by the government by solving a cost-minimization problem with the government financing their total cost. We also study the case in which the same amount of public goods continues to be produced by the public sector but now, again other things equal, public firms minimize their costs like their private counterparts do in the case of public finance.2 These three model economies (namely, the status quo one, the one with cost-minimizing private providers and the one with cost-minimizing public providers) are directly comparable. It is worth emphasizing that, for comparability reasons, we assume that, not only the amount of public goods produced, but also the number of households employed in the production of public goods, remains the same across all regimes. There are four main results. First, a switch from the status quo economy to an economy with cost-minimizing private providers increases the welfare of private employees but makes public employees worse off; the latter happens because the wages of those involved in the production of public goods falls when it is private providers that supply these goods. The same switch allows the government to make efficiency savings. Second, the effect of this switch on per capita output and per capita welfare depends crucially on the method of public financing. When the efficiency savings achieved by the government through the use of private providers - are used to cut distorting income taxes, then per capita 2 This is similar to what Atkinson and Stiglitz (1980, chapter 15.3) call public production efficiency in the sense that the state enterprise chooses its optimal mix of inputs. 2 output and welfare also rise. Third, when we assume that it is public providers/enterprises that choose inputs in a cost-minimizing way, the solution is very similar to the status quo case in which the associated variables are exogenously set at their data averages. This seems to imply that in the UK, over 1990-2018, the public sector has exhausted its role, at least in terms of aggregate efficiency, as a provider of public goods and services. Fourth, since, depending also on the public financing method, there can be aggregate efficiency gains from switching to private providers, we show that the government can design a redistributive transfer scheme that makes everybody better off relative to the status quo, including those previously employed in the public sector. Although we are aware that one should treat quantitative results with caution, our key policy implication is robust and, we believe, intuitive: If the government wants to increase the aggregate pie and also make everybody better off, then it should adopt a mix of reforms that: (i) assigns the production of public goods and services to cost-minimizing private providers (ii) redistributes transfers to compensate those previously employed as public employees (iii) uses the efficiency savings, achieved through the use of private providers, to cut distorting income taxes. We wish to clarify two things at the outset. First, we focus on polar cases. For instance, in the status quo economy, we assume that there is public production only. But we are aware that actually some public services have been contracted out to private suppliers already. At the other end, in the reformed economy, we assume that there are private providers only with the government financing their costs. But we are aware that some public production is always desirable (e.g. police and courts). In any case, our main results are not expected to be affected by the presence, or not, of such public goods; one could take them as given, and then compare public production versus public finance of the remaining public goods. Second, we do not take a stance on the socially optimal amount of public goods. We just take the size/mix of public spending, the share of public employees in population, and the tax rates, as in the data, and compute the induced amount of public goods by using a relatively standard general equilibrium model. In turn, we ask what would have happened in the case in which the same amount of public goods, socially optimal or not, were supplied by cost-minimizing firms with the government just financing their costs. This is consistent with the Mirrlees Review in the UK (Mirrlees et al 2010, 2011) that also takes public spending as 3 given and looks at the efficiency of the tax system. Here, similarly, we look at the efficiency of the system of public goods provision.3 The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 models the status quo case of public production. Section 3 models the case of private providers. Their long-run comparison is in Section 4. Section 5 asks whether public providers can beat private providers. Section 6 looks for Pareto improving policy packages. Section 7 studies transitional dynamics. Section 8 reports on robustness. Section 9 closes the paper. 2. An economy with public production of public goods We add public employees, used as an input in the production of public goods and services, to the baseline neoclassical growth model. Consider a two-sector general equilibrium model in which private firms choose capital and labor supplied by private employees to produce a private good, while the government purchases part of the private good and hires public employees to produce a public good. The latter provides utility-enhancing services to all households. The private good is converted into the public good by a production function so that each can be expressed in the same units. To finance total public spending, including the cost of the public good, the government levies distorting taxes and issues bonds. Thus, irrespectively of the producer, we assume that public goods are provided freely without user charges.4 For simplicity, the model is deterministic. Time is discrete and infinite. Our model in this section is similar to that used by most of the related macroeconomic literature (in particular, Ardagna, 2007), in the sense that the roles of private and public employees are distinct, there is no labor mobility between the private and public sector, and economic policy is exogenous.5 3 For an early review of models on the optimum provision of public goods, see Atkinson and Stiglitz (1980, chapters 15 and 16). See e.g. Angelopoulos et al (2011a, b) for exogenous policy reforms in the UK economy based on computable general equilibrium models. 4 See also e.g. Atkinson and Stiglitz (1980, chapter 16) for public goods provided without charge to all members of society. On the other hand, in chapter 15, the same authors study the pricing of publicly provided (private) goods. 5 Fernández-de-Córdoba et al (2010) provide a survey of this literature. On the other hand, see Quadrini and Trigari (2008) for job search and matching mechanisms. 4 2.1 Population composition and agents’ economic roles Total population is N t at time t . Among N t , there are p 1, 2,..., N tp identical households that work in the private sector and b 1, 2,..., N tb identical households that work in the public sector, where N tb N tp N t . There are also f 1, 2,..., N t f identical private firms. The number of private firms equals the number of households that work in the private sector, Nt f N tp , or equivalently each household employed in the private sector owns one private firm. This population composition allows us to avoid scale or size effects in equilibrium. The population sizes, N t and N tb , or equivalently the share of public employees in population, N tb , are exogenous (defined below). Nt tb Thus, there are four agents in the economy: households that work in the private sector (private employees), households that work in the public sector (public employees), private firms that produce the private good and are owned by private employees, and a consolidated public sector that also produces the public good. All households consume, work, and can save in capital and bonds subject to transaction costs. Note that, by allowing both groups of households to participate in asset markets, we enrich the related literature in which either public employees do not save (see e.g. Ardagna, 2007), or there is a representative household that allocates its work time between working in the private and the public sector (see e.g. Finn, 1998, Cavallo, 2005, Pappa, 2009, Linnemann, 2009, Forni et al, 2009, and Fernández-de-Córdoba et al, 2010). Also note that, since the focus of the paper is on the implications of policy reforms, we construct the baseline model, and choose its parameterization, so as private and public employees differ only in the way their wages are formed rather than in other ways like participation, or not, in asset markets. 2.2 Households working in the private sector The lifetime utility of each household working in the private sector, p 1, 2,..., N tp , is: u (c t t 0 p t , etp , Yt g ) (1) 5 where ctp and etp are p ’s consumption and work hours respectively; Yt g is per capita public goods and services;6 and 0 1 is a time preference parameter. The period utility function is (see also e.g. Christiano and Eichenbaum, 1992): u (ctp , utp , Yt g ) log(ctp Yt g ) (etp )1 1 (2) where , , 0 are preference parameters. Thus, ctp Yt g is composite consumption, where public goods and services influence private utility through the parameter . Each household p enters period t with predetermined holdings of physical capital and government bonds, ktp and btp , whose gross returns are rt and t respectively. The within-period budget constraint of each p is: (1 tc )ctp itp dtp (1 tk )(rt ktp tp ) (1 tl ) wtp etp t btp Gttr , p (3a) where itp is savings in the form of physical capital; dtp is savings in the form of government bonds; tp is dividends received from private firms;7 wtp is the wage rate in the private sector; Gttr , p is government transfers to each p ; and 0 tk , tl , tc 1 are tax rates on capital income, labor income and private consumption respectively. Regarding notation, note that economy-wide quantities, which are treated as given by private agents, are denoted by capital-letters. The laws of motion of physical capital and government bonds for each p are: k 6 p t 1 (1 )kt it Thus, Yt g p p p , k kt p 2 2 Yt (3b) Yt g , where Yt g is total public goods and services (see below). Nt 7 We assume that only private employees receive dividends from private firms (see (3a) and (6a) below). This is unimportant because, for simplicity, there are no profits in equilibrium. We report that our main results do not depend on having profits or not. 6 p t 1 b bt dt p p p ,b btp 2 2 Yt (3c) where 0 1 is the capital depreciation rate; p ,k , p ,b 0 capture the transaction costs paid by each p associated with participation in the capital and bond market respectively; and Yt denotes per capita output.8 Regarding transaction costs, p , k , p ,b 0 , similar quadratic cost functions have been used by e.g. Persson and Tabellini (1992), Benigno (2009) and Angelopoulos et al (2011b). The usefulness of such transaction costs is that they allow us to avoid unit roots in the transition path and get a solution for the portfolio share of each agent in the long run (see below for details). None of our qualitative results depend on these transaction costs. Each p chooses {ctp , ktp1 , btp1 , etp }t0 taking factor prices, economy-wide quantities and policy variables as given. The first-order conditions are written in Appendix A. 2.3 Households working in the public sector (public employees) Public employees are modeled similarly to private employees. Thus, the lifetime utility of each household working in the public sector, b 1, 2,..., N tb , is: u (c , e , Y t t 0 b t b t t g ) (4) where u (ctb , utb , Yt g ) log(ctb Yt g ) (etb )1 1 (5) The within-period budget constraint of each b is: (1 tc )ctb itb dtb (1 tk )rt ktb (1 tl ) wtg etb t btb Gttr ,b 8 Thus, Yt Yt , where Yt is total output in the economy (see below). Nt 7 (6a) where wtg is the wage rate in the public sector; and Gttr ,b is government transfers to each b . The laws of motion of physical capital and government bonds for each b are: b t 1 (1 )k i b t 1 b d k b b t b t b t b t b ,k ktb 2 2 Yt b ,b btb (6b) 2 2 Yt (6c) where b ,k , b ,b 0 capture the transaction costs paid by each b associated with participation in the capital and bond market respectively. Each b chooses {ctb , ktb1 , btb1 , etb }t0 taking factor prices, economy-wide quantities and policy variables as given. The first-order conditions are as in Appendix A if we replace the superscript p with the superscript b . 2.4 Firms in the private sector In each period, each private firm f 1, 2,..., N t f chooses capital and labor inputs, kt f and etf , to maximize profits: t f ytf rt kt f wtp etf (7) where output is produced by a CRS Cobb-Douglas function: ytf A(kt f ) (etf )1 (8) where A 0 and 0 1 are parameters.9 Each f chooses kt f and etf taking factor prices as given. The standard first-order conditions of this static problem are written in Appendix B. 9 We could assume that public goods provide productivity-enhancing services in addition to utility-enhancing ones (see e.g. Ardagna, 2007, in a similar model). We report that our main results do not change. 8 2.5 Government budget constraint The within-period budget constraint of the government is (quantities are in aggregate terms): Gtg Gtw Gttr , p Gttr ,b (1 t ) Bt Bt 1 Tt (9a) where Gtg is total public spending on goods and services purchased from the private sector; Gtw is total public wage payments; Gttr , p and Gttr ,b are respectively transfers to all private and all public employees;10 Bt is the beginning-of-period total stock of government bonds; and Tt denotes total tax revenues, where: Tt tc ( N tp ctp N tb ctb ) tk rt ( N tp ktp N tb ktb ) + tk N tp tp tl ( wtp N tp etp wtg N tb etb ) (9b) In other words, we include the same types of government spending as in e.g. Alesina et al (2002), namely, purchases of goods and services from the private sector, the public wage bill and transfers to individuals. We also include the three main types of taxes, namely, taxes on consumption, capital income and labor income. Inspection of (9a-b) implies that, in each period, there are nine policy instruments ( Gtg , Gtw , Gttr , p , Gttr ,b , tc , tk , tl , Bt 1 , N tb ) out of which only eight can be set independently, with the ninth following residually to satisfy the government budget constraint. As in most of the related literature, we will start by assuming that the adjusting policy instrument is the end-of-period public debt, Bt 1 , so that the other eight policy instruments can be set exogenously (their processes are defined below). For convenience, concerning spending Gtg Gtw w policy instruments, we will work in terms of their GDP shares, s , st , Yt Yt g t sttr , p Gttr , p tr ,b Gttr ,b , st , where Yt denotes total output ( Yt N t f ytf N tp ytf in equilibrium). Yt Yt Similarly, concerning the number of public employees, we will work in terms of their population share, tb 10 Thus, Gttr , p N tb (its process is defined below). Nt Gttr , p Gttr ,b tr , b and . G t N tp N tb 9 2.6 Public sector production function Following the related literature, we assume that total public goods and services, Yt g , are produced using goods purchased from the private sector, Gtg , and public employment, Ltg ( Lgt N tb etb in equilibrium). In particular, following Linnemann (2009), we use a CRS CobbDouglas production function of the form: Yt g A(Gtg ) ( Ltg )1 (10) where 0 1 is a parameter. Notice three things in (10). First, our specification can nest several specifications used by the literature. For instance, Ardanga (2007) assumes that the only input is public employment. Cavallo (2005) and Linnemann (2009) use the same inputs as in (10). Pappa (2009) assumes that the inputs are public employment and public capital, where the latter changes over time via public investment (we have experimented with adding public capital as an input in (10) and the main results do not change). Second, the TFP in (10) is assumed to be the same as in the private sector (see (8) above); this is because we do not want our results to be driven by exogenous factors.11 Third, in our numerical solutions below, we will experiment with different values of the relatively unknown parameter, 0 1 . 2.7 Decentralized competitive equilibrium (DCE) with public production Combining the above, we solve for a DCE in which (i) all households maximize utility, (ii) all firms in the private sector maximize profits, (iii) all markets clear (see Appendix C for market-clearing conditions in labor, capital, bond and goods markets) and (iv) all constraints are satisfied. The DCE consists of the following eleven equilibrium conditions:12 (etp ) (1 tc )(ctp Yt g ) (1 tl ) wtp (11a) 11 See e.g. Angelopoulos et al (2008) for efficiency in the public sector and its effect on economic growth. Yg G tr , p G tr ,b Gg 12 Note that Yt g t , Gtg t stg tp ytf , Gttr , p t p , Gttr ,b t b , Nt Nt Nt Nt stw Gtw wtg Lgt w g N b eb w g b eb t p t f t t p t f t , Yt N tp ytf . Yt Yt N t yt t yt 10 ktp1 k p ,k r 1 (1 ) t 1 t 1 ( tp1 ytf1 ) 2 1 (1 tc )(ctp Yt g ) (1 tc1 )(ctp1 Yt g1 ) (11b) btp1 p ,b 1 t 1 p f 2 ( t 1 yt 1 ) 1 c p g c p (1 t )(ct Yt ) (1 t 1 )(ct 1 Yt g1 ) 2 (11c) 2 p , k kt p p ,b btp p p b b (1 )c k (1 ) kt t 1 t 2 tp ytf 2 tp ytf c t p t p t 1 p (1 tk )rt ktp (1 tl ) wtp etp t btp sttr , p ytf (11d) (etb ) (1 tc )(ctb Yt g ) (1 tl ) wtg (11e) ktb1 k b,k r 1 (1 ) t 1 t 1 ( tp1 ytf1 ) 2 1 (1 tc )(ctb Yt g ) (1 tc1 )(ctb1 Yt g1 ) (11f) btb1 b ,b 1 t 1 ( tp1 ytf1 )2 1 (1 tc )(ctb Yt g ) (1 tc1 )(ctb1 Yt g1 ) (11g) ytf A( ktp tb b p 1 k ) (et ) tp t (11h) Yt g A( stg tp ytf ) ( tb etb )1 (11i) ( stw stg sttr , p sttr ,b ) tp ytf (1 t )( tp btp tbbtb ) tp1btp1 tb1btb1 + tc ( tp ctp tb ctb ) tk rt ( tp ktp tb ktb ) tl ( wtp tp etp wtg tb etb ) p ,k t ctp ktp1 (1 ) ktp 2 p b ,k b b b ct kt 1 (1 ) kt 2 b t (11j) 2 2 ktp p ,b btp p f 2 tp ytf t yt 2 2 ktb b ,b btb g p f p f p f p f st t yt t yt 2 t yt t yt 11 (11k) where, in the above equations, we use the factor returns:13 rt ytf tp tp ktp tb ktb (12a) (1 ) ytf etp (12b) wtp stw tp ytf w b b t et g t (12c) We therefore have eleven equations, (11a-k), in eleven endogenous variables, {ctp , ctb , ktp1, ktb1, btp1, btb1, etp , etb , t , ytf ,Yt g }t0 . This is for any feasible policy, where the latter is summarized by the paths of the exogenous policy instruments, {stg , stw , sttr , p , sttr ,b , tc , tk , tl , tb }t0 . For simplicity, we will assume that all exogenous policy instruments are constant and set at their data average values (see below). The equilibrium equations, (11a-k), are log-linearized around their long-run solution. This model serves as a benchmark and is solved numerically in section 4.14 It is our “status quo” model. 3. The same economy with private providers of public goods We now study what changes when, other things equal, the same amount of public goods, as implied by the above solution, is produced by private firms, the so-called private providers, in each time period. These private providers choose capital and labor inputs to produce the amount of public goods ordered by the government by solving a cost minimization problem with the government financing their total cost. Thus, now the government is not involved in any production itself. 13 Equations (12a-b) follow from the optimality conditions of the private firm and the related market-clearing G w w g Lg w g N b eb w g b eb conditions, while equation (12c) follows from the policy rule stw t t t t p t f t t p t f t . Yt Yt N t yt t yt 12 3.1. Population composition and agents’ economic roles As above, the number of private firms producing the private good equals the number of households working in these firms. This is indexed as p 1, 2,..., N tp , as before. We analogously assume that the number of private firms producing the public good ordered by the government equals the number of households working in these firms. Again, this is indexed as b 1, 2,..., N tb , as before. In other words, the allocation of employees/households to sectors, as well as the total population, remains as above. Thus, the optimization problem of p 1, 2,..., N tp households, which work at the private firms producing the private good, as well as the optimization problem of b 1, 2,..., N tb households, which work at the private firms producing the public good ordered by the government, remain as before (see equations (1)-(3) and (4)-(6) respectively). The only difference, at household level, is notational: each p household rents capital to private firms producing the private good earning a capital return denoted as rt p , while each b household rents capital to private firms producing the public good earning a capital return denoted as rt g .15 The problem of private firms f 1, 2,..., N p producing the private good also remains as above (see equations (7)-(8)). The only difference, at firm level, is again notational: the rental cost of capital for these firms is rt p . What changes, relative to the model in section 2, is the introduction of private firms producing the public good, the so-called private providers, indexed by g 1, 2,..., N tb , and the new role of the government. Regarding private providers, each g produces a given amount of the public good ordered by the government, Yt g / N tb , by choosing capital and labor inputs in a cost-minimizing way, where the path {Yt g }t0 is exogenously set as found by the solution of (11a-k) in the previous regime. In other words, the total amount of public goods, {Yt g }t0 , or equivalently the per capita amount of public goods, {Yt g }t0 , is treated as an exogenous variable in this new regime. Regarding the government, it makes lump-sum transfers as before and finances the total cost of private providers, N tb [rt g ktg wtg etg ] ; the 14 Note that the equilibrium equations are in terms of individual variables directly (i.e. private and public employees) without using any aggregation results. See the related discussion in Garcia-Milà et al (2010). 15 We have experimented with various specifications of this regime. The one we use here, and in particular the assumption that households b rent capital to firms g , while households p rent capital to firms f , instead of assuming a single capital market in which both types of households meet both types of firms, allows us to get a well-defined saddlepath that meets the Blanchard-Kahn criterion. Details are available upon request. 13 latter replaces spending on public wages, Gtw , and goods purchased from the private sector, Gtg , which were among the government spending items in section 2. In what follows, we present what changes relative to section 2. 3.2 Private firms producing a given amount of the public good (private providers) In each period, each private provider g 1, 2,..., N tb chooses capital and labor inputs, denoted as ktg and etg respectively, to minimize its costs. The cost-minimization problem is (as said, economy-wide quantities, denoted by capital letters, are taken as given by private agents): Y g rt g ktg wtg etg t t b ytg Nt (13) where rt g and wtg are respectively the rental cost of capital and the wage rate paid by private providers (see below for details), t is a multiplier measuring the marginal cost of production, Yt g is the total amount of public goods which is exogenously given by the previous problem, and ytg is each private provider’s output which is produced by using the same production function as in (8), namely: ytg A(ktg ) (etg )1 (14) Each g chooses ktg and etg taking factor prices and economy-wide quantities as given. The first-order conditions are: rt t g ytg (15a) ktg (1 ) ytg etg (15b) Yt g A(ktg ) (etg )1 0 N tb (15c) wtg t 14 where Appendix D provides details based on Mas-Colell et al (1995, pp. 139-143). It is useful to point out two things. First, the determination of wtg is different from section 2. In particular, while it was determined by the policy rule for the share of the public wage bill in section 2 (see equation (12c) above), it is now market determined as shown by equation (15b). Second, now both groups of firms, f and g , participate in the factor markets (see also the market-clearing conditions below). 3.3 Government budget constraint The within-period budget constraint of the government changes from (9a) to: N tb [rt g ktg wtg etg ] Gttr , p Gttr ,b (1 t ) Bt Bt 1 Tt (16) where the first term on the left-hand side is the total cost of public goods produced by private firms and the other variables are as defined in (9a-b) above. In each period, there are seven policy instruments ( Gttr , p , Gttr ,b , tc , tk , tl , Bt 1 , N tb ) or equivalently in ratios ( sttr , p , sttr ,b , tc tk tl , Bt 1 , tb ). As in section 2, we will start by assuming that the residually determined policy instrument is the end-of-period public debt, Bt 1 . Compare the vector of policy instruments to that in section 2, where Gtg and Gtw , or equivalently their output shares, stg and stw , were also among the policy instruments. 3.4 Decentralized competitive equilibrium (DCE) with cost-minimizing private providers Combining the above, we solve for a DCE in which (i) all households maximize utility, (ii) all private firms that produce the private good maximize profits and all private firms that produce the public good minimize costs, (iii) all markets clear (see Appendix E for the new market-clearing conditions) and (iv) all constraints are satisfied. The new DCE consists of the following new eleven equilibrium conditions: (etp ) (1 tc )(ctp Yt g ) (1 tl ) wtp (17a) 15 ktp1 k p p ,k r 1 (1 ) t 1 t 1 ( tp1 ytf1 ) 2 1 (1 tc )(ctp Yt g ) (1 tc1 )(ctp1 Yt g1 ) (17b) btp1 p ,b 1 t 1 p f 2 ( t 1 yt 1 ) 1 c p g c p (1 t )(ct Yt ) (1 t 1 )(ct 1 Yt g1 ) 2 (17c) 2 p , k kt p p ,b btp p p b b (1 )c k (1 ) kt t 1 t 2 tp ytf 2 tp ytf c t p t p t 1 p (1 tk ) rt p ktp (1 tl ) wtp etp t btp sttr , p ytf (17d) (etb ) (1 tc )(ctb Yt g ) (1 tl ) wtg (17e) ktb1 k g b,k r 1 (1 ) t 1 t 1 ( tp1 ytf1 ) 2 1 (1 tc )(ctb Yt g ) (1 tc1 )(ctb1 Yt g1 ) (17f) btb1 b ,b 1 t 1 ( tp1 ytf1 )2 1 (1 tc )(ctb Yt g ) (1 tc1 )(ctb1 Yt g1 ) (17g) ytf A( ktp ) (etp )1 (17h) Yt g tb A( ktb ) (etb )1 (17i) tb (rt g ktb wtg etb ) ( sttr , p sttr ,b ) tp ytf (1 t )( tp btp tbbtb ) tp1btp1 tb1btb1 + tc ( tp ctp tb ctb ) tk ( rt p tp ktp rt g tb ktb ) tl ( wtp tp etp wtg tb etb ) p ,k t ctp ktp1 (1 ) ktp 2 p (17j) 2 2 ktp p ,b btp p f 2 tp ytf t yt 2 2 b , k ktb b ,b btb b b b p f ct kt 1 (1 ) kt p f p f t yt 2 t yt 2 t yt b t where, in the above equations, we use the factor returns (see Appendix F for details): 16 (17k) rt p ytf (18a) kt p Yt g rt t b b kt t g wtp (18b) (1 ) ytf etp (18c) (1 )Yt g etb tb wtg t (18d) Therefore, in this new system, we have eleven equations, (17a-k), in eleven endogenous variables, {ctp , ctb , ktp1 , ktb1 , t , btp1 , btb1 , etp , etb , t , ytf }t0 . This is for any feasible policy, where the latter is summarized by the paths of the exogenous policy instruments, {sttr , p , sttr ,b , tc tk tl , tb }t0 , and the path of the per capita amount of public goods, {Yt g }t0 , which is exogenously set as in the previous, status quo, regime. We will again assume that all exogenous policy instruments are constant and set at their data average values (see below). The equilibrium equations, (17a-k), are log-linearized around their long-run solution. The model is solved numerically in the next section. 4. Numerical solutions and comparison of the two model economies We now solve and compare the two model economies developed in sections 2 and 3. 4.1 How we work to solve the models We work in two steps. We first solve the model in section 2, when this model is calibrated to match some stylized facts of the UK economy, in particular the tax-spending policy mix over 1990-2010. This solution will give us, among other endogenous variables, the path of the per capita amount of public goods, {Yt g }t0 , induced by the existing UK tax-spending policy mix. In turn, this status quo economy will be used as a point of reference for evaluating various policy reforms. For instance, in this section, we solve the model economy in section 3, where it is cost-minimizing private providers, rather than the government itself, that produce the same path of per capita public goods, {Yt g }t0 . 17 We will compare the status quo economy to the reformed economy both in the long run and in the transition path. The way we work follows most of the literature on policy reforms.16 Thus, we will first evaluate various policy regimes based on a comparison of long-run equilibria (this is in sections 4-6). Transitional dynamics, as well as lifetime welfare gains from moving from one regime to another, are discussed in section 7. 4.2 Parameters and policy instruments Table 1 reports the baseline parameter values for technology and preference, as well as the values of exogenous policy instruments, used to solve the status quo model economy in section 2. The time unit is meant to be a year. Our parameterization is standard with most parameter values for technology and preference being borrowed from Angelopoulos et al (2011a), who have recently calibrated an aggregate DSGE model to annual data for the UK economy. When we have no a priori information about a technology or preference parameter value, or when different authors use different values, we will consider a range of values. In general, we can report that all main results are robust to changes in the parameter values. Public spending and tax rate values are those of sample averages of the UK economy over 1990-2008. The data are obtained from OECD, Economic Outlook, no. 88. We report that our main results do not change when we consider alternative time periods, e.g. 19702008 or 1996-2008. Table 1 around here (Baseline parameterization) Let us discuss, briefly, the values summarized in Table 1. The labour share in the private production function, 1 , is set at 0.601, which is the value in Angelopoulos et al (2011a). The scale parameter in the technology function, A , is set at 1. The time preference rate is set at 0.99. The weight given to public goods and services in composite consumption, , is set at 0.1, as is usually the case in similar studies. The other preference parameters related to hours worked, and , are set at 5 and 1 respectively; these parameter values jointly imply hours worked within usual ranges. The capital depreciation rate is set at 16 See e.g. Lucas (1990), Cooley and Hansen (1992) and Mendoza and Tesar (1998). Recall that Lucas (1990) compared the macroeconomic allocation implied by the existing US tax mix to that under optimal Ramsey policy according to which the capital tax rate is set to be zero. 18 0.05 . The transaction cost parameter associated with participation in asset markets is set at p ,k p ,b b ,k b ,b 0.002 across both agents and both assets. Our results are robust to changes in these parameter values (see below). In the baseline calibration, the productivity of public employment, vis-à-vis the productivity of goods purchased from the private sector, in the public sector production function, 1 , is set at 0.493. This value is the sample average of public wage payments, as share of total public spending on inputs used in the production of public goods (see also e.g. Linnemann, 2009, for similar practice). But we will also experiment with other values of 1 (see below). Public employees as a share of total population, b , are set at 0.1904 as in the data. Public spending on wage payments and transfers, as shares of output, are respectively stw 0.109 and sttr 0.2199 in the data. We assume that transfers are allocated to private and public employees according to their shares in population, sttr , p tp sttr (1 tb ) sttr and sttr ,b tb sttr (see below for other cases considered). The output share of public spending on goods and services purchased from the private sector, stg , is then calculated residually from total public spending minus spending on public wage payments, transfers and interest payments; this is found to be 0.1119. The effective tax rates on consumption, capital and labor are respectively c 0.1852 , k 0.3875 and l 0.2685 over 1990-2008; the data are taken from Angelopoulos et al (2011a), who have followed the methodology of Conesa et al (2007) in constructing effective tax rates for the UK economy. We can now present numerical solutions. As said, we start with a comparison of long-run equilibria. We report that, using the parameterization of Table 1, all regimes studied feature local determinacy. 4.3 Long-run solution when public debt is the adjusting public finance instrument Using the parameterization in Table 1, the long-run solutions of the status quo economy presented in section 2 and the reformed economy presented in section 3 are reported respectively in columns 1 and 2 in Table 2. These long-run solutions follow from the systems (11a-k) and (17a-k) respectively when variables do not change.17 Without transaction costs, 0 , the long-run system would be “under-identified” in the sense that there would be nine equations and eleven variables. This happens because, in the long run, if 0 , the two agents’ (i.e. private and public workers’) Euler conditions for capital (see equations (11b) and (11f) written in the long 17 19 Recall that, in the reformed economy in section 3, the same amount of public goods, as found in section 2, is supplied by cost-minimizing private providers. Also recall that the superscript b denotes those households that are involved in the production of the public good, either as public employees in the status quo economy, or as workers at the costminimizing private providers/firms in the reformed economy, while the superscript p denotes those households that work in private firms producing the private good. Table 2 around here (Long-run solution when public debt is the residual policy instrument) Before we compare the two regimes, we report that the long-run solution of our status quo economy in column 1 can mimic rather well some key macroeconomic averages in the actual data in the UK. For instance, our long-run solution for the public wage to private wage ratio is found to be w g / w p 0.8109 in column 1 of Table 2, which is close to that in the actual data over our sample period, which is 0.8884. We also report that our long-run output shares of consumption, capital, etc, are close to their average values in the data. We now proceed to compare the status quo economy to the reformed economy. We start with distributional implications and then discuss macroeconomic or aggregate implications (we do so only for presentational convenience because distribution and efficiency are obviously interrelated). 4.3.1 Distributional implications In the long run, the ratio of public to private wages, w g / w p , falls from 0.8109 in column 1 to only 0.3499 in column 2 of Table 2. Lower labor income explains, in turn, the fall in consumption, c b , and the willingness to work, eb , of b households in column 2. Despite the increase in leisure time, (1 eb ) , the fall in consumption, c b , leads to a clear fall in the longrun utility of b households, u b , as we switch from the status quo to the reformed economy. run) are reduced to one equation only. The same applies to the two Euler conditions for bonds (equations (11c) and (11g), written in the long run, are also reduced to one equation only). Thus, the model could pin down the total long-run stocks of capital and bonds but not their allocation to the two types of agents. The same feature characterizes the system in (17a-k). The presence of transaction costs, 0 , help us to circumvent this problem. Alternatively, we could use an ad hoc rule for the allocation of the total long-run stocks of assets to each agent (our main results do not change). In any case, as is known, with perfect capital markets and common discount factors, the allocation of the aggregate stock of capital and bonds to different types of individual investors cannot be pinned down by the equilibrium conditions. This is why resorting to some 20 By contrast, the long-run utility of p households, u p , rises in column 2 . This is thanks to higher consumption, c p , and more leisure time, (1 e p ) , enjoyed by p households under private provision (see below for further details). Notice that, in this particular experiment, the adverse welfare effects on b households dominate the beneficial effects on p households, so that per capita long-run utility, denoted as u ,18 falls under private provision in column 2 (as we shall see below, this aggregate depends heavily on the way the government uses its efficiency savings enjoyed by private provision). 4.3.2 Macroeconomic implications Per capita private consumption and per capita capital, both as levels and as shares of output, rise in column 2 relative to column 1. This happens because the switch to private provision in column 2 releases resources for private use. In particular, the comparison of the resource constraints (11k) and (17k) implies that, in the latter, the elimination of Gtg releases ceteris paribus resources for private use (private consumption and capital accumulation). This is like a traditional wealth effect in the sense that, given output, government spending on goods and services works as a resource drain. This partly explains the rise in per capita consumption and capital. The rise in per capita consumption also explains how the reduction in c b (caused by the fall in w g / w p ) allows an increase in c p , as discussed above. The above are direct effects that work through reallocation of resources. But there are also indirect effects that work through public financing. The fall in w g under private providers leads to a fall in the total labor cost of public good production as share of output, s w . The latter falls from 0.1090 in the data (see column 1 in Table 2) to only 0.0338 in the reformed economy (see column 2 in Table 2). Since this cost is always financed by the government, irrespectively of who is the provider, a more efficient way of delivering the public good in column 2 allows the government to make efficiency savings. In the baseline public financing case studied so far, where the residual policy instrument is - by assumption - the end-of-period stock of public debt, these efficiency savings allow the government to afford a much larger debt burden through the long-run government budget constraint. extraneous assumption, in order to get a portfolio share for each individual in models with different agents and perfect capital markets, is usual in the literature (see e.g. Mendoza and Tesar, 1998, in a two-country model). 18 Per capita values are defined as the weighted average of p households and b households, where the weights are their shares in population. For instance, per capita utility is u v u v u . p 21 p b b Indeed, as reported in Table 2a, the endogenously determined output share of public debt, b / y , rises from 212.71% of GDP in column 1 to a very high number in column 2. It is the combination of direct-resource effects and indirect-public financing effects that explains the value of per capita output, y . In the numerical experiment reported in Table 2, y falls as we switch to the reformed economy ( y falls from 0.6838 in column 1 to 0.6418 in column 2 of Table 2). This seemingly paradoxical result arises simply because we have assumed that it is public debt that adjusts to close the government budget. As said above, in this baseline case, efficiency savings only allow the government to afford the financing of a much higher debt burden. Thus, although we move to a more efficient way of delivering the public good, we do not use - by assumption - the resources saved in a way that benefits the economy. At the same time, the decrease in public spending creates an adverse demand effect on output. The combination of those two effects, namely, the trivial use of government efficiency savings and the adverse effect on the demand side, explains the drop in the level of y , even if we have switched to a more efficient way of delivering the public good in column 2. To confirm this, we next study two more interesting public financing cases. 4.4 Long-run solutions when distorting taxes are the adjusting public finance instruments We now study two more interesting ways of public financing. In Table 3, the residually determined long-run policy instrument is the consumption tax rate, while, in Table 4, the residually determined long-run policy instrument is the labor tax rate. In both cases, the long-run public debt-to-output ratio is exogenously set at its average value in the data, 80%. Table 3 around here (Long-run solution when the consumption tax rate is the residual policy instrument) As shown in columns 1 and 2 of Table 3, efficiency savings from private provision allow the government to afford a much lower consumption tax rate (actually, in our experiment, c turns from a tax in column 1 to a small subsidy in column 2). Lower consumption taxes stimulate the consumption and welfare of p households (compare the values of c p and u p in column 2 of Table 3 to those in column 2 of Table 2). The rise in u p is now high enough to lead to higher per capita welfare (per capita welfare, u , increases from -1.0595 in column 1 to -0.9525 in column 2 in Table 3, while it decreased from -1.0677 22 in column 1 to -1.0774 in column 2 in Table 2). In other words, with consumption taxes as the adjusting instrument, per capita welfare rises when we switch to private provision. Nevertheless, as it was the case in Table 2, per capita output falls again when we switch to private provision. In particular, y falls from 0.6879 in column 1 to 0.6767 in column 2 in Table 3 (this fall is smaller than that in Table 2, where y fell from 0.6838 in column 1 to 0.6418 in column 2). In other words, although the rise in c p is much higher than it was under debt financing in Table 2, this rise is still not strong enough to offset the adverse demand effect on output coming from the fall in consumption of b households and less public spending. This is not surprising: consumption taxes are not very distorting in this class of models so, loosely speaking, their reduction cannot work as an engine of growth. Table 4 around here (Long-run solution when the labor tax rate is the residual policy instrument) In Table 4, the residual public finance policy instrument is the labor tax rate in the long run. Efficiency savings from private provision allow the government to afford a much lower labor tax rate (actually, in our experiment, l turns from a tax in column 1 to a small subsidy in column 2). Since labor taxes are distorting (see also e.g. Angelopoulos et al, 2011a, for the UK economy), their reduction not only strongly stimulates c p , u p and in turn u (per capita welfare, u , increases from -1.0537 in column 1 to -0.9489 in column 2 in Table 4), but it also stimulates long-run per capita output ( y rises from 0.6949 in column 1 to 0.7153 in column 2 in Table 4). In other words, via the public financing channel, we now have substantial supply-side benefits, which more than offset the adverse demand effects on output coming from a smaller public sector. Thus, private provision now leads to a larger national pie and higher per capita welfare (as we show below, a larger pie can allow the government to afford Pareto-improving redistributive policies). 4.5 Summary of this section A switch from the status quo economy to a reformed economy, where the same amount of public goods is produced by cost-minimizing private providers, increases the welfare of private employees but makes public employees clearly worse off. The effect on per capita welfare and per capita output is ambiguous depending crucially on the adjusting public finance instrument. Only when the efficiency savings, coming from a more efficient way of 23 delivering the public good, are used to cut distorting income (labor) taxes, per capita welfare and per capita output can both rise. Recall that these are long-run results. Transition results, when we depart from the status quo economy and switch to private providers over time, are presented below. 5. Can cost-minimizing public providers beat cost-minimizing private providers? One could argue that so far we have been “unfair” to the public sector. In particular, we have compared the status quo economy to an economy with private providers, where, in the former, public production decisions were exogenously set as in the data, while, in the latter, public production decisions were made by cost-minimizing private providers. Although, as said in the beginning of section 4 above, comparisons of this type are common in the literature on policy reforms, one is wondering what would happen when we compare the cases in which, not only private providers, but also public providers minimize their costs, always with the general taxpayer (i.e. the government) financing these costs. We turn to this question now. Although there are several ways of modeling the behavior of public providers/enterprises, here we choose a simple way that also makes the solution of this new regime directly comparable to the solutions of the two other regimes studied above. In particular, like we did in section 3 with private providers, we assume that there is a single public provider who, in each period, chooses its inputs in a cost-minimizing way so as to produce the same amount of public goods, {Yt g }t0 , as offered by the status quo economy. Thus, as in section 3, the path {Yt g }t0 is exogenously set. As said above, our modeling of public providers is not different from Atkinson and Stiglitz (1980, chapter 15.3), where the government tells state enterprises to choose their mix of inputs so as to minimize their costs. 5.1 Cost-minimizing public provider The economy is as in section 2 but now, in addition, in each period, the public provider chooses its two inputs, Gtg and Ltg , or equivalently their output shares, stg and stw , to minimize its costs. The cost-minimization problem is: Gtg wtg Ltg t [Yt g At (Gtg ) ( Ltg )1 ] (19) 24 where wtg denotes the new wage rate received by public employees, t is a multiplier measuring the marginal cost of producing the public good and Yt g is the total amount of public goods which is exogenously set as found by the solution of the status quo model in section 2. It is straightforward to show that the three first-order conditions combined imply: stg w st 1 (20) which says that the ratio of public spending on the two inputs should be equal to the ratio of their productivities. 5.2 Decentralized competitive equilibrium (DCE) with cost-minimizing public provider In the new DCE, we have twelve equations, the eleven equations of the status quo economy, (11a-k), plus equation (20), in twelve endogenous variables, {ctp , ctb , ktp1 , ktb1 , btp1 , btb1 , etp , etb , t , ytf , stg , stw }t 0 . This is for any feasible policy, as summarized by {sttr , p , sttr ,b , tc tk tl , tb }t0 , and the path of {Yt g }t0 , which is exogenously set as found in the status quo economy. These new equilibrium equations are log-linearized around their long-run solution. 5.3 Long-run solutions Long-run solutions of the new model economy, under the three different ways of public financing, are reported in Tables 2, 3 and 4 respectively, column 3. We again use the baseline parameterization in Table 1. Inspection of the results reveals that any differences between the status quo economy in column 1 and the economy in column 3, where the public provider acts optimally, are minor. 5.4 Summary of this section When public providers choose their inputs in a cost-minimizing way, the results are very similar to those under the status quo regime, at least when we use the baseline parameterization. This implies that contracting out the production of public goods to costminimizing private providers is superior to public production, even when public providers 25 act as cost minimizers. It also seems to imply that in the UK, over 1990-2008, the public sector has exhausted its role, at least in terms of aggregate efficiency, as a provider of public goods and services. 6. Searching for Pareto improving reforms As we have seen, although per capita welfare can increase when we move from the status quo economy to an economy with public finance only, public employees clearly become worse off by becoming employees at cost-minimizing private providers. This means that such reforms, although good for the general interest, are unlikely to be implemented, especially, when public sector employees, or their trade unions, have a strong influence in blocking reforms. The question is whether the society can take advantage of the aggregate efficiency gains, generated by private provision/public finance, and design a transfer scheme that improves the welfare of both types of agents, namely both private and public employees, relative to the status quo economy. We find it natural to report results only for those cases in which private provision/public finance increases the aggregate pie (per capita output) relative to the status quo economy. As we showed in section 4, and in particular in Table 4, this happens when the efficiency savings from private provision/public finance are used to cut distorting labor taxes. (Results for the other cases, where the residual public finance instrument is public debt or consumption taxes, are available upon request.) 6.1 Endogenizing transfers and a new DCE We search for a government transfer scheme that, in combination with private provision/public finance of public goods and labor taxes as the residual public finance instrument, makes everybody equally well off in the long run. In particular, instead of assuming that government transfers are exogenously allocated to the two groups according to their population shares, we now endogenize this scheme by solving for an allocation of transfers that makes both agents equally off in the long run of the reformed economy modeled in section 3.19 19 See e.g. Park and Philippopoulos (2003) for other redistributive transfer mechanisms in a dynamic general equilibrium model. 26 Algebraically, the new DCE consists of equations (17a-k) plus a new equation that equates long-run utility across the two agents, u b u p , while the associated new endogenous variable is the long-run share of government transfers, xb , where s tr ,b x b s tr and s tr , p (1 x b ) s tr . Numerically, we compute xb so as u b u p . Results for the long run of this economy are reported in column 4 in Table 4. As can be seen, when we compare this new economy (in column 4) to the status quo economy (in column 1), there is room for substantial welfare gains, now for both types of agents. Notice that, although private employees are worse off in column 4 than in column 2, which was the case with private provision without redistribution of transfers, they are still better off than in the status quo economy in column 1. 6.2 Summary of this section A switch to private provision, in combination with redistributive transfers and use of the efficiency savings from private provision to cut labor taxes, is Pareto improving relative to the status quo economy. 7. Transition and discounted lifetime utility The above results compared long-run equilibria with and without reforms. We now study lifetime utility between pre- and post reform steady states when we depart from initial conditions corresponding to the pre-reform, status quo, economy. 7.1 How we work We work as in e.g. Lucas (1990), Cooley and Hansen (1992) and Mendoza and Tesar (1998). We first check, using our baseline parameterization, that when log-linearized around its steady state solution, each model economy studied so far is saddle-path stable.20 This is under all types of reform and all methods of public financing studied. Then, setting, as initial conditions for the state variables, the steady state solution of the status quo economy, we compute the equilibrium transition path of each reformed economy and calculate the 20 Without asset transaction costs there are unit roots, at least in some regimes. Although there are papers that work with unit roots (see e.g. Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe, 2004, p. 219), we prefer to avoid this feature since it implies that we may not converge to the long-run around which we have approximated. We also report that when we make the model stochastic by adding shocks to e.g. policy instruments and TFP, the impulse response functions give intuitive results. 27 associated discounted lifetime utilities of the two types of households. We also calculate the permanent supplement to private consumption, expressed as a constant percentage, which would leave the household indifferent between two regimes. This percentage is denoted as z , where a positive (resp. negative) value of z will mean that discounted lifetime utility is higher under the reformed economy (resp. the status quo economy). 7.2 Results for lifetime utility Results are reported in Table 5. Again, we report results only for the case in which the efficiency savings from a reform are used to cut a distorting income (labor) tax rate. Recall that, only in this case, a reform increases the aggregate pie (per capita output) relative to the status quo economy in the long run. Table 5 around here (Lifetime utility under regime switches) In Table 5, U p and U b denote respectively the discounted lifetime utility of the p household and the b household, while U is the per capita value. Column 1 describes the case in which we remain forever in the long-run of the status quo economy, while in the other columns we study what happens over time when we switch from the status quo economy to cost-minimizing private providers (column 2), to cost-minimizing public providers (column 3), and finally to cost-minimizing private providers in combination with transfers that compensate those suffered from the reform (column 4). In each case of regime switch (columns 2-4), we also report the associated value of the welfare measure, z , as defined above. As can be seen, the transition results are qualitatively the same as the long-run results. Namely, in all cases studied, the transition from the status quo economy to an economy with private providers is good for private employees and the aggregate economy, but this is clearly at the loss of those employed in the public sector. On the other hand, when we also adjust transfers to compensate the losers, both groups of agents get better off relative to the status quo (see column 4). Finally, again as in the long run, public providers cannot beat private providers even when are both assumed to minimize their costs. 28 7.3 Summary of this section When the criterion is lifetime utility, there seems to be substantial Pareto benefits from a mix of reforms that combines: (i) a transition to cost-minimizing private providers that implies efficiency savings for the government (ii) redistributive transfers that compensate those previously working as public employees (ii) a reduction in labor taxes made affordable by efficiency savings. 8. Robustness We finally check the sensitivity of our results to changes in the parameter values used. In particular, we focus on the value of the relatively unknown parameter, 1 , measuring the productivity of public employees in the public sector production function (see equation (10) above). 8.1 Various ad hoc values of the productivity of public employees Keeping everything else as in the baseline parameterization of Table 1, we now arbitrarily set a low productivity of public employees, say 1 0.3 , and a high productivity, say 1 0.7 . Recall that in the baseline parameterization so far, the calibrated value of 1 was 0.493. Results for these two new cases are reported in Tables 6-9 and 10-13 respectively. Thus, these new tables are as Tables 2-5 with the only difference being that 1 0.3 in Tables 6-9 and 1 0.7 in Tables 10-13. Tables 6-9 around here (This is like Tables 2-5 with 1 0.3 ) Tables 10-13 around here (This is like Tables 2-5 with 1 0.7 ) The main message is that all key results remain unchanged. Let us first briefly look at the case with low productivity, 1 0.3 . Comparison of Tables 2-4 to Tables 6-8 (longrun results) reveals that the only difference is that, in the latter, public employees become worse off as we move from column 1 to column 3, while recall that their utility did not change much in Tables 2-4 above. This is intuitive: when their productivity is low, public employees suffer under cost-minimizing public providers as they do under cost-minimizing 29 private providers. This is also the case when we compute lifetime utility. Namely, comparison of Table 5 to Table 9 reveals that lifetime utility of public employees is lower in Table 9 than in Table 5 in all regimes with cost-minimizing producers; for the symmetrically opposite reason, public employees can gain more in Table 9 than in Table 5, when we combine cost-minimization with redistributive transfers. Let us also look at the case with high productivity of public employees, 1 0.7 . Comparison of Tables 2-4 to Tables 10-12 (long-run results) reveals that now the opposite happens: the public wage bill, stw , and hence the welfare of public employees, rise as we move from column 1 to column 3 in Tables 10-12. This might look paradoxical but it happens simply because of the optimality condition (20): since 1 0.7 is relatively high (or 0.3 is relatively low), it is optimal to choose a relatively high stw (or a relatively low stg ) which in turn makes public employees better off in column 3 in Tables 10-12. This also explains the results for lifetime utility in Table 13. Nevertheless, Table 13 also implies that the key result of the paper holds even in this case: the reform that makes both groups better off relative to status quo is the one that combines cost-minimizing private providers with redistributive transfers and a reduction in labor taxes. 8. 2 Summary of this section The key results are robust to a wide range of the parameter value measuring the productivity of public employees. We also report that our results are robust to changes in the other parameter values (results are available upon request). 9. Conclusions This paper studied a much debated reform of the state - the idea of opening up public services to new providers - in a dynamic general equilibrium setup. We showed that substantial aggregate gains are possible if the society switches to private provision/public finance of public goods and if the government uses the resulting efficiency savings to reduce distorting income taxes. It is remarkable that this happens even when the amount of public goods produced, and the number of households employed in the production of public goods, remain the same as in the status quo economy. We also showed that one can design 30 redistributive schemes that allow everybody, including public employees, to benefit from such a switch. Our results are another example of the importance of social contracts (see also the discussion in Garcia-Milà et al, 2010). In our model, social contracts that terminate the monopoly of the public sector as a producer of public goods, in combination of transfers that compensate those previously employed by the state, can benefit everybody. Our work can be extended in several ways. For instance, we could include uncertainty coming from shocks to e.g. technology and policy instruments. We could also use a richer production function for the public good allowing for substitutability between public employment and goods purchased from the private sector. Also, we could introduce various politico-economy issues, like extra benefits on the part of public employees coming from rent seeking. We leave such extensions for future work. 31 APPENDIX Appendix A: First-order conditions of household p in section 2 The first-order conditions include the budget constraints and: (etp ) (1 tc )(ctp Yt g ) (1 tl ) wtp (A.1) ktp1 k p,k r 1 (1 ) t 1 t 1 (Yt 1 ) 2 1 (1 tc )(ctp Yt g ) (1 tc1 )(ctp1 Yt g1 ) p p ,b bt 1 1 t 1 2 (Yt 1 ) 1 c p g c p (1 t )(ct Yt ) (1 t 1 )(ct 1 Yt g1 ) (A.2) (A.3) Appendix B: First-order conditions of private firm f in section 2 rt ytf wtp (B.1) kt f (1 ) ytf etf (B.2) so that profits are zero. Appendix C: Market-clearing conditions in section 2 In the labor market: N t f etf N tp etp (C.1a) Lgt N tb etb (C.1b) In the capital market: N t f kt f N tp ktp N tb ktb (C.2) In the bond market: Bt N tp btp N tbbtb (C.3) In the goods market (economy’s resource constraint): N tp ctp N tb ctb N tp itp N tb itb Gtg N t f ytf (C.4) where we set Nt f N tp . 32 Appendix D: Cost minimization of private provider g in section 3 Here we follow Mas-Colell et al (1995, pp. 139-143). The first-order conditions imply: rt g t ytg (D.1a) ktg (1 ) ytg w t etg g t t (D.1b) (rt g ) ( wtg )1 rt g ktg wtg etg (rt g ktg wtg etg ) N tb (rt g ktg wtg etg ) tb A (1 )1 ytg Yt g Yt g (D.1c) where (D.1c) follows if we use (D.1a)-(D.1b) to get expressions for ktg and etg respectively, g t g 1 t and use them back in the production function, A(k ) (e ) Yt g Yt g y b b . Nt t g t In turn, we use (D.1c) to substitute out the multiplier, t , in (D.1a) and (D.1b): 1 yg rg k t t A g t 1 wtg 1 Y g r g wg e t t t A 1 (D.2a) g t (D.2b) so that the total cost of each firm can be written as: y g (r g ) ( wtg )1 rt k w e t t A g g t g g t t 1 1 1 Yt g (rt g ) ( wtg )1 N tb A 1 1 1 (D.3) Notice that profits are zero (thanks to CRS). To show this, consider profits: ytg (rt g ) ( wtg )1 y rt k w e y A g t g g t g g t t g t 1 1 1 (D.4) so that (thanks to linearity) the first-order condition is: (rt g ) ( wtg )1 1 A 1 1 1 (D.5) but, if this condition holds, total profits are zero in each period. Appendix E: Market-clearing conditions in section 3 In the labor market: 33 N t f etf N tp etp (E.1a) Ntg etg N tb etb (E.1b) In the capital market: N t f k t f N t p kt p (E.2a) N tg ktg N tb ktb (E.2b) In the bond market: Bt N tp btp N tbbtb (E.3) In the goods market (economy’s resource constraint): N tp ctp N tb ctb N tp itp N tb itb N t f ytf (E.4) where we set N t f N tp and N tg N tb . Also recall that the privately produced public good is provided without charge as in section 2. Appendix F: Factor returns in section 3 rt p ytf rt t g wtp (F.1) kt p ytg ktg Yt g Yt g N t Yt g t b b t b b t b b kt N t kt N t N t kt t (1 ) ytf etp wtg t (F.2) (F.3) (1 ) ytg (1 )Yt g (1 )Yt g N t (1 )Yt g t t t etb etb N tb etb N tb N t etb tb 34 (F.4) Table 1 Baseline parameterization Parameters and policy instruments Description Value Share of capital in private production 0.399 1 Share of public employment in public production 0.493* k Capital depreciation rate 0.05 Rate of time preference 0.99 Public consumption weight in utility 0.1 Preference parameter on work hours in utility 5 Elasticity of work hours in utility 1 sw Public wage payments as share of GDP 0.1090 sg Public purchases as share of GDP 0.1119 s tr Public transfers as share of GDP 0.2199 c Tax rate on consumption 0.1852 k Tax rate on capital income 0.3875 l Tax rate on labor income 0.2685 vb Public employees as share of population 0.1904 A Long-run TFP 1 a Autoregressive parameter of TFP 0.9 a Standard deviation of TFP 0.01 p,k Transaction cost incurred by private agents in capital market 0.002 p,b Transaction cost incurred by private agents in bond market 0.002 b,k Transaction cost incurred by public employees in capital market 0.002 b,b Transaction cost incurred by public employees in bond market 0.002 Notes: * We also experiment with 1 0.3 (see Tables 6-9) and 1 0.7 (see Tables 10-13). 35 Table 2 Long-run solution when public debt is the residual policy instrument 1 Status quo economy 2 Cost-minimizing Private providers 3 Cost-minimizing public providers -1.0432 -0.9794 -1.0432 -1.1720 -1.4938 -1.1726 -1.0677 0.4792 -1.0774 0.4959 -1.0678 0.4792 0.4075 0.2503 0.4071 0.3590 0.3419 0.3590 0.3414 0.2338 0.3413 0.8109 0.3499 0.8099 0.6838 0.6418 0.6837 yg c/ y 0.0706 0.0706 0.0706 0.6808 0.6999 0.6808 k/y 3.6282 3.7690 3.6282 b/ y 2.1271 7.4738 2.1316 sw sg s t, p s t ,b 0.1090 0.0338 0.1088 0.1119 - 0.1119 Variable up ub u cp cb ep eb wg / w p y 0.8096* s tr 0.8096* s tr 0.8096* s tr 0.1904* s tr 0.1904* s tr 0.1904* s tr Notes: (i) We use the baseline parameterization in Table 1. (ii) u v u v u for all per capita quantities). p 36 p b b (the same formula is used Table 3 Long-run solution when the consumption tax rate is the residual policy instrument 1 Status quo economy 2 Cost-minimizing Private providers 3 Cost-minimizing public providers -1.0345 -0.8253 -1.0295 -1.1656 -1.4933 -1.1651 -1.0595 0.4853 -0.9525 0.5992 -1.0553 0.4889 0.4118 0.2555 0.4127 0.3611 0.3605 0.3624 0.3438 0.2499 0.3447 0.8100 0.3001 0.8052 0.6879 0.0711 0.6767 0.0711 0.6902 0.0711 0.6851 0.7887 0.6872 3.6282 3.7411 3.6282 0.8000 0.8000 0.8000 c 0.1634 -0.0675 0.1511 sw sg s t, p s t ,b 0.1090 0.0294 0.1083 0.1119 - 0.1113 Variable up ub u cp cb ep eb wg / w p y g y c/ y k/y b/ y 0.8096* s tr 0.8096* s tr 0.8096* s tr 0.1904* s tr 0.1904* s tr 0.1904* s tr Notes: See notes of Table 2. 37 Table 4 Long-run solution when the labor tax rate is the residual policy instrument 1 Status quo economy 2 Cost-minimizing Private providers 3 Cost-minimizing public providers -1.0280 -0.7900 -1.0282 4 Cost-minimizing private providers plus redistributive transfers -0.8682 -1.1632 -1.6245 -1.1635 -0.8682 -1.0537 0.4918 -0.9489 0.6453 -1.0540 0.4917 -0.8682 0.6119 0.4158 0.2289 0.4156 0.4665 0.3648 0.3811 0.3648 0.3943 0.3480 0.2690 0.3479 0.2200 0.8085 0.2554 0.8083 0.4268 0.6949 0.0719 0.7153 0.0719 0.6949 0.0719 0.7401 0.0719 0.6868 0.7913 0.6867 0.7894 3.6282 3.7162 3.6282 3.7680 0.8000 0.8000 0.8000 0.8000 l 0.2371 -0.0576 0.2373 -0.0381 sw sg s t, p s t ,b 0.1090 0.0255 0.1090 0.0337 0.1119 - 0.1120 - Variable up ub u cp cb ep eb wg / w p y g y c/ y k/y b/ y 0.8096* s tr 0.8096* s tr 0.8096* s tr 0.5302* s tr 0.1904* s Notes: See notes of Table 2. tr 0.1904* s tr 0.1904* s tr 0.4698* s tr 38 Table 5 Lifetime utility under regime switches, with the labor tax rate as the residual policy instrument in the long run 1 Status quo economy Up - z U -102.8009 b z U z -116.3176 -105.3745 - 2 From status quo economy to cost-minimizing private providers -80.2693 0.2564 -160.1591 -0.3611 -95.4803 0.1388 3 From status quo economy to costminimizing public providers -102.8184 -0.0002 -116.3541 -0.0004 -105.3956 -0.0002 4 From status quo economy to cost-minimizing private providers plus redistributive transfers -88.3975 0.1572 -85.9722 0.3606 -87.9357 0.1959 Notes: (i) See notes of Table 2. (ii) For h p, b , U h t u (cth , eth , Yt g ) . (iii) U v U v U . (iv) z is p t 0 the constant private consumption supplement which makes U 39 p Ub. p b b Table 6 Long-run solution when public debt is the residual policy instrument Variable up ub u cp cb ep eb wg / w p y 1 Status quo economy 2 Cost-minimizing Private providers 3 Cost-minimizing public providers -1.0428 -0.9798 -1.0275 -1.1715 -1.4839 -1.4115 -1.0673 0.4791 -1.0758 0.4956 -1.1006 0.4836 0.4074 0.2540 0.2890 0.3589 0.3420 0.3555 0.3413 0.2381 0.2794 0.8109 0.3617 0.4744 0.6836 0.6419 0.6772 yg c/ y 0.0728 0.0728 0.0728 0.6808 0.7004 0.6594 k/y 3.6282 3.7801 3.6282 b/ y 2.1271 7.4257 3.3678 sw sg s t, p s t ,b 0.1090 0.0356 0.0527 0.1119 - 0.1230 0.8096* s tr 0.8096* s tr 0.8096* s tr 0.1904* s tr 0.1904* s tr 0.1904* s tr Notes: (i) The parameterization is as Table 1 except that now 1 formula is used for all per capita quantities). 40 0.3 . (ii) u v p u p v b u b (the same Table 7 Long-run solution when the consumption tax rate is the residual instrument 1 Status quo economy 2 Cost-minimizing private providers 3 Cost-minimizing public providers -1.0342 -0.8274 -0.9892 -1.1652 -1.4819 -1.4057 -1.0591 0.4852 -0.9521 0.5976 -1.0685 0.5091 0.4117 0.2597 0.2938 0.3611 0.3605 0.3624 0.3437 0.2541 0.2868 0.8100 0.3111 0.4616 0.6877 0.0733 0.6766 0.0733 0.6903 0.0733 0.6851 0.7882 0.6781 3.6282 3.7512 3.6282 0.8000 0.8000 0.8000 c 0.1634 -0.0653 0.1055 sw sg s t, p s t ,b 0.1090 0.0310 0.0516 0.1119 - 0.1205 Variable up ub u cp cb ep eb wg / w p y g y c/ y k/y b/ y 0.8096* s tr 0.8096* s tr 0.8096* s tr 0.1904* s Notes: See notes of Table 6. tr 0.1904* s tr 0.1904* s tr 41 Table 8 Long-run solution when the labor tax rate is the residual instrument 1 Status quo economy 2 Cost-minimizing private providers 3 Cost-minimizing public providers -1.0276 -0.7922 -0.9765 4 Cost-minimizing private providers plus redistributive transfers -0.8697 -1.1627 -1.6094 -1.4251 -0.8697 -1.0534 0.4917 -0.9478 0.6433 -1.0619 0.5219 -0.8697 0.6101 0.4157 0.2336 0.2914 0.4679 0.3648 0.3808 0.3689 0.3938 0.3479 0.2731 0.2947 0.2244 0.8086 0.2656 0.4509 0.4386 0.6948 0.0741 0.7148 0.0741 0.7028 0.0741 0.7391 0.0741 0.6868 0.7908 0.6802 0.7888 3.6282 3.7254 3.6282 3.7784 0.8000 0.8000 0.8000 0.8000 l 0.2371 -0.0541 0.1816 -0.0342 sw sg s t, p s t ,b 0.1090 0.0269 0.0509 0.0353 0.1119 - 0.1188 - Variable up ub u cp cb ep eb wg / w p y g y c/ y k/y b/ y 0.8096* s tr 0.8096* s tr 0.8096* s tr 0.5353* s tr 0.1904* s Notes: See notes of Table 6. tr 0.1904* s tr 0.1904* s tr 0.4648* s tr 42 Table 9 Lifetime utility under regime switches, with the labor tax rate as the residual policy instrument in the long run 1 Status quo economy 2 From status quo economy to cost-minimizing private providers 3 From status quo economy to costminimizing public providers Up -102.7638 z - -80.4913 0.2532 -158.6424 -0.3515 -95.3712 0.1381 -97.7318 0.0524 -142.6349 -0.2359 -106.2813 -0.0025 U b z U z -116.2714 -105.3357 - 4 From status quo economy to costminimizing private providers plus redistributive transfers -88.5456 0.1551 -86.1088 0.3583 -88.0816 0.1938 Notes: (i) See notes of Table 6. (ii) For h p, b , U h t u (cth , eth , Yt g ) . (iii) U v U v U . (iv) z is p t 0 the constant private consumption supplement which makes U 43 p Ub. p b b Table 10 Long-run solution when public debt is the residual instrument Variable up ub u cp cb ep eb wg / w p y 1 Status quo economy 2 Cost-minimizing private providers 3 Cost-minimizing public providers -1.0436 -0.9791 -1.0675 -1.1724 -1.5041 -0.8698 -1.0681 0.4793 -1.0791 0.4963 -1.0299 0.4723 0.4076 0.2466 0.5978 0.3591 0.3419 0.3643 0.3415 0.2292 0.3830 0.8108 0.3378 1.3267 0.6839 0.6417 0.6939 yg c/ y 0.0683 0.0683 0.0683 0.6808 0.6993 0.7151 k/y 3.6282 3.7576 3.6282 b/ y 2.1272 7.5226 -0.0184 sw sg s t, p s t ,b 0.1090 0.0320 0.1971 0.1119 - 0.0845 0.8096* s tr 0.8096* s tr 0.8096* s tr 0.1904* s tr 0.1904* s tr 0.1904* s tr Notes: (i) The parameterization is as Table 1 except that now 1 formula is used for all per capita quantities). 44 0.7 . (ii) u v p u p v b u b (the same Table 11 Long-run solution when the consumption tax rate is the residual instrument 1 Status quo economy 2 Cost-minimizing private providers 3 Cost-minimizing public providers -1.0349 -0.8231 -1.0777 -1.1661 -1.5056 -0.8659 -1.0599 0.4854 -0.9531 0.6009 -1.0374 0.4657 0.4119 0.2510 0.5998 0.3612 0.3606 0.3623 0.3439 0.2451 0.3827 0.8100 0.2884 1.3560 0.6880 0.0687 0.6769 0.0687 0.6902 0.0687 0.6851 0.7893 0.7118 3.6282 3.7304 3.6282 0.8000 0.8000 0.8000 c 0.1634 -0.0699 0.2081 sw sg s t, p s t ,b 0.1090 0.0277 0.2024 0.1119 - 0.0868 Variable up ub u cp cb ep eb wg / w p y g y c/ y k/y b/ y 0.8096* s tr 0.8096* s tr 0.8096* s tr 0.1904* s Notes: See notes of Table 10. tr 0.1904* s tr 0.1904* s tr 45 Table 12 Long-run solution when the labor tax rate is the residual instrument 1 Status quo economy 2 Cost-minimizing private providers 3 Cost-minimizing public providers -1.0284 -0.7876 -1.0937 4 Cost-minimizing private providers plus redistributive transfers -0.8666 -1.1637 -1.6407 -0.8565 -0.8666 -1.0541 0.4919 -0.9501 0.6474 -1.0485 0.4556 -0.8666 0.6138 0.4159 0.2239 0.6054 0.4650 0.3649 0.3813 0.3593 0.3948 0.3481 0.2644 0.3827 0.2150 0.8085 0.2446 1.4100 0.4141 0.6951 0.0695 0.7157 0.0695 0.6843 0.0695 0.7411 0.0695 0.6868 0.7919 0.7074 0.7900 3.6282 3.7065 3.6282 3.7568 0.8000 0.8000 0.8000 0.8000 l 0.2371 -0.0613 0.3036 -0.0424 sw sg s t, p s t ,b 0.1090 0.0240 0.2123 0.0319 0.1119 - 0.0910 - Variable up ub u cp cb ep eb wg / w p y g y c/ y k/y b/ y 0.8096* s tr 0.8096* s tr 0.8096* s tr 0.5248* s tr 0.1904* s Notes: See notes of Table 10. tr 0.1904* s tr 0.1904* s tr 0.4752* s tr 46 Table 13 Lifetime utility under regime switches, with the labor tax rate as the residual policy instrument in the long run 1 Status quo economy 2 From status quo economy to cost-minimizing private providers 3 From status quo economy to costminimizing public providers Up -102.8394 z - -80.0365 0.2597 -161.8003 -0.3712 -95.6043 0.1396 -109.2500 -0.0630 -85.5912 0.3664 -104.7453 0.0188 U b z U z -116.3656 -105.4148 - 4 From status quo economy to costminimizing private providers plus redistributive transfers -88.2394 0.1594 -85.8381 0.3630 -87.7822 0.1982 Notes: (i) See notes of Table 10. (ii) For h p, b , U h t u (cth , eth , Yt g ) . (iii) U v U v U . (iv) z p t 0 is the constant private consumption supplement which makes U 47 p Ub. p b b REFERENCES [1] Alesina A., S. Ardagna, R. Perotti and F. Schiantarelli (2002): Fiscal policy, profits and investment, American Economic Review, 92, 571-589. [2] Angelopoulos K., A. Philippopoulos and M. Tsionas (2008): Does public sector efficiency matter? Revisiting the relation between fiscal size and economic growth in a world sample, Public Choice, 137, 245-278. [3] Angelopoulos K., J. Malley and A. Philippopoulos (2011a): Tax structure, growth and welfare in the UK, forthcoming in Oxford Economic Papers. [4] Angelopoulos K., B. Fernandez and J. Malley (2011b): The distributional consequences of supply-side reforms in general equilibrium, mimeo, Department of Economics, University of Glasgow. [5] Ardagna S. (2007): Fiscal policy in unionized labor markets, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 31, 1498-1534. [6] Atksinon A. and J. Stiglitz (1980): Lectures on Public Economics, McGraw-Hill Book Co., New York. [7] Benigno P. (2009): Price stability with imperfect financial integration, Journal of Money Credit and Banking, 41, 121-149. [8] Cavallo M. (2005): Government employment expenditure and the effects of fiscal policy shocks, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper Series, no 2005-16. [9] Christiano L. J. and M. Eichenbaum (1992): Current real-business-cycle theories and aggregate labor-market fluctuations, American Economic Review, 82, 430-450. [10] Conesa J., Kehoe T. and Ruhl K. (2007): Modeling great depressions: the depression in Finland in the 1990’s, Quarterly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Nov., 16-44. [11] Cullis J. and P. Jones (1998): Public Finance and Public Choice, 2nd edition, Oxford University Press Inc., New York. [12] Fernandez-de-Cordoba G., J. J. Perez, and J. L. Torres (2010): Public and private sector wages interactions in a general equilibrium model, Public Choice, published online: 29 September 2010, DOI 10.1007/s11127-010-9705-7 [13] Finn G. M. (1998): Cyclical effects of government’s employment and goods purchases, International Economic Review, 39, 635-657. [14] Forni L., M. Libero and S. Luca (2009): The general equilibrium effects of fiscal policy: estimates for the euro area, Journal of Public Economics, 93, 559-585. 48 [15] Garcia-Milà T., A. Marcet and E. Ventura (2010): Supply side interventions and redistribution, Economic Journal, 120, 105-130. [16] Linnemann L. (2009): Macroeconomic effects of shocks to public employment, Journal of Macroeconomics, 31, 252-267. [17] Lucas R. E. (1990): Supply-side economics: an analytical review, Oxford Economic Papers, 42, 293-316. [18] Mas-Colell A., M. Whinston and J. R. Green (1995): Microeconomic Theory, Oxford University Press, New York. [19] Mendoza E. G. and L. L. Tesar (1998): The international ramifications of tax reforms: Supply-side economics in a global economy, American Economic Review, 88, 226–245. [20] Mirrlees J., S. Adam, T. Besley, R. Blundell, S. Bond, R. Chote, M. Gammie, P. Johnson, G. Myles and J. Poterba (eds) (2010): Dimensions of Tax Design: The Mirrlees Review, Oxford University Press. [21] Mirrlees J., S. Adam, T. Besley, R. Blundell, S. Bond, R. Chote, M. Gammie, P. Johnson, G. Myles and J. Poterba (2011): Tax by Design: The Mirrlees Review, Oxford University Press. [22] Pappa E. (2009): The effects of fiscal shocks on employment and the real wage, International Economic Review, 50, 217-244. [23] Park H. and A. Philippopoulos (2003): On the dynamics of growth and fiscal policy with redistributive transfers, Journal of Public Economics, 87, 515-538. [24] Persson T. and G. Tabellini (1992). The politics of 1992: Fiscal policy and European integration, Review of Economic Studies, 59, 689-701. [25] Quadrini V. and A. Trigari (2008): Public employment and the business cycle, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 109, 723-742. [26] Schmitt-Grohé S. and M. Uribe (2004): Optimal fiscal and monetary policy under sticky prices, Journal of Economic Theory, 114, 198-230. 49