* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Fiscal policy in candidate transition countries
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Exchange rate regimes and shocks Fabrizio Coricelli Budapest, November 28, 2002 Outline CEECs are characterized by high volatility Volatility of shocks, volatility of policy Exchange rate regime: shock absorber or source of shocks Real and financial shocks Real: structural change and productivity shocks (Balassa-Samuelson) Financial: emerging market features Conclusons: Skepticism on flexibility Volatility GDP Terms of trade** CEECs* Real effective exchange rate** Real Gov’t interest revenue/G rate** DP Latin America 4,10 3,74 4,40 8,70 12,66 18,00 6,34 13,18 2,31 2,19 Emerging Asia 4,11 5,92 8,65 2,52 1,82 Advanced countries 2,09 3,73 5,90 2,07 1,02 *1993-2001 **Only Czech republic, Hungary, Poland and Romania Evolution of shocks Initially: price liberalization and structural change Over time: trade opening and integration with EU Over time: opening to capital flows (financial shocks) Trend effects and dynamics Trend real appreciation (Balassa- Samuelson): productivity shocks Cyclical co-movements External shocks: contagion Accounting for REA log(PT/PN)i,t = αoi - α1log(aT – aN)i,t - α2sharei,t - α3govreali,t + α4labi,t + εi,t 1,5 1 0,5 govreal 0 share T=1 T=2 T=3 T=4 T=5 T=6 T=7 T=8 lab prod -0,5 Actual RER Fitted Values -1 -1,5 -2 Balassa-Samuelson: Slovenia 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 1992 1993 Labor (IND/SER) 1994 Productivity diff. 1995 1996 Poli. (Labor (IND/SER)) 1997 1998 Poli. (Productivity diff.) -5.0% -10.0% Sep-02 Jun-02 Mar-02 Dec-01 Sep-01 Jun-01 Mar-01 Dec-00 Sep-00 Jun-00 Mar-00 Dec-99 Sep-99 Jun-99 Mar-99 Dec-98 Sep-98 hungary Jun-98 Mar-98 Dec-97 Sep-97 Jun-97 eu Mar-97 Dec-96 Sep-96 Jun-96 Mar-96 Dec-95 Sep-95 Jun-95 Mar-95 Dec-94 Sep-94 Cyclical co-movements Industrial production annual changes 3month moving average 25.0% 8.0% Poland 20.0% 6.0% 15.0% 4.0% 10.0% 2.0% 5.0% 0.0% 0.0% -2.0% -4.0% Trade openness Figure 1: Degree of Openness in the EU and the CEECs (exports plus imports of goods and services as percent of GDP in 2000) % 300 EU 250 CEECs 200 150 100 50 * 1999 Source: IMF: International Financial Statistics ITALY FRANCE GREECE UK POLAND* SPAIN GERMANY ROMANIA PORTUGAL FINLAND DENMARK SWEDEN LITHUANIA AUSTRIA LATVIA SLOVENIA BULGARIA HUNGARY NETHERLANDS CZECH REP. SLOVAK REP. BELGIUM IRELAND ESTONIA LUXEMBOURG 0 Poland: Flexible exchange rates Risk premium: Poland 1600 EMBI+ EMBI+ Poland 400 1400 350 1200 300 1000 250 800 200 600 150 400 100 200 50 0 1/30/1998 10/30/1998 0 7/30/1999 4/30/2000 1/30/2001 10/30/2001 7/30/2002 Risk premium: Poland 2 After adoption of flexible rates (in 2000) risk premium jumps up Before and after high correlation with EMBI+ Evolution of regimes Fix Stabilisation phase Czech Rep. 1990-1994 Estonia Hungary Latvia Lithuania Malta Poland Slovakia Transition phase 1995-2000 Bulgaria Estonia Latvia Lithuania Malta Preparatory phase Bulgaria 2001 - ERMII Estonia Latvia Lithuania Malta Intermediate Float Cyprus Bulgaria Slovenia Romania Czech Rep. Cyprus Hungary Poland Slovakia Slovenia Romania Cyprus Hungary Czech Rep. Poland Slovakia Slovenia Romania De jure classification according to the IMF. Fix: currency board, conventional peg, narrow band; Intermediate : tightly managed, broad band; Float : managed float, free float Heterogeneity Movement towards extremes Euro is the end-point:is the movement towards more flexibility reasonable? It depends on the ability of flexible rates to absorb shocks and insulate from currency and financial crises Exchange rate shock absorber? Response of exchange rate to external shocks Response of interest rates Habib (2002): high sensitivity to external shocks (change in risik premium). Poland and Czech Republic: Exchange rate follows EMBI+ shocks. Hungary and Slovenia: interest rate reacts. In both cases either real exchange rates and/or real interest rates move in response to international shocks 600 2 400 1 200 0 0 Forint one-year ex ante real rate Euro one-year zero-coupon yield Jan-02 3 Jul-01 800 Jan-01 4 Jul-00 1000 Jan-00 5 Jul-99 1200 Jan-99 6 Jul-98 1400 Jan-98 7 Jul-97 1600 Jan-97 8 basis points % Contagion and interest rates: Hungary EMBI+ (right-hand scale) Poland: interest rate spreads 12 2001 2002 Short term spreads vs. euro still large 10 8 Long-term 6 expectation of entry in the eurozone 4 2 0 3m 6m 1y 2y 3y 4y 5y 10y External constraint External constraint not to be underestimated Exposure to swings in foreign financing Low liability “euroization”? Need to be qualified (example of Hungary) These elements should be factored in when advising flexibility of exchange rates External position, External debt/GDP External debt/Exports 2000-01 Current Account/ GDP FDI /GDP Bulgaria Czech Estonia Hungary Latvia Lithuania Poland Romania Slovakia Slovenia 86.4 42.8 61.4 67.3 65.9 42.9 42.9 27.0 56.3 34.3 148.3 56.2 64.6 97.3 144.0 95.1 214.5 81.7 76.5 58.1 8.3 9.1 6.4 2.6 5.6 3.3 5.9 2.7 10.7 0.2 5.9 4.8 6.8 3.9 6.8 6.0 6.3 3.7 3.7 3.3 avg. CEECs 52.7 103.6 5.5 5.1 Exchange rate and inflation 1 Pass-through: eg. Darvas (2001); Coricelli et al. 2002 High pass-through, especially in Slovenia and Hungary Problem with inflation targeting Exchange rate and inflation 2 Difficulties in bringing down inflation at low rates Exchange rate flexibility may in fact make it worse Implicit real exchange rate targets internalized in the price setting…………. Slovenia 30 25 20 ip ner rer cpi 15 10 5 0 -5 -10 -15 -20 dic-93 feb-95 apr-96 giu-97 ago-98 ott-99 dic-00 feb-02 Czech Republic 25 20 ip ner rer cpi 15 10 5 0 -5 -10 -15 mar-94 mag-95 lug-96 set-97 nov-98 gen-00 mar-01 mag-02 Hungary ip rer 35 ner cpi 25 15 5 -5 -15 apr-94 ago-95 dic-96 apr-98 ago-99 dic-00 apr-02 Poland 35 ip ner rer cpi 25 15 5 -5 -15 -25 mar-94 mag-95 lug-96 set-97 nov-98 gen-00 mar-01 mag-02 Advantages of flexibility not obvious True: with inflationary inertia in the non tradable sector fixing the exchange rate may cause a temporary drop in output in non-tradables However, there would be gains in welfare associated to the reduction of losses due to monopolistic behavior in non tradable sectors (Calvo et al. (2002) Adoption of the euro Would avoid real appreciation induced by nominal appreciation arising from capital inflows Would allow immediate convergence in interest rates Would reduce inefficiency of monopoly power in non-tradable sectors Thus, nominal convergence may be less costly with euro than with flexibility of exchange rates