* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Monopoly Monopoly Definition A firm is considered a monopoly if
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Monopoly Monopoly Definition Herbert Stocker [email protected] Institute of International Studies University of Ramkhamhaeng & Department of Economics University of Innsbruck Repetition Remember: Firms maximize their profits subject to the restrictions they face. There are two kinds of restrictions: Technological restrictions. Market restrictions. A firm is considered a monopoly if . . . it is the sole seller of its product. its product does not have close substitutes. Repetition Remember: Technological restrictions are the same for monopolies and for firms on perfectly competitive markets. These are embedded in the cost function: Remember that we did not need the price of output for the derivation of the cost function! Only market restrictions differ between monopolies and firms on perfectly competitive markets. 1 Monopoly & Perfect Competition Monopoly & Perfect Competition Perfect Competition: Every supplier perceives demand for his own product as perfectly elastic, he can sell every unit of output for the same price. Therefore, marginal revenue is simply the price, and firms are price-takers! Perfect Competition vs. Monopoly Monopoly: A Monopolist is the only supplier and there are no close substitutes for his product. Therefore he perceives that the demand for his product is falling when he increases price. Monopolistic firms are price-seekers; if they want to sell more, they can do so only at a lower price! This has important implications for the marginal revenue of a monopoly, e.g. marginal revenue no longer equals price! Total and Marginal Revenue Perfect Competition: P ‘perceived’ Market Demand Monopoly: P ‘perceived’ Market Demand Q Q Each producer perceives the demand for his product as perfectly elastic. Monopolist perceives demand to be less than perfectly elastic. Example: Q =6−P Total Marginal Average Price Quantity Revenue Revenue Revenue P Q R =P ×Q MR AR = P 6 0 0 – – 5 1 5 5 5 4 2 8 3 4 3 3 9 1 3 2 4 8 −1 2 1 5 5 −3 1 0 6 0 −5 0 2 Marginal Revenue Demand: Q = 6 − P Marginal Revenue ⇒ Inverse Demand: P = 6 − Q [Inverse Demand allows us to express revenue as a function of Q only] P MR 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 Revenue: R = PQ = (6 − Q)Q = 6Q − Q 2 Marginal Revenue: dR MR ≡ = 6 − 2Q dQ 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Q Linear demand curves ⇒ MR curve is double as steep as demand curve! Marginal Revenue In detail: R1 = P1 Q1 R2 = P2 Q2 /− ∆R ≡ R1 − R2 = P1 Q1 − P2 Q2 = P1 (Q1 − Q2 ) + P1 Q2 − P2 Q2 = P1 (Q1 − Q2 ) + Q2 (P1 − P2 ) = P1 ∆Q + Q2 ∆P ≈ P∆Q + Q∆P MR= ∆R ∆Q ∆P = P + Q ∆Q If a monopolist increases output there are two effects: he can sell the additional produced units of output only at a lower price P: P × ∆Q but he has to sell also all other units of output at this lower price: Q × ∆P The resulting change in total revenue is therefore ∆R = Q × ∆P + P × ∆Q Marginal Revenue is ∆R ∆P ≡ MR = Q × +P ∆Q ∆Q Marginal Revenue With Calculus: Market Demand is a function of price: Q = Q(P) We rewrite this and express price as a function of quantity: P = P(Q). This is called inverse demand function. Revenue R can then be expressed as a function of Q only, i.e. R = P(Q) × Q For differentiating this use the product rule: dR dP MR ≡ = ×Q +P dQ dQ 3 Marginal Revenue Marginal Revenue Therefore, marginal revenue depends in a very specific way on the price elasticity of demand: Rearranging terms gives ∆P MR = P + Q × ∆Q ∆P Q = P +P P ∆Q Q ∆P = P 1+ P ∆Q 1 1 =P 1− = P 1+ EQ,P |EQ,P | 1 ∆R =P 1− MR ≡ ∆Q |EQ,P | When demand is elastic (|EQ,P | > 1) increasing output will increase revenue (MR > 0). When demand is inelastic (|EQ,P | < 1) increasing output will decrease revenue (MR < 0). Output, Price Elasticity & Revenue Monopoly What happens with monopolist’s revenue, when he reduces output? P E = −∞ P E = −∞ el tic as el bc tic as ∆P bc E = −1 E = −1 in tic as tic as el el in bc ∆P bc E =0 ∆Q Elastic Demand: Q↓⇒ P ↑⇒ R↓ Q E =0 ∆Q Inelastic Demand: Q↓⇒ P↑⇒ R↑ Q Example We can see from this simple analysis that a monopolist will never produce a quantity in the inelastic portion of the demand curve. Why? If demand is inelastic a decrease of quantity would increase revenue. Producing less would lower cost. This implies he could make higher profits by reducing the quantity, therefore this cannot be a maximum! More generally . . . 4 Profit Maximization Profit Maximization Monopolists like all firms maximize profit, and profit is the difference between revenue and cost π =R −C For a maximum it must be true that dπ dR dC ! = − =0 dQ |{z} dQ |{z} dQ MR MC Therefore profit maximization implies Perfect Competition For a firm on a perfectly competitive market demand is perfectly elastic, this implies MR = P. Therefore, profit maximizing firms choose output where MR = P = MC MR = MC This result is true for monopolists and for firms on perfectly competitive markets! Profit Maximization Monopoly For a monopolist marginal revenue is 1 MR = P 1 − |EQ,P | therefore a monopolist chooses output and price where 1 MR = P 1 − = MC |EQ,P | MR = MC holds generally, but MR is different for firms under perfect and imperfect competition! Monopoly: Profit Maximization Which quantity should a monopolist produce? P Lost Profit MC D(P) AC ⇒ ⇐ MC MR MR MC MR Q When marginal revenue is higher than marginal cost the firm should produce more! When marginal revenue is is smaller than marginal cost the firm should produce less! 5 Monopoly: Profit Maximization Which quantity should a monopolist produce? P MC D(P) bc AC MC MR MR Q ∗ QM Profits are maximized when the cost of the last unit are equal the revenue of the last unit, Monopoly: Profit Maximization Monopolies are ‘price-seekers’: P MC ∗ PM b b AC MR = MC Monopoly: Profit Maximization D(P) bc MR Q b ∗ QM Monopolist chooses the output where MR = MC, and charges the maximum price consumers are willing to pay for this output. Monopoly: Profit Maximization Profits: Profits: P P AC b Profits are defined as MC ∗ PM b b π π = (P − AC)Q AC b ∗ QM MC Loss b b D(P) bc b ∗ PM MR Q D(P) bc i.e. profits depend on average cost and price! If AC are high profits become negative, the monopoly runs a loss! (Still, this output level minimizes losses.) b ∗ QM MR Q 6 Monopoly In perfect competition, the market supply curve is determined by marginal cost. For a monopoly, output is determined by marginal cost and the shape of the demand curve (demand elasticity). Since supply depends on the demand curve, there is no supply curve for monopolistic market. Shifts in demand usually cause a change in both price and quantity. Monopoly Monopoly Profits of a monopolist: P Market demand: P = 4 − Q 4 Revenue: R = 4Q − Q 2 R Marginal revenue: MR = 4 − 2Q 3 π∗ C Cost: C = 0.2Q 2 + 0.5 ∗ Marginal cost: MC = 0.4Q P 2 MCCondition for profit maximum: MR MR = MC 1 4 − 2Q = 0.4Q bc bc bc bc 0 0 Example ∗ 1 Q2 3 4Q Q∗ π∗ = 1.667 = R ∗ − C ∗ = 2.833 Profits of a monopolist: P 4 Q =4−P ↔ R R = 4Q − Q 2 , 3 π∗ C C = 0.2Q 2 + 0.5, P∗ Q P R 0.00 4.00 0.00 2 0.50 3.50 1.75 3.00 3.00 MC 1.00 1.50 2.50 3.75 1.67 2.33 3.89 MR 2.00 2.00 4.00 1 2.50 1.50 3.75 bc P = 4−Q MR = 4 − 2Q MC = 0.4Q bc bc bc 0 0 3.00 3.50 4.00 ∗ 1 Q2 3 1.00 0.50 0.00 3.00 1.75 0.00 MR 4.00 3.00 2.00 1.00 0.67 0.00 -1.00 -2.00 -3.00 -4.00 C 0.50 0.55 0.70 0.95 1.06 1.30 1.75 2.30 2.95 3.70 MC 0.00 0.20 0.40 0.60 0.67 0.80 1.00 1.20 1.40 1.60 π -0.50 1.20 2.30 2.80 2.83 2.70 2.00 0.70 -1.20 -3.70 4Q 7 Monopoly: Alternative Presentation Profit with Total Cost: P 4 π∗ 3 P∗ 2 0 C bc MR 1 R MC bc ∗ 1 Q2 3 4Q π ∗ = R(Q) − C (Q) Attention: AC(Q ∗ ) = 0.63̇ MC(Q ∗ ) = 0.66̇ 3 P∗ 2 bc MC π∗ 1 bc 0 Profit with Average Cost: P 4 bc Long-Run Profit Maximization AC bcbc MR 0 0 ∗ 1 Q2 3 4Q In the long run . . . Monopolist maximizes profit by choosing to produce output where MR = LMC, as long as P > LAC Will exit industry if P < LAC! Monopolist will adjust plant size to the optimal level. π ∗ = (P − AC)Q Long-Run Profit Maximization A General Rule for Pricing Optimal plant is where the short-run average cost curve is tangent to the long-run average cost at the profit-maximizing output level. 8 Markup Pricing Markup Pricing Remember MR = P 1 − 1 |EQ,P | = MC This can be rearranged to express price directly as a markup over marginal cost MC P=h MC 1− 1 |EQ,P | i If e.g. |EQ,P | = 2 then P = MC/(1 − 0.5) = 2 × MC, i.e. the monopolist charges double MC! Markup Pricing: Supermarkets & Convenience Stores Example Supermarkets: Many firms, similar products. The estimated demand elasticity for individual stores is EQ,P ≈ −10 The profit maximizing markup is therefore P = MC/(1 − 0.1) = MC/0.9 ≈ 1.11MC Empirical evidence shows that prices are set about 10 – 11% above MC. Remember MR = P 1 − 1 |EQ,P | = MC Another way to rewrite this is P − MC 1 = P |EQ,P | The left-hand side, (P − MC)/P, is the markup over marginal cost as a percentage of price. Therefore, the optimal markup as a percentage of price is simply the inverse of the demand elasticity! Markup Pricing: Supermarkets & Convenience Stores Example Convenience Stores: Convenience differentiates shops The estimated demand elasticity for individual stores is EQ,P ≈ −5 The profit maximizing markup is therefore P = MC/(1 − 0.2) = MC/0.8 ≈ 1.25MC Prices are set about 25% above MC. Convenience stores might still have lower profits because of lower sales volume and high AFC! . . . 9 Markup Pricing: Rule of Thumb P Profits MC ∗ PM b D(P) bc AC b ∗ QM P π = (P − AC)Q b π Markup Pricing: Rule of Thumb MR Q are highest when MR = MC, but managers often don’t know their marginal cost! Market Power If demand is very elastic, there is little benefit to being a monopolist; the larger the elasticity, the closer to a perfectly competitive market. Pure monopoly is rare. However, also a market with several firms, each facing a downward sloping demand curve, will produce so that price exceeds marginal cost! ∗ PM b b bc bc b ∗ QM Therefore, managers sometimes use average cost AC (or AVC) as MC a proxy and produce where AC = MR. D(P) This results in smaller AC profits; but the loss might be small when MR demand is rather elasQ tic. Market Power Firms on markets with imperfect competition often produce similar goods that have some differences, thereby differentiating themselves from other firms. This gives them (limited) market power. The analysis in this chapter is also applicable in these cases. 10 Market Power Monopoly power is determined by ability to set price higher than marginal cost. For a pure monopoly market power is determined by the elasticity of demand the firm is facing. Since the monopoly is the only supplier the demand it is facing is total market demand. Degree of monopoly power is determined completely by elasticity of market demand. Market Power Market Power With more firms in the market offering close substitutes elasticity of demand is usually much higher, therefore the have much less market power. Demand for a firm’s product is usually (much) more elastic than the market elasticity. Even if market demand for eggs should be inelastic, demand for eggs from a specific farmer XXX is usually very elastic. Attention: For Managers only the elasticity of demand for their own product is relevant! Measures of Market Power Lerner Index: Remember: Monopoly power, however, does not guarantee profits. One firm may have more monopoly power but lower profits due to high average costs. Profit depends on average cost relative to price! measure of market power that focuses on the difference between a firm’s product price and marginal cost of production. L= P − MC 1 = P |EQ,P | Under perfect competition, i.e. when P = MC, L = 0. When L = 1 the market power is highest possible. 11 Measures of Market Power Cross Elasticity of Demand: Percentage change in the quantity demanded of good X relative to the percentage change in the price of good Y: EQX ,PY = ∂QX PY ∂PY QX The higher the cross price elasticity, the greater the potential substitution between goods and, therefore, the lower is market power. Sources of Monopoly Power Why do some firms have considerable monopoly power, and others have little or none? The less elastic the demand for a firm’s product, the more monopoly power a firm has. The monopoly power of a firm falls as the number of firms increases; all else equal. Managers would like to create barriers to entry to keep new firms out of market. Measures of Market Power Concentration Ratios: Measure market power by focusing on share of the market held by the largest firms. Assume that the larger the share of the market held by few firms, the more market power those firms have. Problems: Describe only one point on the size distribution. Market definitions may be arbitrary. Barriers to Entry Economies of scale and mergers. Barriers created by government. Input barriers. Brand loyalties. Consumer lock-in and switching costs. Network externalities. 12 Barriers to Entry Economies of Scale and Mergers Exist when a firm’s long run average cost curve slopes downward or when lower production costs are associated with larger scale of operation. Can act as a barrier to entry in different industries (→ MES) Mergers are particularly important in industries with economies of scale, e.g. technology, media, and telecommunications. Barriers to Entry: Natural Monopolies Natural Monopoly: when a firm can supply a good or service to an entire market at a smaller cost than could two or more firms. A natural monopoly arises when there are economies of scale over the relevant range of output, i.e., average cost curve is falling over the relevant range of output. Natural monopolies cause market failure, and are therefore often regulated or run by the government. Examples include tap water distribution systems, bridges, . . . Minimum Efficient Scale (MES) MES & Market Entries: Average cost at half of the MES (1/2 MES) is a indicator for technological market entry barriers. AC AC High market entry barriers bc bc bc Low market entry barriers bc MES MES 1 MES 2 1 MES 2 MES Q MES Q → important for intensity of competition, Mergers & Acquisitions, . . . Barriers to Entry Barriers Created by the Government Licenses (e.g. for physicians and other professionals). Patents and copyrights: The need for patent protection arises because innovations represent new information that has the characteristics of a public good. Public goods: A good that has high costs of exclusion and is nonrival in consumption. Because of free riding behaviour public goods would not be provided on free markets. 13 Barriers to Entry Input Barriers Control over raw materials (e.g. diamonds and DeBeers). Barriers in financial capital markets Larger firms can get lower interest rates. Smaller firms need more collateral for loans. Smaller firms are perceived as riskier. Barriers to Entry Consumer Lock-In and Switching Costs When consumers become locked into certain types or brands and would incur substantial switching costs if they changed. Managers often use consumer lock-in and switching costs strategies to gain market power. Examples for consumer lock-in and switching costs strategies: Contractual commitments Durable purchases Brand-specific training Specialized suppliers Search costs Loyalty programs, . . . Barriers to Entry Creation of Brand Loyalties The creation of brand loyalties through advertising and other marketing efforts is a strategy that managers use to create and maintain market power. Managers hope that demand for their product becomes less elastic by these measures. Barriers to Entry Network Externalities Act as a barrier to entry because the value of a product depends on number of customers using the product. Can be considered demand-side economies of scale, in contrast to supply-side economies. For example software systems. 14 Social Costs of Monopoly Power P Social Costs of Monopoly Power ∗ PM PC∗ b b b MC = AC bc b Q(P) MR b ∗ QM b QC∗ Q (For simplicity we assume constant MC and AC.) Perfect Competition & Welfare P Perfect Competition & Welfare Qs Cost to producers Value to Cost to buyers Qd producers Q Value to buyers Value to buyers Value to buyers is greater than cost to sellers! bc Monopoly power results in higher prices and lower quantities. However, does monopoly power make consumers and producers in the aggregate better or worse off? We can compare producer and consumer surplus. P PC∗ Perfect competition is efficient, because the allocation of resources maximizes total surplus! Consumer surplus Qs bc Producer surplus Qd QC∗ Q is less than cost to sellers! 15 Monopoy & Welfare Social Costs of Monopoly P Social cost of monopoly is likely to exceed the deadweight loss. The incentive to engage in monopoly practices is determined by the profit to be gained. Rent Seeking: Firms may spend to gain monopoly power MC Deadweight Loss PM PC∗ bc MR bc bc D QM QC∗ Q Public Policy Toward Monopolies Government responds to the problem of monopoly in one of four ways: Making monopolized industries more competitive. Regulating the behavior of monopolies. Turning some private monopolies into public enterprises. Doing nothing at all (if the market failure is deemed small compared to the imperfections of public policies). Lobbying Advertising Building excess capacity Antitrust Laws Antitrust laws are a collection of statutes aimed at curbing monopoly power. Antitrust laws give government various ways to promote competition. They allow government to prevent mergers. They allow government to break up companies. They prevent companies from performing activities that make markets less competitive. 16 Antitrust Issues Antitrust Issues Focus of the Horizontal Merger Guidelines: Legislation limits market power of firms and regulates how firms use their market power to compete. Antitrust legislation focuses for example on . . . Price discrimination that lessens competition. The use of tie-in sales and exclusive dealings. Mergers between firms that reduce competition. Regulation Definition of the relevant market. Level of seller competition in that market. Possibility that a merging firm might affect price and output. Nature and extent of entry into the market. Other factors influencing coordination among sellers. Extent to which any cost savings and efficiencies could offset increase in market power. Public Policy Toward Monopolies Government may regulate the prices that the monopoly charges: The allocation of resources will be efficient if price is set to equal marginal cost. However, in natural monopolies this will result in a loss! (When average cost (AC) fall marginal cost (MC) must be lower than AC. Optimal pricing P = MC would therefore result in losses!) In practice, regulators will allow monopolists to keep some of the benefits from lower costs in the form of higher profit, a practice that requires some departure from marginal-cost pricing. Rather than regulating a natural monopoly that is run by a private firm, the government can run the monopoly itself (e.g., sometimes the government runs the Postal Service). Government can do nothing at all if the market failure is deemed small compared to the imperfections of public policies. 17 Any Questions? 18