Download Research proposal - Digital Ecosystems

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts
no text concepts found
Transcript
TITLE: Business Networks and Ecosystems: rethinking the biological metaphor
AUTHORS: Angelo Corallo, Stefania Protopapa
INTRODUCTION
Driven by technological and market changes organizations compete and cooperate, and bring
firms to experiment alternative coordination mechanisms that lead to intermediate or hybrid forms
of organization. During the 90s, Powell and Castells argued that networks are distinctive form of
coordinating economic activity and made sense to classify as “business network” any organizational
structure adopting such a coordination mechanism.
Although research has made important contributions towards the understanding of business
networks, further theoretical and empirical research is required to develop a better understanding of
the processes underlying the structure and evolution of them.
Renewing the expectation of Marshall (1948) several authors look for inspiration in biological
science, electing “the theory of ecosystems” and “the evolutionary theory” as the main biological
research fields affecting social and economic science that provide innovative perspective and
theoretical models.
In this work, we look forward to rethink the biological metaphor in order to explain the real
relationship between business network and ecosystem in an evolutionary perspective.
BUSINESS NETWORKS AS BUSINESS ECOSYSTEMS
Castells (1996) proposed the concept of the networked enterprise as the organizational form that
a firm would adopt to fit the conditions of uncertain and unpredictable environments. According to
the same author, the strengths of the networked enterprise lie in the shift from vertical bureaucracies
to horizontal enterprise enabled by the use of digital technology to connect and relate dispersed
organizational nodes. In the networked enterprise, components are both independent of and
dependent on the network organization and can also be part of several other networks. A network
organization combines the advantage of bureaucratic organization with a structure that supports
innovation.
Networks (Quinn et al. 1998) could be shaped by pointing out the nodes where knowledge is
created and detained, the nodes where it is used to implement solution, and the kind of relationship
that links together the different nodes. Taking into account both firm and market perspectives, the
new organizational problem of the firms seems to be no longer that of granting alignment among
different department objectives, but of coordinating networks of knowledge-owning firms to create
added value products and services.
1
Inside clusters, a co-evolution process is emerging; it develops between the networks of
localized knowledge and the trans-local knowledge networks (Doz et al. 2001), based on digital
information exchange. These inter-organizational structures, defined as virtual clusters, are
characterized by collaboration and complementarities and by the exchange of mainly digital
knowledge. The concept of space is therefore crucial.
We may extend the concept of ‘actor agglomeration’ from industrial district to business
network, as the generalization of any agglomeration structure that is represented by a set of firms,
linked by some sort of spatial proximity (geographical, technological or institutional).
Economists belonging to any school of thought have discussed similarities between biological
evolution and economic development for more than a century (Hodgson, 1998). Basing on the
premise that "human beings exist wholly within nature as part of the natural order in every respect",
Jacobs (2000) argues that the same principles underlie both ecosystems and economies. In
particular, the author investigates the hypothesis according to which economic life obey the same
rules as those governing the systems in nature, arguing that economic life is ruled by processes and
principles that people do not invent and can not transcend.
Two serious drawbacks have always constrained the rigid application of biological metaphors to
the study of economic development. The first is that evolution involves no intentionality toward a
specific goal, whereas economic development is driven by the satisfaction of human wants. The
second is that, with the exception of the smallest levels of complexity (such as genes and microbes),
different biological species do not interbreed, while human beings produce new things by
relentlessly combining artefacts, skills and ideas (Basalla, 1988; De Gregori, 1985; Mokyr, 1990).
In this sense, economic development is the result of individuals trying to solve problems affecting
them by combining heterogeneous facts, ideas, faculties, and skills on a scale that is unparalleled in
the rest of nature (Jacobs, 2000).
Even if any comparison between economic and ecologic realms has to be careful, biological
ecosystems seem to provide a powerful metaphor for understanding a business network. As
biological ecosystems, business networks are communities of agents with different characteristics
and interests, bound together by different mutual relationships as a collective whole. Species within
ecosystems are related and interact with each other as much as firms play a specific role in a
business network. The fate of each living organism in the ecosystem is related to the fate of the
others; cooperation and competition, as much as in a business network, are considered ecosystem
characterizing phenomena.
Tansley (1935) firstly defined an ecosystem as the whole system represented by both the
biological organisms and a complex set of physical factors and he correlated the ecosystem with a
network of relationships. Starting from the definition by Tansley, Lindeman (1942) developed the
2
modern approach to the ecosystem by adopting Elton’s food web model and Lotka’s
thermodynamic approach (Elton, 1927; Lotka, 1925) .
The first approach to business ecosystem is due to Moore (1993) who argued that a firm is not
just a member of a single industry but a part of a business ecosystem that crosses a variety of
industries. In a business ecosystem, firms’ capabilities co-evolve around new innovations that
characterise the ecosystem itself, as the locus around which species co-evolve by exploring
innovative evolutionary path.
Extending Moore’s biological metaphor and emphasizing the keystone metaphor, Iansiti and
Levien (2004a) identified in keystone firms the leader and the centre of the ecosystem. They support
two basic items: that the food web model is useful to describe systems of organizations as a network
of mutual relationships, and that the new form of competition, the need for collaboration and the
process of market co-evolution are simply explained as a results of the biological metaphor
adoption.
Anyway we believe that biological metaphor proposed by Iansiti and Levien is hard to be used
as an instrument of analysis for the business ecosystem for some reasons. First, it uses both
thermodynamic and network theory in order to model interaction among populations and
environment, while the business ecosystem perspective is not able to model the environmental
conditions and can’t leverage the thermodynamic theory to build a business ecosystem theory.
Second, the concept of community, as defined in biological science, is proper to define Iansiti’s own
approach than the ecosystem one, since community takes care about populations relationships and
evolution, and excludes environmental interaction. Third, Iansiti identifies the role of leader in
keystone species that seem to have a role that is closer to the Iansiti artificial ecosystem than to the
natural ones.
As a consequence, the key question is: how could we design, or at least support the creation and
growth of natural business ecosystems? Although a business ecosystem may evolve toward
centralized structures, moving toward what Tapscott et al. (2000) define as an aggregator model, a
business ecosystem theory needs to be quite general in order to explain it as a kind of self
constructed and auto organized business network. In such a context, we focus on the understanding
of the rules that govern natural biological ecosystems and, as a consequence, natural business
ecosystems.
THE EVOLUTIONARY PERSPECTIVE
Evolutionary perspective is the common ground for a theory of organizational change, capable
of explaining the evolution of organizational models in terms of emergence and selection of new
species.
3
Organisms play two roles in evolution. The first is the basis for most evolutionary theory and it
consists of carrying genes; organisms survive and reproduce according to chance and natural
selection pressures in their environments. However, organisms also interact with environments and
modify at least some of the natural selection pressures present in their own, and in each other's,
local environments. This second role for phenotypes in evolution is not been subject to a great deal
of investigation: it is called "niche construction" (Odling-Smee 1988).
Niche construction should be regarded, after natural selection, as a second major participant in
evolution. It is the process whereby organisms, through their activities and choices, modify their
own and each other's niches. By transforming natural selection pressures, niche construction
generates feedback in evolution in a manner that alters the evolutionary dynamic. Odling-Smee et
al. (2003) developed a new approach to evolution that treats niche construction as a fundamental
evolutionary process in its own right: it is called extended evolutionary theory.
In this new perspective, culture adds a second knowledge inheritance system to the evolutionary
process through which socially learned information is accrued, stored, and transmitted between
individuals. Tylor (1871) defined culture as “that complex whole which includes knowledge, belief,
art, morals, custom and any other capabilities and habits acquired by man as member of a society”,
so how could such an inextricably interwoven complex of ideas, behaviour, and artefacts evolve?
EVOLUTIONARY THEORY AND ORGANIZATIONAL CHANGE
The first and most influential biological metaphor applied to socio economic science was
Darwinian selection on the population ecology by Hannan and Freeman (1977), that takes from the
biological perspective the suggestion of the emergence of new species of organizations that
compete for resources. According to Hannah and Freeman, each organization is defined by its
technology, structure, products or services, objective and people. These elements cause the
organization’s survival in the environment or make it disappear because of environmental selective
pressure.
The attempt to adapt the evolutionary theory as a metaphor for explaining business perspective
has a strong limitation in the lack of a unit of analysis for the evolution process, as gene for
biological evolution. As a consequence it is difficult to create a model describing the emergence of
organizational phenotypes in the evolution processes and their fitness respect to the environmental
conditions.
Nelson and Winter (1982) suggested an evolutionary model, mainly based on the parallelism
between genes and routines. The Nelson and Winter Evolutionary Theory of the Firm focuses the
attention on organizational routines as unit of knowledge. They consider routines as behavioural
patterns that workers use during their activities, which make different one firm from the others.
Partly driven by his attempt to show that Universal Darwinism (Dawkins, 1983) provides a suitable
4
framework for evolutionary economics (Hodgson and Knudsen 2006), also Hodgson suggests that
routines are like genotypes (Hodgson 2003, Hodgson and Knudsen 2003).
The routine approach can be extended separating the perspective between behaviour and thing:
according to Fontana (1998) behaviour is not a thing but it is property of a thing. As a consequence,
the organizational routines could represent the functions and the dynamical principles that govern
the interactions among the parts of the organization. In this perspective Nelson and Winter routines
became the phenotype of more complex genotypic elements that Padgett defines logic of identity.
According to Padgett (2001), organizations - social or biological - are developmental products
of these founder logics, interacting with the inherent properties of the social or biological raw
materials being assembled. In economic organization, these raw materials are in large part the social
networks of business interaction partners, selected through trading and personnel flows.
Social and political networks have the two-fold roles of generation and regulation of markets.
Recombination and refunctionality are the key elements through which organizational ideas and
models are transposed from one domain to another. Social and political networks operate through
negative feedback as a regulatory mechanism for transposition and reproduction, granting stability
and equilibrium to the systems (Padgett and Powell, 2003).
FINAL CONSIDERATIONS
In the attempt to review the biological metaphor overcoming the limitations highlighted before,
we considered the promising perspective come out from the studies of Fontana and Padgett.
The Fontana analysis about the relationships existing between phenotype, genotype and
populations gives the opportunity for a deepeening about organizational genotype, relationship
about organizational genotype and phenotype, environmental influence on the emergence of
organizational population.
The Padgett analysis focuses the attention on the systematic relationship between processes of
organizational birth and the surrounding social and economic contexts, out of which organizations
are constructed. This perspective fits organizational emergence in respect to the surrounding social,
economical and political environment.
Padgett logic of identity and multiple dynamic networks represent two key issues that enable
further research on business ecosystem theoretical foundation and give a fundamental contribution
in order to develop an evolutionary model for business network.
5
REFERENCES
BASALLA, G., The Evolution of Technology, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, (1988).
CASTELLS, M., The Rise of the Network Society, Oxford: Blackwell, (1996).
DARWIN, C., On the Origin of Species by Natural Selection, Murray (1859).
DAWKINS R. Universal Darwinism. In: Bendall DS (ed) Evolution from molecules to man.
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, pp 403–425, (1983)
DEGREGORI, T. R., A Theory of Technology: Continuity and Change in Human Development,
Ames, Iowa State University Press, (1985).
DOZ, Y., SANTOS J. and WILLIAMSON P., From Global to Metanational: How Firms Win in
the Knowledge Economy, Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press, (2001).
ELTON, C., Animal Ecology, New York: Macmillan, (1927).
FONTANA, W., ‘Mammals, Florence and chemistry: chance and necessity of change’,
Commentary on the paper of J. Padgett, ‘Organizational genesis, identity and control: the
transformation of banking in renaissance Florence’. Prepared for the seminar series on Philanthropy
and Social Change at the Robert Wood Johnson Foundation, Princeton, NJ, (1998).
HANNAN, M.T. and FREEMAN J., ‘The population ecology of organizations’, American
Journal of Sociology, 82, 929-964, (1977).
HODGSON, G., Socialism against markets? A critique of two recent proposals, Economy and
Society 27(4) : 407-33, (1998)
HODGSON G. M The mystery of the routine: the Darwinian destiny of an evolutionary theory
of change. Revue Écon 54(2) 355–384, Mars,(2003)
HODGSON G. M, KNUDSEN T. The firm as an interactor: firms as vehicles for habits and
routines, Mimeo,(2003)
HODGSON G. M, KNUDSEN T. Why we need a generalized Darwinism: and why generalized
Darwinism is not enough. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization (forthcoming), (2006)
IANSITI, M. and LEVIEN R., ‘Strategy as ecology’, Harvard Business Review, March, 68-78,
(2004a).
IANSITI, M. and LEVIEN R., The Keystone Advantage: What The New Dynamics of Business
Ecosystems Mean for Strategy, Innovation and Sustainability, Boston, MA: Harvard Business
School Press, (2004b).
JACOBS, J. The Nature of Economies, New York, The Modern Library (Random House),
(2000)
LINDEMAN, R., ‘The trophic-dynamic aspect of ecology’, Ecology, 23, 399-418, (1942).
LOTKA, A.J., Elements of Physical Biology, Baltimore, MD: Williamson and Wilkins, (1925).
6
MARSHALL, J.T.. Ecologic races of song sparrows in the San Francisco Bay region. Part 1:
Habitat and abundance. Condor 50:193-215, (1948).
MOKYR, J., The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress, Oxford,
Oxford University Press, 1990.
MOORE, J.F., ‘Predators and prey: a new ecology of competition’, Harvard Business Review,
May-June, 75-86, (1993).
NELSON, R.R. and WINTER S.G., An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Cambridge,
MA: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press (1982).
ODLING-SMEE, F.J.: 1988, ‘Niche Constructing Phenotypes’, in H.C. Plotkin (ed.), The Role
of Behavior in Evolution, MIT Press, Cambridge, pp. 73–132.
ODLING-SMEE F.J., LALAND K.N., FELDMAN M.W., Niche Contruction: the neglected
process in evolution, Princeton: Princeton University Press, (2003).
PADGETT, J.F., ‘Organizational genesis, identity and control: the transformation of banking in
Renaissance Florence, in A. Casella and J. Rach (eds), Networks and Markets, New York: Russell
Sage, pp. 211-257, (2001).
PADGETT, J.F. and W.W. POWELL, Market Emergence, Draft, (2003).
QUINN, J.B., ANDERSON, P. & FINKELSTEIN, S. New Forms of Organizing. In H.
Mintzberg & J.B. Quinn (Eds), Readings in the strategic process (pp. 162-174). Upper Saddle
River, NJ: Prentice Hall. 1998
TANSLEY, A.G., ‘The use and abuse of vegetational concepts and terms’, Ecology, 16, 204307, (1935).
TAPSCOTT, D., TICOLL D. and LOWY A., Digital Capital, Boston, MA: Harvard Business
School Press (2000).
TYLOR, E. B. Primitive culture: researches into the development of mythology, philosophy,
religion, art, and custom. 2 vols. London, John Murray (1871).
7