* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download 3 The Balance of Payments
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
National and International Accounts: Income, Wealth, and the Balance of Payments 5 1. Measuring Macroeconomic Activity: An Overview 2. Income, Product, and Expenditure 3. The Balance of Payments 4. External Wealth 5. Conclusions © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 1 Introduction • In this chapter, we study economic transactions between countries, how they are undertaken, and what impact they have on the macroeconomy. • The first task of any macroeconomist is to measure economic transactions. • The goals of this chapter are to: o explain the international system of trade and payments o discover how international trade in goods and services is complemented and balanced by a parallel trade in assets o see how these transactions relate to national income and wealth © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 2 1 Measuring Macroeconomic Activity: An Overview • At various points in the circular flow of payments, economic activity is measured and recorded in the national income and product accounts. • In an open economy, however, such measurements are more complicated because we have to account for cross-border flows. • These additional flows are recorded in a nation’s balance of payments accounts. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 3 1 Measuring Macroeconomic Activity: An Overview The Flow of Payments in a Closed Economy: Introducing the National Income and Product Accounts • Gross national expenditure (GNE) is the total expenditure on final goods and services by home entities in any given period. • GNE is made up of three parts: personal consumption C, investment I, and government spending G. GNE= (C + I + G) • A country’s gross domestic product (GDP) is the value of all (intermediate and final) goods and services produced as output by firms, minus the value of all goods and services purchased as inputs by firms. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 4 1 Measuring Macroeconomic Activity: An Overview The Flow of Payments in a Closed Economy: Introducing the National Income and Product Accounts • GDP is a product measure, in contrast to GNE, which is an income measure. • In a closed economy, income is paid to domestic entities. It thus equals the total income resources of the economy, also known as gross national income (GNI). © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 5 1 Measuring Macroeconomic Activity: An Overview FIGURE 5-1 The Closed Economy Measurements of national expenditure, product, and income are recorded in the national income and product accounts, with the major categories shown. The purple line shows the circular flow of all transactions in a closed economy. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 6 1 Measuring Macroeconomic Activity: An Overview The Flow of Payments in an Open Economy: Incorporating the Balance of Payments Accounts • The difference between payments made for imports and payments received for exports is called the trade balance (TB), it equals net payments to domestic firms due to trade. • GNE plus TB equals GDP, the total value of production in the home economy. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 7 1 Measuring Macroeconomic Activity: An Overview The Flow of Payments in an Open Economy: Incorporating the Balance of Payments Accounts • The value of factor service exports minus factor service imports is known as net factor income from abroad (NFIA), and thus GDP plus NFIA equal GNI, the total income earned by domestic entities from all sources, domestic and foreign. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 8 1 Measuring Macroeconomic Activity: An Overview The Flow of Payments in an Open Economy: Incorporating the Balance of Payments Accounts • Gifts may take the form of income transfers or “in kind” transfers of goods and services. • They are considered nonmarket transactions, and are referred to as unilateral transfers. • Net unilateral transfers (NUT) equals the value of unilateral transfers the country receives from the rest of the world minus those it gives to the rest of the world. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 9 1 Measuring Macroeconomic Activity: An Overview The Flow of Payments in an Open Economy: Incorporating the Balance of Payments Accounts • These net transfers have to be added to GNI to calculate gross national disposable income (GNDI). • Thus, GNI plus NUT equals GNDI, which represents the total income resources available to the home country. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 10 1 Measuring Macroeconomic Activity: An Overview The Flow of Payments in an Open Economy: Incorporating the Balance of Payments Accounts The current account (CA) is a tally of all international transactions in goods, services, and income (occurring through market transactions or transfers). © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 11 1 Measuring Macroeconomic Activity: An Overview The Flow of Payments in an Open Economy: Incorporating the Balance of Payments Accounts • The value of asset exports minus asset imports is called the financial account (FA). • These net asset exports are added to home GNDI when calculating the total resources available for expenditure in the home country. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 12 1 Measuring Macroeconomic Activity: An Overview The Flow of Payments in an Open Economy: Incorporating the Balance of Payments Accounts • A country may not only buy and sell assets but also transfer assets as gifts. • Such asset transfers are measured by the capital account (KA), which is the value of capital transfers from the rest of the world minus those to the rest of the world. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 13 1 Measuring Macroeconomic Activity: An Overview FIGURE 5-2 The Open Economy Measurements of national expenditure, product, and income are recorded in the national income and product accounts, with the major categories shown on the left. Measurements of international transactions are recorded in the balance of payments accounts, with the major categories shown on the right. The purple line shows the flow of transactions within the home economy. The green lines show all crossborder transactions. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 14 2 Income, Product, and Expenditure Three Approaches to Measuring Economic Activity • The expenditure approach looks at the demand for goods: it examines how much is spent on demand for final goods and services. The key measure is GNE. • The product approach looks at the supply of goods: it measures the value of all goods and services produced as output minus the value of goods used as inputs in production. The key measure is GDP. • The income approach focuses on payments to owners of factors: it tracks the amount of income they receive. The key measures are gross national income (GNI) and gross national disposable income (GNDI) (which includes net transfers). © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 15 2 Income, Product, and Expenditure From GNE to GDP: Accounting for Trade in Goods and Services • Personal consumption expenditures (usually called “consumption”) equal total spending by private households on final goods and services, including nondurable goods such as food, durable goods, and services. • Gross private domestic investment (usually called “investment”) equals total spending by firms or households on final goods and services to make additions to the stock of capital. Investment includes construction of a new house or a new factory, the purchase of new equipment, and net increases in inventories of goods held by firms (i.e., unsold output). © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 16 2 Income, Product, and Expenditure From GNE to GDP: Accounting for Trade in Goods and Services • Government consumption expenditures and gross investment (often called “government consumption”) equal spending by the public sector on final goods and services, including spending on public works, national defense, the police, and the civil service. It does not include any transfer payments or income redistributions, such as Social Security or unemployment insurance payments—these are not purchases of goods or services, just rearrangements of private spending power. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 17 2 Income, Product, and Expenditure From GNE to GDP: Accounting for Trade in Goods and Services (5-1) GDP C I G EX IM All imports, Gross All exports, Gross final & intermediate final & intermediate domestic national product expenditure GNE Trade balance TB This formula says gross domestic product is equal to gross national expenditure (GNE) plus the trade balance (TB). The trade balance (TB), also referred to as net exports, may be positive or negative. • If TB > 0, exports are greater than imports and we say a country has a trade surplus. • If TB < 0, imports are greater than exports and we say a country has a trade deficit. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 18 2 Income, Product, and Expenditure From GDP to GNI: Accounting for Trade in Factor Services • Gross national income equals gross domestic product (GDP) plus net factor income from abroad (NFIA). GNI C I G ( EX IM ) ( EX FS IM FS ) Gross nationalexpenditure GNE Trade balance TB (5-2) Net factor income from abroad NFIA GDP © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 19 APPLICATION Celtic Tiger or Tortoise? FIGURE 5-3 A Paper Tiger? The chart shows trends in GDP, GNI, and NFIA in Ireland from 1980 to 2011. Irish GNI per capita grew more slowly than GDP per capita during the boom years of the 1980s and 1990s because an everlarger share of GDP was sent abroad as net factor income to foreign investors. Close to zero in 1980, this share had risen to around 15% of GDP by the year 2000 and has remained there. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 20 2 Income, Product, and Expenditure From GNI to GNDI: Accounting for Transfers of Income If a country receives transfers worth UTIN and gives transfers worth UTOUT, then its net unilateral transfers (NUT), are NUT = UTIN − UTOUT . Adding net unilateral transfers to gross national income, gives a full measure of national income in an open economy, known as gross national disposable income (GNDI), henceforth Y: Y C I G ( EX IM ) ( EX FS IM FS ) (UT UT ) (5-3) GNDI GNE Trade balance (TB ) Net factor income from abroad ( NFIA) Net unilateral transfers (NUT ) GNI © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 21 HEADLINES The Asian tsunami on December 26, 2004, was one of the worst natural disasters of modern times. Hundreds of thousands of people were killed and billions of dollars of damage was done. Some aftershocks were felt in international politics. Jan Egeland, UN undersecretary general for humanitarian affairs and emergency relief, declared, “It is beyond me why we are so stingy.” His comments rocked the boat in many rich countries, especially in the United States where official aid fell short of the UN goal of 0.7% of GNI. However, the United States gives in other ways, making judgments about stinginess far from straightforward. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor AP Photo/Andy Eames Are Rich Countries “Stingy” with Foreign Aid? An Indonesian soldier thanks two U.S. airmen after a U.S. Navy helicopter delivered fresh water to Indonesian tsunami victims. The normal operating costs of military assets used for humanitarian purposes are not fully counted as part of official development assistance. 22 2 Income, Product, and Expenditure From GNI to GNDI: Accounting for Transfers of Income FIGURE 5-4 Major Transfer Recipients The chart shows average figures for 2000 to 2010 for all countries in which net unilateral transfers exceeded 15% of GNI. Many of the countries shown were heavily reliant on foreign aid, including some of the poorest countries in the world, such as Liberia, Eritrea, Malawi, and Nepal. Some countries with higher incomes also have large transfers because of substantial migrant remittances from a large number of emigrant workers overseas (e.g., Tonga, El Salvador, Honduras, and Cape Verde). © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 23 2 Income, Product, and Expenditure What the National Economic Aggregates Tell Us Y C I G {( EX IM ) ( EX FS IM FS ) (UT UT )} (5-4) GNDI GNE Trade balance (TB ) Net factor income from abroad ( NFIA) Net unilateral transfers (NUT ) Current account ( CA ) • On the left is our full income measure, GNDI. • The first term on the right is GNE, which measures payments by home entities. • The remaining terms measure net payments to the home country from all international transactions in goods, services, and income. We group the three cross-border terms into an umbrella term that is called the current account (CA). © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 24 2 Income, Product, and Expenditure Understanding the Data for the National Economic Aggregates TABLE 5-1 U.S. Economic Aggregates in 2012 The table shows the computation of GDP, GNI, and GNDI in 2012 in billions of dollars using the components of gross national expenditure, the trade balance, international income payments, and unilateral transfers. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 25 2 Income, Product, and Expenditure Some Recent Trends FIGURE 5-5 U.S. Gross National Expenditure and Its Components, 1990-2012 The figure shows consumption (C), investment (I), and government purchases (G) in billions of dollars. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 26 2 Income, Product, and Expenditure Some Recent Trends FIGURE 5-6 U.S. Current Accounts and Its Components, 1990-2012 The figure shows the trade balance (TB), net factor income from abroad (NFIA), and net unilateral transfers (NUT) in billions of dollars. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 27 2 Income, Product, and Expenditure What the Current Account Tells Us Y C I G CA (5-5) • This equation is the open-economy national income identity. It tells us that the current account represents the difference between national income Y (or GNDI) and gross national expenditure GNE (or C + I + G). Hence: • GNDI is greater than GNE if and only if CA is positive, or in surplus. • GNDI is less than GNE if and only if CA is negative, or in deficit. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 28 2 Income, Product, and Expenditure What the Current Account Tells Us • The current account is also the difference between national saving (S = Y − C − G) and investment: S I CA (5-6) Y C G • This equation is called the current account identity even though it is just a rearrangement of the national income identity. Thus, • S is greater than I if and only if CA is positive, or in surplus. • S is less than I if and only if CA is negative, or in deficit. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 29 APPLICATION Global Imbalances FIGURE 5-7 (1 of 2) Saving, Investment, and Current Account Trends: Industrial Countries The charts show saving, investment, and the current account as a percent of each subregion’s GDP for four groups of advanced countries. The United States has seen both saving and investment fall since 1980, but saving has fallen further than investment, opening up a large current account deficit approaching 6% of GDP in recent years. Japan’s experience is the opposite: investment fell further than saving, opening up a large current account surplus of about 3% to 5% of GDP. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 30 APPLICATION Global Imbalances FIGURE 5-7 (2 of 2) Saving, Investment, and Current Account Trends: Industrial Countries (continued) The Euro area has also seen saving and investment fall but has been closer to balance overall. Other advanced countries (e.g., non-Euro area EU countries, Canada, Australia, etc.) have tended to run large current account deficits. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 31 APPLICATION Global Imbalances • We define private saving (Sp) as that part of after-tax private sector disposable income Y that is not devoted to private consumption C. Sp Y T C (5-7) • We define government saving (Sg) as the difference between tax revenue T received by the government and government purchases G. Sg T G (5-8) • Private saving plus government saving equals total national saving, S S Y C G (Y T C ) (T G ) Privatesaving S p Sg (5-9) Government saving © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 32 APPLICATION Global Imbalances FIGURE 5-8 (1 of 2) Private and Public Saving Trends: Industrial Countries This chart shows private saving and the chart on the next slide public saving, both as a percent of GDP. Private saving has been declining in the industrial countries, especially in Japan (since the 1970s) and in the United States (since the 1980s). Private saving has been more stable in the Euro area and other countries. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 33 APPLICATION Global Imbalances FIGURE 5-8 (2 of 2) Private and Public Saving Trends: Industrial Countries (continued) Public saving is clearly more volatile than private saving. Japan has been mostly in surplus and massively so in the late 1980s and early 1990s. The United States briefly ran a government surplus in the late 1990s but has now returned to a deficit position. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 34 APPLICATION Global Imbalances Do government deficits cause current account deficits? • Sometimes they go together, but these “twin deficits” are not inextricably linked, as is sometimes believed. • We can use the equation just given and the current account identity to write CA S p Sg I (5-10) • The theory of Ricardian equivalence asserts that a fall in public saving is fully offset by a contemporaneous rise in private saving. • However, empirical studies do not support this theory: private saving does not fully offset government saving in practice. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 35 APPLICATION Global Imbalances FIGURE 5-9 (1 of 3) Global Imbalances The charts show saving (blue), investment (red), and the current account (beige) as a percent of GDP. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 36 APPLICATION Global Imbalances FIGURE 5-9 (2 of 3) Global Imbalances (continued) In the 1990s, emerging markets moved into current account surplus and thus financed the overall trend toward current account deficit of the industrial countries. Note: Oil producers include Norway. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 37 APPLICATION Global Imbalances FIGURE 5-9 (3 of 3) Global Imbalances (continued) For the world as a whole since the 1970s, global investment and saving rates have declined as a percent of GDP, falling from a high of near 26% to low near 20%. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 38 3 The Balance of Payments Accounting for Asset Transactions: The Financial Account • The financial account (FA) records transactions between residents and nonresidents that involve financial assets. This definition covers all types of assets: • real assets such as land or structures, • and financial assets such as debt (bonds, loans) or equity, issued by any entity. • Subtracting asset imports from asset exports yields the home country’s net overall balance on asset transactions, which is known as the financial account, where FA = EXA − IMA. • The financial account therefore measures how the country accumulates or decumulates assets through international transactions. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 39 3 The Balance of Payments Accounting for Asset Transactions: The Capital Account • The capital account (KA) covers two remaining areas of asset movement of minor quantitative significance. 1. the acquisition and disposal of nonfinancial, nonproduced assets (e.g., patents, copyrights, trademarks, etc.) 2. capital transfers (i.e., gifts of assets), an example of which is the forgiveness of debts • We denote capital transfers received by the home country as KAIN and capital transfers given by the home country as KAOUT. The capital account, KA = KAIN − KAOUT, denotes net capital transfers received. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 40 3 The Balance of Payments Accounting for Home and Foreign Assets • From the home perspective, a foreign asset is a claim on a foreign country. • When a home entity holds such an asset, it is called an external asset of the home country. • When a foreign entity holds such an asset, it is called an external liability of the home country because it represents an obligation owed by the home country to the rest of the world. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 41 The Double-Entry Principle in the Balance of Payments Summary of hypothetical international transactions 1. 2. 3. CA: Drinks in Paris bar −IM −$110 FA: Bar’s claim on AMEX +EXH +$110 CA: Arkansas wine exported to Denmark EX +$36 CA: Jutland wine imported to United States −IM −$36 FA: George’s French tech stocks -IMAF −$10,000 FA: BNP claim against Citibank +EXH +$10,000 A A © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 42 The Double-Entry Principle in the Balance of Payments Summary of hypothetical international transactions (continued) 4. 5. CA: Relief supplies exported to Bam −EX +$5,000 CA: George’s charitable gift −UTOUT −$5,000 KA: U.S. grant of debt relief −KAOUT −$1,000,000,000 FA: Decline in U.S. external assets −EXF +$1,000,000,000 A © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 43 3 The Balance of Payments Accounting for Home and Foreign Assets • If we use superscripts “H” and “F” to denote home and foreign assets, we can break down the financial account as the sum of the net exports of each type of asset: FA ( EX AH IM AH ) ( EX AF IM AF ) ( EX AH IM AH ) ( IM AF EX AF ) Net export of home assets Net export of foreign assets Net export of home assets = Net additionsto external liabilities Net import of foreign assets = Net additionsto external assets (5-11) • FA equals: o the additions to external liabilities (the home-owned assets moving into foreign ownership, net) o minus the additions to external assets (the foreign-owned assets moving into home ownership, net). © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 44 3 The Balance of Payments How the Balance of Payments Accounts Work: A Macroeconomic View • Recall that gross national disposable income is Y GNDI GNE TB NFIA NUT GNE CA Resources available to home country from income • In addition, the home economy can free up resources by engaging in net sales (or purchases) of assets. We calculate these extra resources using our previous definitions: [ EX KAOUT ] [ IM KAIN ] A A Value of all assets exported Value of all assets exported as gifts Value of all assets imported EX A IM A KAIN KAOUT Value of all assets imported as gifts Value of all assets exported via sales Value of all assets imported via purchases © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor FA KA Extra resources available to the home country due to asset trades 45 3 The Balance of Payments How the Balance of Payments Accounts Work: A Macroeconomic View • Adding the last two expressions, we have the value of the total resources available to the home country for expenditures. This total value is equal the total value of home expenditure on final goods and services, GNE: GNE CA Resources available to home country due to income FA KA GNE Extra resources available to the home country due to asset trades • Cancelling GNE from both sides we obtain the result known as the balance of payments identity or BOP identity: CA Current account + KA Capital account + FA = 0 (5-12) Financial account © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 46 3 The Balance of Payments How the Balance of Payments Accounts Work: A Microeconomic View • The components of the BOP identity allow us to see the details behind why the accounts must balance. CA (EX IM ) (EX FS IM FS ) (UT UT ) KA (KA KA ) FA (EX AH IM AH ) (EX AF IM AF ) (5-13) • If an item has a plus sign, it is called a balance of payments credit or BOP credit. • If an item has a minus sign, it is called a balance of payments debit or BOP debit. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 47 3 The Balance of Payments How the Balance of Payments Accounts Work: A Microeconomic View • We have to understand one simple principle: every market transaction (whether for goods, services, factor services, or assets) has two parts. • If party A engages in a transaction with a counterparty B, then A receives from B an item of a given value, and in return B receives from A an item of equal value. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 48 3 The Balance of Payments Understanding the Data for the Balance of Payments Account TABLE 5-2 (1 of 3) The U.S. Balance of Payments in 2012 The table shows U.S. international transactions in 2012 in billions of dollars. Major categories are in bold type. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 49 3 The Balance of Payments Understanding the Data for the Balance of Payments Account TABLE 5-2 (2 of 3) The U.S. Balance of Payments in 2012 (continued) The table shows U.S. international transactions in 2012 in billions of dollars. Major categories are in bold type. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 50 3 The Balance of Payments Understanding the Data for the Balance of Payments Account TABLE 5-2 (3 of 3) The U.S. Balance of Payments in 2012 (continued) The table shows U.S. international transactions in 2012 in billions of dollars. Major categories are in bold type. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 51 3 The Balance of Payments Understanding the Data for the Balance of Payments Account • A country that has a current account surplus is called a (net) lender. By the BOP identity, it must have a deficit in its asset accounts. • Any lender, on net, buys assets (acquiring IOUs from borrowers). For example, China is a large net lender. • A country that has a current account deficit is called a (net) borrower. By the BOP identity, it must have a surplus in its asset accounts. • Any borrower, on net, sells assets (issuing IOUs to lenders). As we can see, the United States is a large net borrower. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 52 3 The Balance of Payments Some Recent Trends in the U.S. Balance of Payments FIGURE 5-10 U.S. Balance of Payments and Its Components, 19902012 The figure shows the current account balance (CA), the capital account balance (KA, barely visible), the financial account balance (FA), and the statistical discrepancy (SD), in billions of dollars. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 53 3 The Balance of Payments What the Balance of Payments Account Tells Us • The balance of payments accounts consist of: o the current account, which measures external imbalances in goods, services, factor services, and unilateral transfers. o the financial and capital accounts, which measure asset trades. • Surpluses on the current account side must be offset by deficits on the asset side. Deficits on the current account must be offset by surpluses on the asset side. • The balance of payments makes the connection between a country’s income and spending decisions and the evolution of that country’s wealth. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 54 4 External Wealth • Just as a household is better off with higher wealth, all else equal, so is a country. • “Net worth” or external wealth with respect to the rest of the world (ROW) can be calculated by adding up all of the home assets owned by ROW and then subtracting all of the ROW assets owned by the home country. • In 2012, the United States had an external wealth of about –$4,474 billion. This made the United States the world’s biggest debtor in history at the time of this writing. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 55 4 External Wealth The Level of External Wealth • The level of a country’s external wealth (W) equals ROW assets Home assets External wealth = owned by home owned by ROW (5-14) W A L • A country’s level of external wealth is also called its net international investment position or net foreign assets. It is a stock measure, not a flow measure. If W > 0, home is a net creditor country: external assets exceed external liabilities. If W < 0, home is a net debtor country: external liabilities exceed external assets. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 56 4 External Wealth Changes in External Wealth • There are two reasons a country’s level of external wealth changes over time. 1. Financial flows: As a result of asset trades, the country can increase or decrease its external assets and liabilities. Net exports of home assets cause an equal increase in the level of external liabilities and hence a corresponding decrease in external wealth. 2. Valuation effects: The value of existing external assets and liabilities may change over time because of capital gains or losses. In the case of external wealth, this change in value could be due to price effects or exchange rate effects. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 57 4 External Wealth Changes in External Wealth • Adding up these two contributions to the change in external wealth (ΔW), we find Change in Financial external wealth account W Net export of assets = FA Capital gains on external wealth (5-15) Valuation effects = Capital gains minus capital losses • Since −FA = CA + KA, substituting this identity into Equation (5-15), we obtain Change in Current Capital Capital gains on external wealth account account external wealth (5-16) W CA = Unspent income KA = Net capital transfers received © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor Valuation effects = Capital gains minus capital losses 58 4 External Wealth Understanding the Data on External Wealth TABLE 5-3 (1 of 3) U.S. External Wealth in 2011-2012 The table shows changes in the U.S. net international investment position during the year 2012 in billions of dollars. The net result in row 3 equals row 1 minus row 2. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 59 4 External Wealth Understanding the Data on External Wealth TABLE 5-3 (2 of 3) U.S. External Wealth in 2011-2012 (continued) The table shows changes in the U.S. net international investment position during the year 2012 in billions of dollars. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 60 4 External Wealth Understanding the Data on External Wealth TABLE 5-3 (3 of 3) U.S. External Wealth in 2011-2012 (continued) The table shows changes in the U.S. net international investment position during the year 2011 in billions of dollars. The net result in row 3 equals row 1 minus row 2. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 61 4 External Wealth Some Recent Trends • For the past 30 years the United States has almost always had a financial account surplus, reflecting a net export of assets to the rest of the world to pay for chronic current account deficits. • If there were no valuation effects, then Eq. (5-15) implies that the change in the level of external wealth should equal the cumulative net import of assets over the intervening period. • But valuation effects or capital gains can generate a significant difference in external wealth. • From 1988 to 2012 these effects reduced U.S. net external indebtedness in 2012 by more than half compared with the level that financial flows alone would have predicted. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 62 4 External Wealth What External Wealth Tells Us • External wealth data tell us the net credit or debit position of a country with respect to the rest of the world. • They include data on external assets (foreign assets owned by the home country) and external liabilities (home assets owned by foreigners). • A creditor country has positive external wealth, a debtor country has negative external wealth. • Countries with a current account surplus (deficit) must be net buyers (sellers) of assets. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 63 4 External Wealth What External Wealth Tells Us • An increase in a country’s external wealth results from every net import of assets; conversely, a decrease in external wealth results from every net export of assets. • In addition, countries can experience capital gains or losses on their external assets and liabilities that cause changes in external wealth. • All of these changes are summarized in the statement of a country’s net international investment position. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 64 K e y POINTS Term KEY 1. National flows of expenditure, product, income, and wealth, and international flows of goods, services, income, and assets, together measure important aspects of a country’s economic performance and describe its economy’s relationship to economies in rest of the world. The records kept in the national income and product accounts, the balance of payments account, and the net international investment position track these data. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 65 K e y POINTS Term KEY 2. The key measures of economic activity are: • Gross national expenditure (GNE) measures an economy’s total spending on final goods. It is the sum of consumption, investment, and government consumption: GNE = C + I + G. • Gross domestic product (GDP) measures total production (value of all output minus value of all purchased inputs). • Gross national income (GNI) measures the total payments to an economy’s domestic factors. • Gross national disposable income (GNDI, also denoted Y) measures an economy’s disposable income including transfers. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 66 K e y POINTS Term KEY 3. In an open economy, GDP need not equal GNE. When nations can trade, the sum of goods and services demanded by domestic residents need not be the same as the sum of goods and services supplied by domestic firms. The difference between GDP and GNE is the trade balance TB: GDP = GNE + TB. The trade balance is the difference between a nation’s imports and exports of goods and services. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 67 K e y POINTS Term KEY 4. In an open economy, GDP need not equal GNI because imports and exports of factor services (measured by net factor income from abroad or NFIA) imply that factor income received by domestic residents need not be the same as factor payments made by domestic firms. Thus, GNI = GDP + NFIA. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 68 K e y POINTS Term KEY 5. In an open economy, the true level of disposable income is best measured by gross national disposable income or Y = GNDI. GNDI need not equal GNI because net unilateral transfers (NUT) to foreigners may be positive, due to foreign aid and other nonmarket gifts. Thus, Y = GNDI = GNI + NUT. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 69 K e y POINTS Term KEY 6. The sum of all the aforementioned international transactions, TB + NFIA + NUT, is called the current account (CA). © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 70 K e y POINTS Term KEY 7. From the relationships just outlined, we find that Y = C + I + G + CA. This expression is known as the national income identity. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 71 K e y POINTS Term KEY 8. National saving S is defined as Y − C − G. From the national income identity, we can derive the current account identity: S = I + CA. The current account equals investment minus saving. Movements in investment or saving, all else equal, feed directly into the current account. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 72 K e y POINTS Term KEY 9. All international trades in goods and services and in assets are recorded in an account known as the balance of payments (BOP). As a result of double-entry bookkeeping, and allowing for gifts and transfers, the BOP must sum to zero. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 73 K e y POINTS Term KEY 10. The BOP contains the following: • Net exports of goods and services, TB, called the trade balance • Net exports of factor services, NFIA, called the net factor income from abroad • Net unilateral transfers received, NUT, called the net unilateral transfers • Net transfers of assets received, KA, called the capital account • Net exports of assets, FA, called the financial account © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 74 K e y POINTS Term KEY 11. The first three items are the current account (CA). Since the BOP accounts sum to zero, this implies the balance of payments identity: CA + FA + KA = 0. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 75 K e y POINTS Term KEY 12. External wealth is a measure of a country’s credit or debt position versus the rest of the world. It equals external assets—rest of world (ROW) assets owned by home—minus external liabilities (home assets owned by ROW). The net export (import) of assets lowers (raises) a country’s external wealth. External wealth is one part of a country’s total wealth. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 76 K e y POINTS Term KEY 13. External wealth can change for one of two reasons: the export or import of assets (called financial flows) or changes in the value of existing assets due to capital gains or losses (called valuation effects). Both of these channels affect net external wealth. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 77 K e y TERMS Term KEY national income and product accounts balance of payments accounts gross national expenditure (GNE) gross domestic product (GDP) gross national income (GNI) trade balance (TB) net factor income from abroad (NFIA) net unilateral transfers (NUT) gross national disposable income (GNDI) current account (CA) financial account (FA) capital account (KA) national income identity national saving current account identity private saving government saving © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor external asset external liability BOP identity BOP credit BOP debit (net) lender (net) borrower external wealth (W) net creditor net debtor 78 APPENDIX TO CHAPTER 5 External Wealth and Total Wealth • External wealth is only part of a country’s total wealth, the sum of the home capital stock (all nonfinancial assets in the home economy, denoted K) plus amounts owed to home by foreigners (A) minus amounts owed foreigners by home (L): Total wealth = K + ( A - L) Home nonfinancial assets External wealth • Changes in the value of total wealth can then be written as follows: Change in Additions Additions Capital gains Capital gains + total wealth = to K + to A – L + on K on A – L Additions(acquisitons minus disposals) © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor Valuation effects (gains minus losses) 79 APPENDIX TO CHAPTER 5 External Wealth and Total Wealth • Additions to the domestic capital stock K are simply investment, denoted I. Additions to external wealth, A – L, equal net additions to external assets minus net additions to external liabilities Change in total wealth I Additionsto K = Additionsto assets in the home economy ( FA) Additionsto A L = Net import of assets into the home economy Capital gains Capital gains + + on K on A – L Valuation effects (gains minus losses) • Now, using the BOP identity, we know that CA + KA + FA = 0 so that minus the financial account –FA must equal CA + KA, hence we can write Change in Capital gains Capital gains + total wealth I CA KA on K on A – L © 2014 Worth Publishers Valuation effects (gains minus losses) International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 80 APPENDIX TO CHAPTER 5 External Wealth and Total Wealth • The BOP identity makes the connection between external asset trade and activity in the current account. We take the connection one step further using the current account identity, S = I + CA, which allows us to write Change in Capital gains Capital gains + total wealth S KA on K on A – L Valuation effects (gains minus losses) • The message of this expression is clear. As we all probably know from personal experience, there are only three ways to get more (or less) wealthy: do more (or less) saving (S), receive (or give) gifts of assets (KA), or enjoy the good (bad) fortune of capital gains (losses) on your portfolio. What is true about individuals’ wealth is also true for the wealth of a nation in the aggregate. © 2014 Worth Publishers International Economics, 3e | Feenstra/Taylor 81