Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Identifying Government Spending Shocks: It’s all in the timing By Valerie A. Ramey What is the Impact of an Increase in Government Spending? Traditional Keynesian Increase in Government Spending leads to: ↑ Output ↑ Consumption ↑ Hours ↑ Real Wage ↓ Investment Neoclassical Theory: Impact of Increased Gov. Aiyagari, Christiano, & Eichenbaum (1992), Baxter & King (1993) Key mechanism: Negative wealth effect increases labor supply ↑ Output ↓ Consumption ↑ Hours ↓ Real Wage ↓ or ↑ Investment New Keynesian Theory Rotemberg & Woodford (1992): Countercyclical markups Devereux, Head & Lapham (1996): increasing returns Gali, Lopez-Salido, Valles (2007): sticky prices, noncompetitive labor markets, rule-of-thumb consumers Ravn, Schmitt-Grohe, Uribe (2006): deep habits Empirical Evidence on the Impact of ↑ G • Papers using VAR techniques for identification e.g. Rotemberg and Woodford (1992), Blanchard and Perotti (2002), Fatás and Mihov (2001), Perotti (2004), Montford and Uhlig (2005), Galí, López-Salido, and Vallés (2006)), Perotti(2007) ↑ output • ↑ hours ↑ consumption ↑ real wages ↓ investment Papers using Ramey-Shapiro war dates e.g. Ramey and Shapiro (1998), Edelberg, Eichenbaum, and Fisher (1999), Burnside, Eichenbaum, and Fisher (2004), and Cavallos (2005)). ↑ output • ↑ hours ↓consumption ↓ real wages ↓ or ↑ investment Other Event Studies e.g. Giavazzi & Pagano’s (1990), Cullen & Fishback (2006), Barro & Redlick (2009) ↓consumption or no effect Outline of talk 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. Overview of behavior of government spending Generate results using the two methods on the same data and time period Compare the timing of war dates to the timing of VAR shocks Present theoretical model that explains both results Show that changing the timing on the war dates produces the same results as the VAR Introduction of 2 new “news” variables and extension of sample back to 1939 Real Government Spending Per Capita 1 3 4 1.5 5 2 6 2.5 7 3 8 3.5 Real Defense Spending Per Capita 1950 1960 1970 1980 year 1990 2000 2010 1950 1960 1970 1980 year 1990 Red lines are Ramey-Shapiro military dates + 9/11. (numbers in thousands of 2005 dollars) 2000 2010 Some Historical Perspective Real Defense Spending Per Capita 0 2 4 6 8 10 (thousands of 2005 dollars) 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 year 1990 2000 2010 0 .05 .1 .15 Components of Government Spending Fraction of nominal GDP 1950 1960 1970 defense state & local 1980 year 1990 2000 nondefense federal 2010 Two Leading Identification Methods 1. VAR method Order government spending first in a VAR, use standard Choleski decomposition to identify shocks to government spending. 2. Ramey-Shapiro Dates Augment system with a dummy variable that takes the value of unity at times when a major political event caused Business Week to begin forecasting large increases in defense spending. Shocks to the dummy variable rather than actual government spending are identified as the shock. Ramey-Shapiro Dates: The dummy variable takes the value of unity at 4 dates. 1950:3: North Korea invaded South Korea in late June 1950. 1965:1 Johnson began air strikes against N. Vietnam in Feb. 1965. 1980:1 The USSR invaded Afghanistan on Dec. 24, 1979. *2001:3 Terrorists struck the World Trade Center and the Pentagon on 9/11. Framework for Comparison X t A( L) X t 1 U t X includes: total govt spending, GDP, Barro-Redlick tax rate, total hours (including military), nondurable + services consumption, private fixed investment, product wage in private business. Log per capita (except BS tax, product wage) Quarterly data: 1947:1 – 2008:4, 4 lags, quadratic trend Identification Standard VAR: order government spending first War dates: also include current and 4 lags of RameyShapiro war dates variable augmented with 9/11. 1950:3, 1965:1, 1980:1, 2001:3 Set shock size so that peak response of government spending is the same across specifications Comparison of Identification Methods VAR shocks in top row; War dates in bottom row 68% bands total hours -.12 -.2 -.4 0 0 0 .4 .12 .2 .8 .4 .27 gdp 1.2 government spending 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter quarter government spending gdp total hours 16 20 16 20 -.12 -.2 -.4 0 0 0 .4 .12 .2 .8 .4 .27 quarter 1.2 0 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter Comparison of Identification Methods VAR shocks in top row; War dates in bottom row 68% bands consumption, ndur + serv real wages -.18 -.12 -.06 -.9 -.2 -.6 -.1 -.3 0 0 0 .06 .12 .3 .1 investment, nonres + res 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter quarter consumption, ndur + serv investment, nonres + res real wages 16 20 16 20 -.18 -.12 -.06 -.2 -.9 -.6 -.1 -.3 0 0 0 .06 .3 .12 quarter .1 0 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter Why Do these Two Methods Give Such Different Results? It’s All in the timing I will argue that the shocks identified by the VAR are mostly anticipated and this explains all of the difference in the results. Defense Spending During Vietnam War .4 0 .5 .5 .6 .7 1 Defense Spending During Korean War 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 VAR Shocks During Vietnam War -.1 -.05 -.04 -.02 0 0 .05 .02 .1 .04 .15 VAR Shocks During Korean War 1970 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 Business Week Defense Forecasts 10 50 20 60 30 70 40 80 50 Business Week Defense Forecasts 1970 1965 1950 1951 1952 fiscal year actual Aug 50 forecast 1953 1954 Jun 50 forecast Sep 50 forecast 1966 1967 fiscal year actual Aug 65 forecast Jan 67 forecast 1968 1969 Jan 65 forecast Sep 66 forecast May 67 forecast .15 .2 .2 .3 .25 .4 .3 .5 .35 .4 Defense Spending During 9/11 .6 Defense Spending During Carter-Reagan 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1999 2001 2002 2003 2004 VAR Shocks During 9/11 0 .05 -.05 -.1 -.04 -.02 0 .02 .1 .04 VAR Shocks During Carter-Reagan 2000 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1999 2001 2002 2003 2004 OMB Defense Forecasts 300 350 400 450 500 100 150 200 250 300 350 OMB Defense Forecasts 2000 1980 1982 1984 1986 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 fiscal year actual Jan. 1980 forecast Oct. 1981 forecast Jan. 1979 forecast Jan. 1981 forecast actual Feb. 2002 forecast Feb. 2004 forecast Apr. 2001 forecast Feb. 2003 forecast Survey of Professional Forecasters 0 .02 .04 .06 Forecasts of Real Federal Spending Growth from Quarter t-1 to t+4 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Are VAR shocks anticipated? Yes. Hypothesis Tests p-value in parenthesis Do War dates Granger-cause VAR shocks? Yes (0.017) Do one-quarter ahead Professional Forecasts Granger-cause VAR shocks? 1981:3 – 2008:4 Yes (0.025) Do four-quarter ahead Professional Forecasts Granger-cause VAR shocks? 1981:3 – 2008:4 Yes (0.016) Do VAR shocks Granger-cause War dates? No (0.148) A simple model shows how getting the dates wrong can lead to faulty inferences. Very simple model with government spending and lump-sum taxation. Simulate a defense spending process similar to data. The key is that the new spending is announced two quarters before it happens, similar to what we saw in the data. Model Yt ( Z N )0.67 Kt0.33 t t U log( Ct ) log( 1 Nt ) t Yt Ct I t Gt Kt 1 I t (1 0.023) Kt ln Z t .95 ln Z t 1 ezt , ez 0.01 ln t .95 ln t 1 et , e 0.008 ln GFt constant 1.4 ln GFt 1 0.18 ln GFt 2 0.25 ln GFt 3 eg t , ln Gt ln GFt 2 eg 0.028 Theoretical Effect of an Increase in Government Spending (announced two quarters in advance) hours .04 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter quarter quarter consumption investment real wages 20 16 20 0 16 -.005 -.01 wg -.015 -.2 -.04 -.1 -.03 0 ig -.02 cg .1 -.01 .2 0 .3 0 0 0 .01 .01 0 .25 gg .5 yg .02 .02ng.03 .03 1 .75 .05 gdp .04 government spending 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter Estimation of VARs on Simulated Data Actual Spending Identification in top row; News in bottom row 68% bands gdp hours 0 -.1 -.05 0 -.05 .4 0 .8 .05 .05 .1 1.2 government spending 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter quarter quarter government spending news gdp hours 16 20 16 20 0 -.05 -.1 0 -.05 .4 0 .8 .05 .05 .1 1.2 0 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter Estimation of VARs on Simulated Data Actual Spending Identification in top row; News in bottom row 68% bands real wages 8 12 16 -.04 20 0 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter quarter quarter consumption investment real wages .4 20 16 20 -.04 -.06 -.8 -.05 -.025 -.4 0 -.02 0 0 .025 16 .02 4 .05 0 -.06 -.05 -.8 -.025 -.4 0 -.02 0 0 .025 .4 .02 investment .05 consumption 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter If the argument is right, then delaying the military dates should produce the standard VAR results Procedure: delay Ramey-Shapiro dates to time of first big VAR defense shock. Actual 1950:3 1965:1 1980:2 2001:3 Delayed Dates 1951:1 1965:3 1981:4 2003:2 Empirical Results from Delaying the Timing of the Ramey-Shapiro Military Dates Estimates on Actual Data total hours -.1 -.2 -.5 0 0 0 .1 .5 .2 .2 1 .4 .3 gdp 1.5 government spending 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter quarter consumption, ndur + serv investment, nonres + res real wages 20 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 -.1 -.4 -.05 -.2 0 0 .05 .1 .2 .1 .2 .4 .15 16 .3 quarter .6 0 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter A New Measure of Defense Shocks The simple dummy variable incorporates only a small part of the information available in the narrative record. Thus, I created a new variable: the present discounted value of the forecasted changes in defense-related spending. This is what matters for the wealth effect. I created the variable by reading mostly Business Week, but also the New York Times, Washington Post, and Wall Street Journal from January 1939 to December 2008. Business Week 5/25/40, p. 60: “The German drive to the English Channel this week assured quick adoption of the President’s program to speed up war preparations. But the proposed expenditure of less than $3.5 billion in the coming fiscal year is only a small beginning; of that, business men can now be certain… In the 1919 fiscal year costs ran to $11 billion. A major war effort in the ‘40s would come higher… since we have started six years behind, a vast outlay is required if we are to attain military parity with Hitler’s industrial machine. In a major war at least four times the $3.5 billion we plan to spend in 1941 would be needed, and quite conceivably five to six times that – or anywhere from 20% to 30% of the peacetime national income. However, it is not possible to jump immediately up from a $3.5 billion to a $14 billion military effort. It takes time to shift a nation from a peace economy to a war-preparation economy and thence to a war economy. Right now we are at the very beginnings of a war-preparation economy.” Business Week 10/25/41: “Expect dramatic developments in the defense program in the next few weeks. Plans were under way before the Kearny incident and the sinking of two more American ships but they have been speeded by this week’s shocks and by the heartening reports on Russia’s capacity to hold out, brought home by the Harriman mission. Beginning this week, war production –and it’s ‘war,’ not ‘defense’ …becomes the No. 1 item on the business docket.” p. 7 “Already, Washington is taking cognizance of the imminence of a shooting war…A year ago, the government thought of armament expenditures of $10 billion a year; six months ago the goal was $24 billion; as recently as last month $36 billion was regarded as a desirable but hard-to-achieve outlay; but now an annual expenditure of $50 billion is begin seriously discussed – not as the desirable goal, but as an inescapable necessity.” p. 13 -20 0 20 40 60 80 Defense News: PDV of Expected Change in Spending as a % of lagged GDP 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 year 1990 2000 2010 Explanatory Power of New Defense Shock Series for Growth of Real Per Government Spending 1 2 3 R-squared F-statistic 1939:1 – 2008:4 0.410 37.58 Marginal Fstatistic 9.00 1947:1 – 2008:4 1955:1 – 2008:4 0.518 0.037 51.15 1.60 19.65 0.429 Columns 1 and 2 from regression on current and 4 lags of shock. Column 3 is from full VAR. Framework for Defense News VAR X t A( L) X t 1 U t X includes: defense news variable (as a % of lagged GDP), total govt spending, GDP, Barro-Redlick tax rate, 3-month T-bill rate 6th variable is rotated in. Newly constructed Quarterly data: 1939:1 – 2008:4, 4 lags, quadratic trend VAR with Defense News Variable: 1939-2008 (red lines: 68%; green lines: 95%) total hours .1 -.1 -.1 -.5 0 0 0 .1 .5 .2 1 .3 .2 gdp 1.5 government spending 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 16 20 quarter quarter manufacturing wage 3 month Tbill rate average marginal income tax rate .1 .05 -.05 -6 -.2 -4 -.1 0 -2 0 0 .1 2 .2 4 .15 quarter .3 0 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 VAR with Defense News Variable: 1939-2008 (red lines: 68%; green lines: 95%) services consumption .1 0 -.05 -.2 -40 -.15 -20 -.1 .05 -.05 0 0 20 .15 nondurable consumption .05 real baa bond rate 0 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 16 quarter quarter consumer durable purchases nonresidential investment residential investment 20 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 -1 -2 -1 -1 -1.5 -.5 -.5 -.5 0 0 0 .5 .5 .5 quarter 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 Effect of Defense Shocks with and without WWII (Blue: 1939 - 2008; green: 1947 – 2008) total hours -.5 -.05 -.05 0 0 0 .05 .05 .1 .5 .1 .15 .2 .15 gdp 1 government spending 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 16 20 quarter quarter manufacturing wage 3-month Tbill rate average marginal income tax .1 quarter -.05 -.1 -4 -.3 -3 -.2 -2 0 -.1 -1 0 .05 0 .1 1 0 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 Effect of Defense Shocks with and without WWII (Blue: 1939 - 2008; green: 1947 – 2008) real baa bond rate nondurable consumption .02 .04 .06 .08 -40 -.1 -.02 0 -20 -.05 0 0 20 .05 services consumption 0 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 16 quarter quarter consumer durable purchases nonresidential investment residential investment .2 -1 -.8 -.5 -.6 -.4 -.5 0 -.2 0 0 .5 20 .5 quarter 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 Alternative Measure for Later Period •The defense news variable has little predictive power for the post-Korean War Period. •As an alternative, I use government spending shocks constructed using data from the Survey of Professional Forecasters. 1968:4 – 1981:2: Forecast nominal defense spending, GDP deflator 1981:3 – 2008:4: Forecast real federal spending Shock(t) = Δ ln(gt) - Et-1Δ ln(gt) VAR with Shock Based on Professional Forecasters: 1968-2008 (red lines: 68%; green lines: 95%) -.6 -1 -.5 -.4 0 -.5 -.2 .5 0 0 1 .2 .5 total hours .4 gdp 1.5 government spending 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 16 20 quarter quarter quarter business wage 3 month Tbill rate average marginal income tax rate 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 .2 .1 -.1 -.3 -.4 -60 -.2 -40 -.2 0 -20 0 0 .2 20 .4 0 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 VAR with Shock Based on Professional Forecasters: 1968-2008 (red lines: 68%; green lines: 95%) services consumption 0 4 8 12 16 -.2 -.4 -.8 -100 -.6 -50 -.4 -.2 0 0 0 .2 .2 nondurable consumption 50 real baa bond rate 20 0 4 8 12 16 20 0 4 8 12 16 quarter consumer durable purchases nonresidential investment residential investment 20 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 -2 -4 -6 -3 -3 -2 -2 -1 -1 0 0 0 2 1 4 quarter 1 quarter 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 0 4 8 12 quarter 16 20 Conclusions Standard VAR methods appear to identify shocks that are anticipated. Anticipation effects are very important from the view point of a neoclassical model. Both theory and empirical evidence suggests that difference in standard VAR results and Ramey-Shapiro dates is due to faulty timing of VAR shocks. Bottom Line: An increase in (nonproductive) government spending lowers consumption and has a multiplier of unity or less.