Download Has Algeria suffered from the Dutch disease? Evidence from 1960

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Fei–Ranis model of economic growth wikipedia , lookup

Exchange rate wikipedia , lookup

Non-monetary economy wikipedia , lookup

Fear of floating wikipedia , lookup

Rostow's stages of growth wikipedia , lookup

Chinese economic reform wikipedia , lookup

Đổi Mới wikipedia , lookup

Post–World War II economic expansion wikipedia , lookup

Transformation in economics wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Has Algeria suffered from the Dutch disease?
Evidence from 1960-2013 data*
Farid GASMI
Toulouse School of Economics (Arqade & Idei)
and
Imène LAOURARI
Université Abdelhamid Mehri-Constantine 2
Abstract
Algeria is strongly dependent on oil exports revenues to fuel its economy and following the 1986
oil counter-shock this country has experienced a persistent decline of its manufacturing sector.
Although it has benefited from high oil prices over the last decades and implemented a myriad of
economic reforms, Algeria has failed to develop its manufacturing sector and diversify its
economy. One of the main mechanisms through which fluctuations in oil prices can constitute an
impediment to the development of the manufacturing sector, and hence to long-term growth, in
an economy that heavily relies on a natural resource exports is referred to in the literature as the
Dutch disease. This paper aims to test whether or not Algeria’s economy has suffered from the
main symptoms of this syndrome by analyzing data covering more than half-a-century. More
specifically, we use annual data from 1960 to 2013 and investigate two important implications of
this phenomenon that occur following an oil boom, namely, the "spending effect" and the
"resource movement effect." According to the former the real exchange rate of the domestic
currency should appreciate while the latter merely says that the manufacturing sector should be
expected to shrink. We perform some simple tests of these signs of the Dutch disease using a set
of regressions while controlling for some other factors that could have led to similar economic
symptoms. The results do not allow us to unambiguously claim that the Algerian economy has
suffered from the Dutch disease over the period under study.
Key words: Algeria, Oil, Dutch disease, Real exchange rate, Manufacturing sector.
JEL-codes: O13, O14, O55, Q32, Q43, C32.
January 2016
*
Corresponding author: [email protected]. Parts of this material were worked out while I. Laourari was
doing a research internship at the Toulouse School of Economics in 2015 under a grant from the Jean-Jacques
Laffont Foundation. This author expresses her deep gratitude to the JJL Foundation for its support. An earlier version
of this paper was presented at the conference "Les ressources naturelles dans les pays en développement : Moteur de
croissance ou élément de vulnérabilité économique ?," Béjaïa, Algeria, November 29-30, 2015. We thank partcipants
to this conference for useful comments.
1. Introduction
A widely spread argument in both academic and institutional circles is that resource-rich
countries face a tradeoff. On the one hand, the resource endowment provides these countries’
government with revenues to be used to foster economic development and increase social
welfare. On the other hand, the economic behavior of the market for the resource may
substantially unbalances growth across sectors. For example, a resource boom such as a favorable
shock in oil prices may be expected to lead to a significant appreciation of the domestic currency
leading to a contraction of the country’s non-resource sectors, in particular, the manufacturing
sector. The latter known to be an important source of innovations and technological spillovers,
the consequence would then be permanent decrease of growth rates in the economy. This is the
phenomenon that has been characterized in the literature as the Dutch disease.1
The expression Dutch disease was first coined in a 1977 article published in The Economist
with reference to "the adverse effects on Dutch manufacturing of the natural gas discoveries of
the nineteen sixties, essentially through the subsequent appreciation of the Dutch real exchange
rate." Subsequently, a vast literature has investigated, on both theoretical and empirical grounds,
this phenomenon seeking to bring evidence of its existence in natural resource-rich economies.
Initially though, scholars mainly paid attention to the theoretical foundations of the Dutch disease
concept. The seminal work by Corden and Neary (1982) is considered as a breakthrough in
understanding the two fundamental mechanisms through which this phenomenon works, namely,
the resource movement effect and the spending effect. The first effect refers to how a booming
tradable sector drives resources away from a lagging tradable sector, whereas the second effect,
accounts for the outcome of increasing incomes from the booming sector being spent on the nontradable sector and imports. As the literature grew, attention shifted to the empirical examination
of the existence of Dutch disease and its consequences. The more recent studies further explore
this issue by investigating policy implications and responses to the Dutch disease with an
emphasis on fiscal policy.
1
The Dutch disease is typically associated with mineral resources. Representative examples of events in economic
history the consequences of which have been given a Dutch disease-type of interpretation include the discovery of
gold in Australia in the 1850s, the gas boom in the Netherlands in the 1960s, the North Sea Oil in the 1970s, and the
experience in oil-exporting countries following the boom in oil prices. However, its mechanics are also valid in some
other contexts such as a wealth increase that springs from a technological improvement in the non-mining tradable
sectors or a large inflow of foreign aid to developing countries.
2
Like many of the resource-rich countries, Algeria is strongly dependent on oil exports
revenues to fuel its economy. This country is among the top ten net oil exporters in the world and
the top three oil producers in Africa. It began oil production in 1958 while still a French colony
and joined the OPEC cartel in 1969 as an independent country. The Algerian economy, like that
of other oil exporting countries, is permanently exposed to oil price fluctuations since oil exports
accounts for 98% of the country's total exports, contributes over 60% of the total government
revenues and accounts for 30% of GDP. During the 1970s, Algeria has benefited from important
revenue windfalls thanks to the sharp increase in oil prices following the 1973 and 1979 oil
shocks. These substantial revenues gave the country the opportunity to design and implement a
very promising development strategy based on massive investments in infrastructures and heavy
industries in order to rapidly catch-up with the high-income economies. Algeria's
industrialization process was indeed regarded as the sine qua non condition to reach sustained
levels of economic and social development.
Throughout the 1970s and up to the early 1980s, Algeria gave the impression of a country
enjoying a degree of economic development and socio-political stability. This period was
characterized by sustained levels of economic growth with an annual growth of 4.7% on average
over the 1970-1985 period and significant enhancements in social welfare. The contribution of
the manufacturing sector to GDP increased from 12% in the late 1960s to reach 16% in the
1970s, while the unemployment rate decreased from 32% to 21% over the same period.
Following the 1986 oil counter-shock, however, the Algerian economy unveiled its structural
vulnerability. This sudden slump in oil revenues jeopardized the government’s ability to support
employment and domestic consumption. The country was on the verge of bankruptcy and was
forced to implement drastic measures, such as freeze investment spending in the industrial sector.
In fact, this period announced the inception of the country's deindustrialization process.
Indeed, the share of manufacturing output fell from 11.38% in the 1980s to 7.46% in the
1990s. As a result, the economy plunged into a long recession. GDP growth has significantly
decreased between 1986 and 1994 and fell from 4.7% to 1.4% between 1986 and 2002.
Moreover, high inflation rate, foreign debt and unemployment were recorded. The industrial
sector in Algeria had continued to experience sluggish growth since shortly after the adoption, in
1994, of the Structural Adjustment Program. Despite the recent oil revenue windfalls and the
myriad of economic reforms introduced so far by the government to improve the country's
industrial performance, Algeria is still struggling to develop its manufacturing sector and
3
diversify its economy. In contrary, the contribution of manufacturing output to GDP fell from
11.5% in 1995 to 5.9% in 2013. The daunting questions that these observations call for is then:
To what extent can one attribute the steady decline of the Algerian manufacturing sector to the
availability of oil resources and why is it that this sector hasn’t positively responded to the many
policies conducted by the Algerian government aimed at diversifying its economy? The answers
to these questions clearly take us to the heart of the Dutch disease argument and this study
questions its validity as an explanatory story for the evolution of the Algerian economy.
The main purpose of this article is to test whether or not Algeria’s economy has suffered
from the main symptoms of the Dutch disease by analyzing data covering more than half-acentury. More specifically, we use annual data from 1960 to 2013 and investigate two important
implications of this phenomenon, namely, the "spending effect" and the "resource movement
effect." According to the former, the real exchange rate of the domestic currency should
appreciate while the latter merely says that the manufacturing sector should shrink. We test for
these signs of the Dutch disease using a set of regressions while accounting, through control
variables, for other factors that could have led to similar economic symptoms.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 overviews some studies that
we think are most related to our work. Section 3 briefly describes our data, which covers the
1960-2013 period, and discusses some aspects of the econometric methodology used to analyze
these data. Section 4 reports our results and Section 5 summarizes our findings and gives some
concluding remarks. An appendix contains complementary material on data and sources.
2. Related literature
There exists an extensive literature that discusses various aspects of the Dutch disease
phenomenon, in particular, the negative impact of a mining boom on a country’s manufacturing
sector. This section briefly surveys some of the most important theoretical pieces on the subject
and examines some empirical studies that have considered this issue and are most related to our
work. This review is by no means exhaustive but rather serves the purpose of guiding us in
identifying relevant variables and choosing appropriate proxies for these variables.
In its original meaning, the expression "Dutch disease" refers to the side effects of a
resource windfall on a country’s manufacturing sector and, more broadly speaking, on this
4
country’s economic performance.2 The basic mechanics of this phenomenon is as follows. An
increase in a natural resource exports revenues leads to a surplus in the balance of payments
owing to the rising prices and/or volumes, which induces a significant appreciation of the real
effective exchange rate of the national currency. This appreciation harms domestic non-resource
sectors competitiveness and results in a leakage of resources from manufacturing. Even though
this contraction of the manufacturing sector following a natural resource boom is the essence of
the Dutch disease phenomenon, over time this concept has evolved to encompass a broader set of
negative macroeconomic effects associated with what is viewed as a resource curse.3
In the literature on the Dutch disease, the core model is usually associated with Corden and
Neary (1982). A presentation of these authors’ complete model is clearly beyond the scope of our
empirical paper, yet it is useful to recall here its main ingredients and the lessons to be drawn. In
its basic form, this model considers a small open economy comprising three sectors, a booming
sector, a tradable goods sector, and a non-tradable goods sector.4 The prices of the goods in the
booming and the tradable goods sectors are set in the world market whereas those of the nontradable goods are determined by domestic factors. Output in the three sectors is produced by
means of two inputs, a sector-specific input and labor assumed to be mobile among the three
sectors.
These authors identify two effects of the booming sector on the economy. The first effect is
referred to as the "resource movement effect" or "direct deindustrialization." The increase of
labor demand in the booming sector leads to a shift of labor from the tradable sector to the
booming sector and thus will directly decrease output in the tradable sector. Moreover, the
movement of labor from the non-tradable sector to the booming sector at constant prices will
reduce the supply of non-tradable goods and create an excess demand in this market.
Consequently, the price of non-tradable goods in terms of tradable goods rises and this real
2
The expression "Dutch disease" itself somewhat embodies some element of confusion. In its initial sense, it referes
to the structural industrial changes steming from an inrush of wealth into an economy and the subsequent
reallocation of domestic expenditures across sectors. The consequence of this resource reallocation that the literature
has emphasized is a significant shrinking of the manufacturing sector and its negative impact on growth. Given that
this phenomenon reflects an arguably "rational" reaction of economic agents to the arrival of new and easy wealth,
appealing to a disease may appear as a paradox. To be sure, it can be indeed seen as such from the perspective of the
workers and enterprise owners in the industries that are negatively affected by the phenomenon.
3
Basically, the Dutch disease relates to a structural problem that springs from the deprivation of resources from the
manufacturing sector which diminishes its capacity to generate basic innovations and know-how that foster steady
long-term economic growth. Moreover, the concentration on natural resource exports and the absence of output
diversification make the economy more vulnerable to external economic shocks.
4
The booming sector is typically the oil or gas sector but can include other minerals. The tradable goods sector
generally refers to manufacturing and/or agriculture and the non-tradable goods sector to services.
5
appreciation of non-tradable goods further shifts resources out of the tradable goods sector into
the non-tradable goods sector.
The second effect, known as the "spending effect" or "indirect deindustrialization," stems
from the fact that the boom brings in national income and hence increases demand for both the
tradable and non-tradable sectors’ products. The price of the non-tradable good will thus rise
while those of the other sectors’ products remain unchanged as they are determined in
international markets. As a result, the non-tradable sector’s output diminishes because the
increase in their relative price harms domestic production and makes it less attractive.5
The combination of these two effects creates the so-called Dutch disease. Altough Corden
and Neary (1982) focus on describing the mechanism through which the tradable goods sector
contracts subsequent to a boom in the mineral sector, they indicate that their conclusions may be
altered in several ways. In particular, they show that by modifying some of the underlying
assumptions, the predicted negative effects of the boom on the tradable goods sector may be less
severe and even, in some cases, that there may not be a Dutch disease at all.6
A large stream of the literature has contributed to the Dutch disease theory based on Corden
and Neary’s model. For instance, arguing that the effects of the boom on both traded and nontraded goods sectors are inherently dynamic, Bruno and Sachs (1982) extend the static analysis
by allowing for capital mobility not only among the domestic sectors but also from abroad. Under
these less restrictive assumptions, they show that although the basic result of the Dutch disease
analysis remains valid, i.e., a resource boom leading to an unequivocal decline in tradable goods
production, international capital mobility eliminates the relative increase in the price of nontraded goods. They emphasize the role of generated capital inflow saving and suggest
government budget policy for mitigating the effects of the Dutch disease.
Wijnbergen (1984) points out that the Dutch disease phenomenon becomes a real issue
when a process of learning by doing that stimulates technological progress is trapped in the
tradable goods sector. This author presents a straightforward two-sector-two-period model in
which productivity in the second period depends on the first period’s output and tests the
5
Again, this induces a real exchange rate appreciation which in turn brings about an additional movement of labor
out of the tradable goods sector into the non-tradable goods sector reinforcing the direct deindustrialization
phenomenon.
6
For instance, Corden (1984) shows that if an economy is initially in a situation where all domestic resources are not
fully employed before the boom, the latter may actually have a stimulating effect on the tradable sector.
6
assumption that a temporary decline in the "new technology" producing sector permanently
lowers productivity and hence the country's income per capita. The author also investigates the
question of whether oil revenues from a boom and their negative impact upon the tradable goods
sector could be alleviated by increasing production subsidies. He finds that the optimal size of the
production subsidy is the result of a tradeoff between current welfare losses and future benefits
associated with such a subsidy.7
A whole strand of the literature has attempted to customize the above theoretical
framework to less developed economies. Focusing on the impact of oil resources in Cameroon,
Benjamin et al. (1989) argue that if some important characteristics of developing countries, such
as imperfect substitutability between domestic and imported goods, are included in the basic
model, then the standard conclusions may change. Using a multisectoral computable general
equilibrium model to assess the impact of an oil revenue increase on the economy, they find
rather poor support for Dutch disease. Indeed, they conclude that not only the boom of the
resource sector had no significant negative effect on manufacturing, but also, strinkingly, that
some industrial sectors have even shown signs of growth. Nevertheless, they find that the
agricultural sector has seemingly declined following the boom.
More recently, Hamilton and Hartwick (2009) set out a model of a small open economy
that exports oil and a traditional exportable in return of imported capital. The small open
economy also has local production of a non-tradable good. They consider that an unexpected oil
stock discovery represents an unanticipated jump in capital imports from abroad and explore the
consequences of the country's economy. The effects they find support a classic Dutch Disease
phenomenon. Indeed, they show that, subsequent to an exogenous increase in the country’s oil
stock, the size of the traditional export sector declines, the domestic goods sector expands, the
domestic wage and price of the domestic good rise, and the rentals on land contracts. One of their
main conslusions is that the Dutch disease effects are intensified when the economy uses less
produced capital (all rented from abroad) after the oil discovery than before the discovery.
It is widely admitted that the Dutch disease occurs via two distinct channels, one resulting
in a fall in the output share of non-natural resource tradables relative to non-tradables (the
7
Wijnbergen (1984) finds that subsidies for tradables should be increased if the country does not accumulate foreign
assets during a boom but rather uses this wealth for final consumption. If a country manages to break the link
between oil booms and total expenditure through accumulation of foreign assets, no clear policy comes out of the
model. In fact, as foreign assets income enables the flow of resources into the non-traded goods sector, it may not be
necessary to switch to production of non-oil traded goods.
7
resource movement effect), and another leading to a real exchange rate appreciation (the
spending effect). The literature has, however, not always dealt these two channels in a
simultaneous manner. Bruno and Sachs (1982) and Wijnbergen (1984) examnine only the
spending effect. Krugman (1987) focuses on the resource movement and argues that it gives rise
to a major issue being that the tradable sector cannot recover its relative loss of influence after the
depletion of the natural resources that led to the boom. Nonetheless, the author considers that
specialization is in general beneficial thus underestimating the dynamic effects of the destruction
that it implies. Barry and Bradley (1997) look at the impact of foreign direct investment in
Ireland back in the 1980s and 1990s. The authors report that this large inflow of capital slowed
the increase of wages because of high supply of skilled labor, thereby ruling out the resource
movement effect of the Dutch disease.
A plethora of empirical studies has investigated the existence of the Dutch disease in
different countries. We already mentioned Benjamin et al. (1989) who analyze the impact of an
oil boom on a developing country and discuss the case of Cameroon. One the main conclusions
of these authors has been already highlighted in their previous paper, Benjamin et al. (1986),
namely, the performance differential between the agriculture and industrial sectors of oilexporting countries during the post-1973 period, a phenomenon that clearly calls for government
intervention. Fardmanesh (1991) uses 1966-1986 annual data on five oil-exporting developing
countries, namely, Algeria, Ecuador, Indonesia, Nigeria, and Venezuela to estimate a three-sector
reduced form model and investigate the impact of an oil boom/price increase on the economy.
The author finds that, on the one hand, under the pressure of the spending effect the agricultural
sector shrinks and the non-traded goods and the protected manufacturing sectors expand. On the
other hand, due to the world-price effect, the agricultural sector contracts and the protected
manufacturing sector expands. To illustrate their point, they argue that the oil price surge of the
1970s led to a shrinking of the agricultural sector and an expansion of the (protected)
manufacturing sector and, to some large extent, the non-traded goods sector. Conversely, the oil
collapse of the 1980s has ultimately promoted the agricultural sector and undermined the
manufacturing sector and non-traded goods sectors. In sum, the analysis of these panel data
provide empirical support to the Dutch disease hypotheses.
Bjornland (1998) examines the impact of energy booms on manufacturing output in
Norway and the UK. Using quarterly data from 1976 to 1994, the author estimates a VAR model
containing variables that proxy manufacturing production, oil and gas extraction, real oil prices,
8
and inflation. The results show only weak evidence of the Dutch disease, with other
macroeconomic variables, such as changes in aggregate supply and demand, accounting for a
much larger share of fluctuations in manufacturing output. An interesting finding that has
relevance for policy-makers is that Norway’s manufacturing sector actually benefited from
energy discoveries and higher oil prices. Bjornland attributes this to macroeconomic policies that
explicitly sought to protect manufacturers by using part of the windfall from higher energy prices
to subsidize manufacturing industries over a transition period. In contrast, the UK did not follow
such a strategy, and large increases in unemployment brought about by factory closures led to
increase spending on social programs instead.
Oomes and Kalcheva (2007) investigate whether from 1995 to 2005 the Russian economy
has seen its real exchange rate appreciate and the growth of its manufacturing sector slow down.
Regarding the first symptom, they estimate the empirical long-run relationship between the real
exchange rate and its determinants. They find evidence of stable cointegration relationships
between the real exchange rate, the oil price, and other relevant variables for the period.
Regarding the second symptom, they use sector-level data to compare growth rates across
Russian sectors for output and employment. They find evidence that Russia also exhibited this
symptom of Dutch disease. In particular, their sectoral data show that the manufacturing sector
has grown relatively more slowly than other sectors since 2001 and manufacturing employment
growth has even lessened. However, the authors emphasize that it is difficult to conclude that the
observed symptoms are indeed the result of the Dutch disease, because they can be explained by
other factors that presumably they didn’t control for.
Jbir and Zouari-Ghorbel (2011) examine the impact of oil price increases on key
macroeconomic variables of the Algerian economy. Using a VAR model both with linear and
non-linear specification to analyze data over the period 1995-2007, they find that in the short
term the real exchange rate appreciated. The authors argue that oil price shocks which lead to
higher inflation rates represent the main cause of this appreciation of the real exchange rate. The
non-linear effects of these shocks on the economic activity are however found not to be
significant during the period analyzed. Moreover, monetary shocks as reflected in the money
market rate do not seem to constitute a significant explanatory factor of the economic activity
recession.
9
Recently, Mironov and Petronevich (2015) have investigated the effects of the oil boom
of the 2000s on the Russian economy. Based on the predictions of the classical model of Corden
and Neary (1982), their analysis seeks to characterize the linkages between changes in the real
effective exchange rate of the Russian Ruble and the evolution of the Russian economic structure
over the 2002-2013 period. Controlling for the existence of large-scale state-owned enterprises,
an important feature of the Russian economy, they provide evidence of a negative relationship
between the real effective exchange rate and growth of the manufacturing sector as well as total
income of workers. Moreover, they find that real effective exchange rate and return on capital are
positively related in all of the three sectors considered in the standard model, namely, oil,
manufacturing, and services. Finally, although they conclude on the existence of various Dutch
desease symptoms in the Russian economy during the period of interest, the authors point out
that, while clearly observable, the shift of labor from manufacturing to services cannot be
explained by the appreciation of the Ruble alone.
It appears from the above, admittedly not exhaustive, literature review that the empirical
evidence on the existence of the Dutch disease remains mixed and generally inconclusive.
Although it has been observed in many countries, there is a broad consensus among researchers
that the phenonmenon need not be an unavoidable consequence of a natural resource boom. In
some countries, such as the Netherlands and Norway, the negative impact of the real exchange
rate appreciation on the manufacturing sector appears to be very small. Relatedly, Sachs and
Warner (2001) find that countries with high resource-exports to GDP ratios experience lower
growth rates. More recently, Ismail (2010) finds a much stronger evidence of Dutch disease
effects with a 10% increase in an oil windfall associated with a 3.4% fall in value added across
manufacturing sectors. These effects are larger in economies that are more open to capital flows
and with relatively less capital-intensive manufacturing sectors. Other studies corroborate similar
findings. For instance, a panel data study of 62 Sub-Saharan and developing countries by
Elbadawi et al. (1997) and another study by Lartey (2008) for Philippines find evidence of Dutch
disease effects.
It is important to emphasize that scholars are increasingly paying more attention to the role
of policy in mitigating and managing Dutch disease consequences rather than to the conception
of models to assess the existence and impact of this phenomenon in some specific countries.8 For
8
The case of Norway has been examined by Gylfason (2001) and Larsen (2005) and that of Botswana by Gylfason
(2001).
10
instance, Corden (2012) argues that the best policy response to Dutch disease would be to "do
nothing" and allow the currency to appreciate and raise the real consumption wage as a result of
lower import prices. The author further stresses that piecemeal protectionism to safeguard
industries affected by Dutch disease would increase the negative effect on other industries that
are also affected by the stronger currency and would do more damage to the economy.9 Generally
speaking, efforts should be aligned towards the creation of a favorable economic environment,
characterized by stability, flexibility, and competitiveness. A comprehensive approach is required
to address the broader competitiveness and productivity growth of an economy while protecting
it from volatility of international commodity and capital markets. Such an approach would go a
long way towards promoting product and export diversification in the long-run (Kojo, 2014).
To conclude this review, we should mention that it has been suggested in the literature on
the Dutch disease that the mixed findings may be explained by the failure of most of the studies
to take into account the country’s political framework and the nature of the country’s
institutions.10 An alternative point that the literature has pointed out is the difficulty in claiming
that the observed symptoms are indeed the result of the Dutch disease syndrome for these
symptoms may have occurred as a consequence of other factors such as the emerging role of
China in the world economy or unobservables that haven’t been controlled for.
3. Data and econometric methodology
As already indicated, the Dutch disease may occur through two interrelated channels, the
spending effect and the resource movement effect channels.11 As far as empirical identification of
these two effects is concerned, the literature has typically considered that evidence of the former
is provided by the occurrence of a real exchange rate appreciation while the latter reflects in a
contraction in the output growth of the manufacturing sector. Testing whether or not these two
effects have actually occurred in the Algerian economy by tracking the statistical evolution of
these variables in which these these effects are supposed to appear is the main objective of our
empirical analysis. We should however realize that while testing for these effects through the
9
Other economists such as Palley (2003) also provide some insightful policy recommendations to avoid the risks
associated with the high dependency on resource-based activities.
10
This point has been emphasized by Gylfason, (2001) and Robinson et al. (2002) among others.
11
It should be pointed out here that if the booming sector employs relatively few workers and labor mobility is low,
then the spending effect is expected to dominate the resource movement effect (Oomes and Kalcheva, 2007). This
seems a priori to be the case in Algeria since employment in the oil sector accounted, on average, for no more than
2% of the country's total employment over the decade 1980-1992 (ONS, 2012).
11
modeling of these outcome variables, it is important to take care of the quite subtle task of
controlling for other factors that could lead to similar outcomes.
The existence of a positive nexus between the real effective exchange rate and real oil
prices is known to be a necessary condition for the presence of the Dutch disease since it triggers
the process through which an increase in oil prices negatively affects local non-booming sectors.
Needless to say that the number and the nature of the economic fundamentals that have an effect
on the real effective exchange rate depends on the economic characteristics of a country, in
particular, its level of development.12 Naturally, how complete the equation to be specified for
modeling this variable also hinges on the extent to which appropriate data are available.
To perform tests of whether or not the Algerian economy has suffered from the
consequences of the Dutch disease as transmitted through the two channels discussed above, we
collected annual data from 1960 to 2013 on the real effective exchange rate of the Algerian dinar,
reer, real oil prices, rop, the productivity differential between Algeria and its major trading
partners, prod, government expenditure expressed as a percentage of the gross domestic product
(GDP), gex, net foreign assets, nfa, terms of trade, tot, manufacturing value added, manu,
inflation rate, inf, real GDP per capita, rgdp, and degree of openness, open. Table 1 below lists
these variables, each of which is a fifty-four observation-long time series, while the appendix
gives more detailed information on these variables and their data sources, and discuss the effect
of these variables that theory allows us to expect.
Table 1 - Variables and designation
Variable
Designation
reer
Real effective exchange rate
rop
Real oil prices
prod
Productivity differential
gex
Government expenditure
nfa
Net foreign assets
tot
Terms of trade
manu
Manufacturing value added
inf
Inflation rate
rgdp
Real GDP per capita
open
Degree of openness
12
The issue of the determinants of the real exchange rate has attracted much interest in applied macroeconomics.
For a recent empirical piece, see Kakkar and Yan (2014) and the references cited therein.
12
All the variables were transformed into their natural logarithm prior to performing our
econometric analysis in order to minimize the effect of the significant differences in their
magnitude and interpret the estimated coefficients as "elasticities" of the dependent variable with
respect to the corresponding independent variables. More importantly, this log-transformation has
been shown to alleviate the problem of heteroscedasticity (Maddala and Kim, 1998). Let us now
outline the econometric methods applied to these data.
We perform our empirical work in two stages. We first tackle the task of testing the effect
which is considered as the driving force of the Dutch disease, namely, the spending effect. To this
end, we focus on detecting the existence of a long term relationship between the real exchange
rate and real oil prices while controlling for other factors. We rely on unit root tests to determine
the order of integration of the appropriate time series and then apply cointegration and error
correction techniques within an Autoregressive-Distributed Lag (ARDL) framework. We then
investigate the existence of the resource movement effect in the Algerian data by means of a
regression model in which the dependent variable is our proxy for output of the manufacturing
sector and the independent variable of interest, next to some control variables, is the real
exchange rate. Cross-examining the results obtained in those two stages of the analysis will then
allow us to infer on whether the oil price fluctuations have had a long term negative impact of
manufacturing in Algeria, i.e., whether this country’s has indeed suffered from the symptoms of
the Dutch disease.
Valid temporal data analysis requires first checking what is considered in the econometric
literature as a crucial characteristic of time series, namely, their stationarity, and then
determining, if appropriate, their order of integration. The standard recommendation is to test out
the stochastic properties of the variables to be used in the estimation of econometric relationships
using a unit root test and a complementary stationarity test. Indeed, by testing both the unit root
hypothesis and the stationarity hypothesis, one can distinguish series that appear to be stationary,
series that appear to have a unit root, and series for which the data are not sufficiently informative
to conclude that they are stationary or integrated. When both types of tests are in agreement, then
we are in a position to come to a clear-cut conclusion. Hence, a battery of standard univariate unit
root tests was used in this study. More specifically, three tests were conducted, the Augmented
Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test, the Phillips-Perron (PP) test, and the Kwiatkowski, Phillips, Schmidt
and Shin (KPSS) test.
13
The unit root testing procedure is well established in the literature and will therefore not be
discussed here with great details. The ADF and PP tests are designed to test the null hypothesis of
a unit root against the alternative of no unit root. Unlike the ADF and PP tests, the KPSS test is a
test of stationarity with the null being that the series is stationary. A rejection of the null
hypothesis of stationarity in the KPSS test would then tend to corroborate a failure to reject the
null hypothesis of a unit root in the ADF and PP tests. Three different specifications of these tests
are available. The first excludes both the trend and the intercept. A second specification includes
the intercept but excludes the trend term. The third specification includes both the trend term and
the constant term. Following Harris et al. (2002), we use this third specification in our analysis.
The results of a unit root test indicate that the time series under consideration is either
integrated of order zero, I(0), i.e., stationary or of order one, I(1). Thus, it is necessary to apply an
appropriate econometric technique to tackle the problem of mixed order of integration of the data.
Various econometric techniques have been developed to investigate relationships among nonstationary macroeconomic variables. Prominent among them are the univariate cointegration
technique (Engle and Granger, 1987), the multivariate cointegration technique (Johansen, 1988,
Johansen and Juselius, 1990) and the newly developed ARDL approach (Pesaran and Smith,
1995, Pesaran et al., 1996, Pesaran et al., 2000, and Pesaran et al., 2001). We choose to estimate
and analyze the long-run relationships and dynamic interactions among our variables of interest
by using the bounds testing or ARDL cointegration procedure developed by Pesaran et al. (2001).
Recent studies indicate that the ARDL approach to cointegration is preferable to other
conventional cointegration approaches mainly because of the following four reasons.
First, the bounds test procedure is rather straightforward. In contrast to other multivariate
cointegration techniques such as Johansen and Juselius (1990), it allows the cointegration
relationship to be estimated by OLS once the lag order of the model has been identified. Second,
unlike other techniques, the bounds testing procedure does not require preliminary testing for
stationarity of the variables included in the model. It is applicable irrespective of whether the
regressors in the model are purely I(0), purely I(1), or mutually cointegrated. Third, the test is
relatively more efficient in small- or finite- samples as is the case in our study. The procedure
will however fail in the presence of I(2) series. Hence, although investigation of a cointegration
relationship using the ARDL approach does not necessitate testing for a unit root, as Ouattara
(2004) argues, the presence of I(2) variables in the relationship might render the F-statistic of
Pesaran et al. (2001) invalid. This is on account of the fact that the bound test is based on the
14
assumption of variables being I(0) or I(1). Therefore, the implementation of unit root tests within
the ARDL framework is still necessary in order to ensure that none of the variables is integrated
of order 2, I(2), or higher. Thus, we have performed different unit root tests to all of our variables.
Finally, this test identifies the variable to be normalized in the long-run relationship.13
The appendix provides a formal description of the bounds procedure. Applying this
procedure to our variables amounts to taking:
= ( ,
)=(
,
,
,
,
,
)
,
(1)
where
=
= (
is the I(1) dependent variable and
,
,
,
,
,
)
is the matrix of I(0) and I(1) regressors with a multivariate identically and independently
distributed zero mean error vector. This leads to the following vector equilibrium correction
model (VECM):
∆
=
+
+
+
Δ
+
Δ
+
Δ
+
+
+
+
Δ
+
+
+
Δ
Δ
+
,
= 1,2, … ,
(2)
The implementation of the ARDL bounds testing procedure involves three steps. A first
step is to estimate equation (2) using OLS and perform an F-test that allows to check the
13
A limitation of the bounds test, however, is that it is not appropriate in situations where there may be more than
one long-term relationship among the variables. This is the case for example when one variable is explained by the
remaining variables and a feedback from these variables exists.
15
predictive power of the lagged variables. More specifically, we examine the joint significance of
the coefficients of the lagged variables by formulating a test of the null hypothesis
H :
=
=
=
=
=
=0
(3)
against the alternative hypothesis
H :
≠ 0, or
≠ 0, or
≠ 0, or
≠ 0, or
≠ 0, or
≠0
(4)
that is, at least one of the lagged variables has some predictive power. The decision of the
cointegration
,
,
test
,
,
based
on
this
reer-normalized
F-statistic,
(
/
), is as follows. There are two asymptotic critical values of the bounds
that provide such a test when the independent variables are I(d) where 0 ≤ d ≤ 1: A lower value
assuming the regressors are I(0) and an upper value assuming purely I(1) regressors. If the Fstatistic is above the upper critical value, the null hypothesis of no long-run relationship can be
rejected irrespective of the orders of integration of the time series. If the F-statistic falls below the
lower critical value, the null hypothesis cannot be rejected. Finally, if the F- statistic falls
between the lower and upper critical values, the result is inconclusive.14
Once cointegration has been established, the second step of the ARDL bounds testing
procedure consists in estimating the conditional ARDL(p,q,r,s,l,k) long-run model of the
dependent variable as:
14
The approximate critical values for the F-statistic were obtained from Pesaran and Pesaran (1997).
16
∆
=
+
+
+
+
+
,
+
+
= 1,2, … ,
(5)
where all variables are as previously defined. As it is clear from equation (5), this formulation
involves selecting the orders of the ARDL(p,q,r,s,l,k) model in the six right-hand-side variables,
which we do using the Akaike information criteria (AIC).
In the third and final step, we obtain the short-run dynamic parameters by estimating an
error correction model associated with the long-run estimates. This model is specified as:
∆
=
+
Δ
+
+
Δ
Δ
+
Δ
+
Δ
+
+
+
,
Δ
= 1,2, … ,
(6)
where the
′ ,
′ ,
′ , ’s, ’s, and ’s are the short-run dynamic coefficients of the model
once it has converged to equilibrium and
is the error (or equilibrium) correction term
derived from the confirmed long-run equilibrium relationship and
is the coefficient associated
with this error correction term.15
To examine the existence of the resource movement effect in our dataset on Algeria, we
estimate the following regression with the variables transformed into their natural logarithms:
15
This series is obtained from the estimation of equation (5) as the values of the residuals lagged one time. It
measures the variables’ speed of convergence to their equilibrium level after a shock and it is expected to have a
significant negative value which usually ranges between -1 and 0.
17
ln(
)=
+
+
,
ln(
)+
ln(
)+
ln(
)+
ln(
)+
ln(
)
= 1,2, …
(7)
As already alluded to, one of the advantage of this log-log specification is that it allows for the
interpretation of each of the coefficients associated with the independent variables as the
elasticity of the dependent variable with respect to that independent variable. While numerical
values of these elasticities can be obtained by merely estimating equation (7) with Ordinary Least
Squares (OLS), one needs to check that some key assumptions are verified in the data for the
estimates to be reliable. Indeed, a violation of one or more of these assumptions may lead to
biased and inaccurate results. Given the dynamic nature of our data, we have investigated the
issues of multicollinearity and heteroscedasticity.
Multicollinearity is a common problem when estimating linear regression models. It occurs
when there are high correlations among independent variables, leading to unreliable and unstable
estimates of regression coefficients. A widely used diagnosis for multicollinearity is the variance
inflation factor (VIF).16 The VIF is computed for each predictor by running a linear regression of
that predictor, the k
say, on all the other explanatory variables and then obtaining the R-
squared, R , from that regression. The VIF for that k
predictor is then simply given by VIF =
1/(1 − R ). A VIF of 1, its lower bound, means that there is no correlation among the k
predictor and the remaining predictor variables, and hence the variance of the associated
coefficient,
in the standard regression analysis notation, is not inflated at all. The general rule
of thumb is that VIFs exceeding 4 warrant further investigations while VIFs exceeding 10 are
signs of serious multicollinearity requiring correction (Kutner et al., 2004).
The second problem that potentially plagues dynamic data such as ours is autocorrelation of
the error terms meaning that the error terms are not homoscedastic. Although, the OLS estimators
are still unbiased, this violation of the assumption of homoscedasticity has three important
consequences. First, statistical tests of the significance of the parameters and the confidence
intervals for the predicted values are not correct. Second, the estimates of the regression
coefficients are not efficient. Third, the OLS residuals are not independent which means that they
contain information that can be used to improve the prediction of the model. In other words, if
16
The term "inflation" here referes to the fact that the very consequence of multicollinearity is to increase (inflate)
the variance of the coefficients and hence to lessen their accuracy.
18
the model suffers from autocorrelation, it loses much of its predictive power. To detect the
presence of serial correlation in the residuals, the standard practice is to use the Durbin Watson
(DW) test. If the DW-statistic lies between 1.5 and 2.5, it indicates no autocorrelation. If it lies
below 1.5 or above 2.5, it indicates respectively positive and negative autocorrelation, in which
case "robust" rather than standard OLS residuals should be used in the inferences.
4. Empirical results
Stationarity tests
Before proceeding with the ARDL bounds test, unit root tests that inform on the stationarity
status of our time series are performed in order to determine the order of integration necessary to
make them covariance stationary. The purpose here is to ensure that the variables are not I(2),
i.e., that taking differences twice is necessary to make them stationary, which would cause
spurious results.17 The ADF and PP unit root tests discussed in the previous section are applied to
our time series in both their levels and their first differences. Table 2 below gives the results of
these tests. We see from this table that while the null hypothesis of the existence of a unit root
against the alternative hypothesis of stationarity is accepted for all the series in their levels, it is
systematically rejected for the series in their first differences. Therefore, we conclude that all
variables are I(1), i.e., integrated of order one.
To further explore the stationarity of our times series, we perform a KPSS test. The results
of this test, which are presented in Table 3 below, show that, in levels, the null hypothesis of the
series being stationary is rejected for reer, prod, and nfa and accepted for rop, tot, open, and gex.
We also see from this table that all the series are stationary in their first difference. On the basis
of these results, we can thus infer that the series reer, rop, prod, and nfa are integrated of order
one, i.e., I(1), while tot and gex are I(0). These mixed results from the analysis of unit root
properties of our time series further confirm the appropriateness of using an ARDL model to
investigate the existence of a cointegration statistical relationship among the variables.
17
See the discussion on this issue in the previous section and Ouattara (2004) for more details.
19
Variable
reer
rop
tot
prod
nfa
gex
reer
rop
tot
prod
nfa
gex
Table 2: ADF and PP unit root tests+
Series in levels
(ADF-statistic, Lag)
(PP-statistic, Lag)
(-2.201, 2)
(-2.002, 3)
(-1.584, 1)
(-1.723, 3)
(-2.153, 1)
(-2.221, 3)
(-1.600, 1)
(-2.201, 3)
(-0.587, 4)
(-0.679, 3)
(-0.887, 1)
(-1.029, 3)
Series in first differences
(-3.638*, 0)
(-3.819*, 3)
*
(-5.636 , 0)
(-7.725*, 3)
(-6.736*, 0)
(-6.732*, 3)
*
(-9.501 , 0)
(-9.355*, 3)
*
(-8.684 , 0)
(-9.641*, 3)
(-7.077*, 0)
(-7.081*, 3)
+
A "*" attached to a value of the ADF- or the PP-statistic indicates a rejection by the test of the null
hypothesis H 0 that the series is a unit root process, in which case it is not stationary, at the 5% statistical
significance level.
Variable
reer
rop
tot
prod
nfa
gex
reer
rop
tot
prod
nfa
gex
Table 3: KPSS unit root test+
Series in levels
(KPSS-statistic, Lag)
(0.223, 3)
(0.141*, 3)
(0.132*, 3)
(0.149, 3)
(0.311, 3)
(0.115*, 3)
Series in first differences
(0.097 *, 3)
(0.019 *, 3)
(0.067 *, 3)
(0.128 *, 3)
(0.109 *, 3)
(0.109 *, 3)
+
A "*" attached to a value of the KPSS-statistic indicates a no rejection, at the 5%
significance level, of the null hypothesis H 0 that the series is stationary against the
alternative hypothesis H1 that it is a unit root process.
The spending effect results
Now that we have made sure that our data are in the form of being exploited, we investigate
whether the Algerian economy has experienced the two effects that characterize the Dutch
disease, namely, the spending and resource movement effects. To explore the existence of the
20
spending effect in our data we undertake an ARDL cointegration analysis. Recall that the ARDL
procedure assumes that only one long run relationship exists between the dependent variable and
the exogenous variables (Pesaran et al., 2001).18 Accordingly, we estimate equation (2) to test for
the presence of a long run relationship between the variable reer and the variables rop, prod, tot,
nfa, and gex.
Constrained by the length of our data span, we use a general-to-specific modeling
approach and a model selection procedure based on the AIC criterion to set a maximum lag order
of 2 for the conditional ARDL-VECM.19 Then, the joint significance of the coefficients
associated with the retained lagged variables is tested by means of an F-test of null hypothesis
that these coefficients are all equal to zero meaning that no long-run relationship exists between
reer and the set of variables rop, prod, tot, nfa, and gex. The existence of such a cointegration
relationship is accepted if this F-test rejects the null. Table 4 below synthesizes the results that are
essential for reaching a decision.20 Besides showing the value of the reer-normalized F-statistic,
(
/
,
,
,
,
) = 1.52, it gives the critical values of the bounds for small
samples.21 This F-statistic falling below the lower critical bound for all three significance levels
typically considered (1%, 5%, and 10%), we conclude the variables reer and rop, prod, tot, nfa,
gex are not in a cointegrating long-run relationship, and hence that there is no empirical evidence
in our data that would support the occurrence of the spending effect in the Algerian economy
throughout the 1960-2013 period.
Table 4: Bounds test for cointegration
Significance level
Critical value
I(0)
I(1)
Lower bound
Upper bound
1%
3.41
4.68
5%
2.62
3.79
10%
2.26
3.35
F-statistic: 1.52
18
This point has been mentioned in the previous section. See footnote 14.
This lead to select an equation with an intercept and with no linear trend.
20
Detailed estimation resuts are available from the authors upon request.
21
These bounds are those that have been generated by Narayan (2004) for samples with size between 30 and 80.
21
19
Instead of contenting ourselves with this conclusion, we may ask the following question.
Is there anything structural about the Algerian economy that may have prevented the spending
effect from actually occurring? Algeria has implemented a managed float exchange rate policy
since 1995 with the objective of maintaining a stable real exchange rate against a basket of
currencies of this country’s main trading partners and competitors. As depicted in Figure 1
below, the real exchange rate of the Algerian dinar has persistently depreciated since then by
about a yearly average of 0.81%.
The stated objective of this monetary strategy is threefold. First, it provides the Algerian
government with a tool for adjusting the nominal exchange rate in order to offset any
accumulated price increases. Second, such adjustments could also be a means of reducing
imports and hence encouraging domestic production. Third, and most importantly for our
purposes, it should allow Algerian policy makers to protect the domestic tradable non-mining
sector from the damaging effects of any mining sector boom-triggered appreciation of the
domestic currency.22 This could explain, indeed, to some large extent, the fact that oil price
increases did not result in an appreciation of the real exchange rate of the Algerian dinar, and thus
spared Algeria's economy from the supposedly expected symptom of the spending effect.
Figure 1: The reel effective exchange rate of the Algerian dinar (1960-2013)
22
One should point out though that, for the specific case of Algeria, the domestic tradable non-mining sector is not
really exposed to international competition.
22
The resource movement effect results
Prior to investigating whether or not the resource movement effect has occurred in Algeria, it is
useful to take a glance at the data. Table 5 below gives some descriptive summary statistics of the
time series used in the analysis of such an effect. More specifically, this table reports the mean,
the standard deviation, the minimum, and the maximum of each variable of equation (7) in
addition to the variable mining, which represents the value added of the mining sector as a
percentage of GDP. We see that, over the 1960-2013 period, the average contribution of the
manufacturing sector to GDP is 8.32% and has varied between a minimum of 3.74% and a
maximum of 13.57% with a standard deviation of 2.64.
Unsurprisingly, the mining sector contribution to GDP is practically three times as large
as that of the manufacturing sector with a mean of 37.07% and a standard variation from this
mean of 8.94 from a minimum of 17.39% and a maximum of 53.01%.23 The average inflation
rate is about 8.67% with a standard deviation of 7.63, indicating that the country has experienced
high inflation levels that reached a maximum of 31.68%. The degree of openness of the Algerian
economy is also quite high with a ratio of imports plus exports to GDP averaging 0.55,
essentially reflecting the high level of both imports and oil exports, and hence the strong
dependency of this economy from the rest of the world.
Variable
manu (%)
reer (index)
rop ($2014)
inf (%)
open (%)
rgdp ($2005)
mining (%)
Table 5: Summary statistics
Mean
St. Dev.
Min
8.32
226.30
48.47
8.57
0.55
2469.36
37.07
2.64
111.68
31.62
7.63
0.11
461.50
8.94
Max
3.74
13.57
100
10.97
443.67
117.09
1.34
0.33
1513.22
17.39
31.68
0.77
3243.99
53.01
In order to assess whether or not the resource movement effect occurred in Algeria over the
period under study (1960-2013), i.e., whether there exists a causal (negative) relationship
between the share of manufacturing value added in GDP and oil price variations in our data, we
23
With an average value of GDP per capita fo $2469.36 ($2005), Algeria falls in the The World Bank category of
middle-income countries.
23
estimate equation (7) with OLS.24 The estimation results are presented in Table 6 below.
Although quite simplistic, the regression performed well, explaining over 83% of the variation in
the dependent variable. The robustness checks indicate that the regression does not suffer from
heteroscedasticity, multicollinearity, and autocorrelation problems. There is no problem of
multicollinearity since the value of the VIF for each of the independent variable is less than 10. In
addition, there is no problem of autocorrelation since the value of DW lies between 1.5 and 2.5.
Finally, since the data were log-transformed any heteroscedasticity problem has been attenuated.
Therefore, accurate inferences can be derived from this model.
Table 6: The resource movement effect - OLS regression results+
Independent
Coefficient Standard- t-statistic
p-value VIF
variables
error
ln_reer
0.46
0.05
9.11*
0.000
1.52
ln_rop
-0.32
0.07
-4.38 *
0.000
3.64
*
ln_inf
0.15
0.03
5.75
0.000
1.10
ln_rgdp
0.66
0.25
1.61
0.712
3.44
ln_open
-0.03
0.13
-0.26
0.797
1.54
*
Constant
-4.66
1.88
-2.48
0.017
F(5, 44): 44.23
R-squared: 0.83
Adjusted R-squared: 0.82
DW-statistic: 2.24
+
We indicate with a "*" statistical significance at a 5 % level.
Quite surprisingly, there seems to be a positive relationship between the real effective
exchange rate and manufacturing sector contribution to GDP which is inconsistent with the
Dutch disease theory. The coefficient for the real exchange rate variable is statistically significant
and according to the estimation results, a 1% increase in the real effective exchange rate leads to
an increase of 0.45% in the manufacturing sector value added in GDP, ceteris paribus. One
possible explanation of this finding, as pointed out by Shakeri (2009), is that the Dutch disease
effect is very responsive to the country's manufacturing sector structure. The result is very likely
to vary depending on whether or not the industries including in the sample are exposed to foreign
24
A preliminary indication of this relationship can be obtained from the correlation coefficients between the
dependent variable and the various independent variables of equation (7) that are shown in Table A.1 of the
appendix. These measures of the sign and strength of the (linear) relationship between these variables are quite
informative indeed. We see that the correlation coefficients between the dependent variable, i.e., the share of
manufacturing value added in GDP and each of the five independent variables included in equation (7) are no less
than 40% showing that these variables are indeed good potential candidates as predictors of the dependent variable as
will be confirmed by the performance diagnosis of our regression.
24
competition. The industries that cater for the home market as a result of trade protection or that
possess monopolistic price-setting power may benefit from the rise in domestic demand as a
result of oil boom. This ambiguous finding certainly calls for a further investigation with a more
disaggregated data in order to draw a clear-cut conclusion about the effect of the real effective
exchange rate on the growth of the manufacturing sector.
The negative sign of the estimated coefficient associated with the real oil prices variable is
statistically significant and indicates that as oil prices increase, there is a contraction in the share
of the manufacturing sector contribution to GDP. More specifically, all things equal, a 1%
increase in real oil prices leads to a 0.32% decrease in manufacturing sector value added in GDP.
At first glance, this finding may appear to be in contradiction with the previous results obtained
from the spending effect estimation. Nevertheless, it proves that Algeria has experienced what
might be thought of as a "partial" manifestation of the Dutch disease because a
deindustrialization did in fact happen, although it did not stem from an appreciation of the
country's real exchange rate as the theory suggests.
This finding becomes even more interesting when one views it as providing a piece of
evidence that oil revenues deriving from real prices hikes were squandered away without any
lasting or significant improvements in the country's manufacturing sector.25 That being said, a
certain degree of caution has to be taken when interpreting this result because the series used to
conduct this empirical analysis are annual. Indeed, the long period of time over which oil prices
are observed can be subject to a multitude of fluctuations, and therefore the cause of the
deindustrialization can also be attributed to many other factors.
The coefficient associated with the inflation variable is statistically significant and has the
expected sign. It says that, all things equal, a 1% increase in inflation leads to a 0.14% increase in
the manufacturing sector contribution in GDP. This result may seem to be in contradiction with
the fact that Algeria's manufacturing sector actually experience persistent decline despite high
inflation rates recorded over the 1960-2013 period. However, it corroborates the theoretical
prediction that stipulates that higher inflation levels should lead to a rise in the price of tradable
goods, and hence, to a subsequent expansion of the manufacturing sector. It should be stressed
25
The question of why and how this has happened requires a deeper analysis of the political economy of the
Algerian society which is beyond our current study.
25
out here that the response of an oil exporting country to inflation pressures that spring from an oil
boom depends on the exchange rate regime.26
Although the coefficient associated with real GDP per capita, a variable that is supposed to
control for the Algeria's level of overall economic development, is not statistically significant at a
5% level, it displays the correct sign.27 This finding shows that, ceteris paribus, increases in real
GDP per capita have no measurable effect on the manufacturing sector, ceteris paribus. One
possible explanation could be that despite increases in real GDP per capita in Algeria, their levels
were not high enough to show in industrial development. Theory demonstrates how crucial the
role of the manufacturing sector in enhancing growth levels and building strong foundations to
ensure a rapid and successful catching up process for developing countries is. In other words, as a
country's real GDP per capita augments, this wealth increase is expected to show in some sort of
industrial development, which obviously does not seem to be the case, in any significant way, for
Algeria.
The coefficient attached to the degree of openness is not significant and has the wrong sign.
Indeed, one would expect a positive sign because an increase in the degree of openness of an
economy is supposedly associated with a higher capacity of exports (McKinnon, 1963) and in the
Dutch disease paradigm, only the manufacturing sector has the ability to export as non-tradable
goods are subject to domestic consumption (Corden and Neary, 1982). Hence, a rise in exports is
an indicator of an expansion of the tradable sector relative to the non-tradable sector. This result
makes perfect sense considering the structure of Algeria’s international trade, which is dominated
to a large extent by oil exports.28 In fact, this provides further evidence that a rise of the degree of
openness in Algeria is essentially due to the increasing volumes of the mining sector exports
rather than an expansion of the manufacturing sector exports.
5. Summary and conclusions
Algeria heavily relies on oil exports revenues to fuel its economy and since the 1986 oil countershock the performance of its manufacturing sector has been disappointingly poor. Moreover,
even though at some times during the last couple of decades oil prices have been relatively high
26
For instance, a recent study by Allegret and Benkhodja (2011) for the 1990–2010 period in Algeria concludes
that, in order to stabilize output and inflation, monetary policy should focus on a core inflation target.
27
Note that this coefficient is close to being statistical significant at a level between 10 and 20%.
28
For a recent study of the impact of Algeria’s international trade stucture on this country’s oil real purchasing
power, see Gasmi and Laourari (2005).
26
and the government has conducted a myriad of economic reforms, Algeria has failed to develop
its manufacturing sector and diversify its economy.
One of the main mechanisms through which fluctuations in a natural resource prices can
constitute an impediment to the development of the manufacturing sector, and hence to long-term
growth, in an economy that heavily relies on this resource exports is referred to in the literature as
the Dutch disease. This paper has sought to test whether or not Algeria’s economy has suffered
from the main symptoms of the Dutch disease by analyzing data covering more than half-acentury.
More specifically, we use annual data from 1960 to 2013 and investigate the existence of
two distinct yet interrelated channels through which the Dutch disease may occur, namely, what
referred to in the literature as the "spending effect" and the "resource movement effect."
According to the former, following an oil boom the real exchange rate of the domestic currency
should appreciate while the latter merely says that the manufacturing sector should shrink. We
test for these signs of the Dutch disease using a set of regressions while accounting, through
control variables, for other factors that could have led to similar economic symptoms.
How does this phenomenon actually work? Following an oil boom, a substantial part of the
revenue windfall is spent on non-tradable goods leading an appreciation of the real exchange rate.
Resources are then driven away from the manufacturing sector (the tradable sector), to the extent
that this sector is exposed to international competition, into the services sector (non-tradable
sector). Furthermore, the higher profitability of the oil sector raises the prices of factors of
production, which further causes a contraction of the manufacturing sector. Given that this sector
represents an important source of technological spillovers, its decline, also known as
deindustrialization, is very likely to induce a permanent decrease of growth rates in the economy.
Our empirical strategy consisted in testing two important channels through which the Dutch
disease could affect the Algerian economy, the spending effect and the resource movement effect.
To investigate the existence of the former effect, we searched for empirical evidence of a robust
long-run relationship between real oil prices and real effective exchange rate of the Algerian
dinar. Using an ARDL approach and controlling for a set of relevant variables, we found no
empirical evidence of the existence of a cointegration relationship between these variables. This
led us to conclude that the data do not provide any support for the spending effect.
27
Did this empirical rejection of the spending effect channel of the Dutch disease mean that
the disease itself should have been rejected? In view of the importance of the matter from a
policy standpoint, we decided to investigate the resource movement channel as well. To this end,
we estimated a regression with growth of the manufacturing sector as the dependent variable and
real exchange rate and real oil prices as independent variables next to some control variables that
we thought were pertinent for the analysis. The results did not allow us to reach an unambiguous
conclusion. Indeed, while the real effective exchange rate was found to have a positive impact on
manufacturing, real oil prices had a negative impact on this sector.
While we are tempted to end the investigation conducted in this paper by merely arguing
that the diagnosis of the Dutch disease for the Algerian economy cannot be confirmed, we choose
to give a couple of directions for further research that would likely throw more light on the
subject. A first and rather technical issue that obviously needs to be tackled is simultaneity. In
addition to carefully testing and accounting for endogeneity of the right-hand-side variables
included in the two separate regressions that we used to model the spending and the resource
movement effects, intuition as well as theory warrants the use of a simultaneous-equation
framework to model these two interrelated effects. A second avenue of research is to attempt to
understand the Algerian economy’s deindustrialization puzzle by analyzing it in a more
systematic way. The Dutch disease is a possible explanation, but it is far from being the only one.
Political economy as well as international trade considerations are among promising lines of
thought.
28
Appendix
Variables used to test the spending effect and theoretical predictions
Real effective exchange rate (reer): This variable is defined as a measure of the trade-weighted
average exchange rate of a currency against a basket of currencies after adjusting for inflation
differentials with regard to the countries concerned and expressed as an index number relative to
a base year. This paper uses the real effective exchange rate of the Algerian Dinar against a
basket of 41 trade partners' currencies adjusted for inflation using consumer price index series
with a base year 2007=100 . It is treated as a dependent variable and, provided the spending effect
exists in the data, is expected to have a long run positive relationship with real oil prices. Data on
this variable were extracted from the Darvas (2014) online database.
Real oil prices (rop): This variable represents nominal oil price deflated by the US consumer
price index (with 2014 as a base year). The data were obtained from the BP Statistical Workbook
2015. As to the effect of oil price booms on the real effective exchange rate, it is expected to be
positive in the long run. In other words, it is expected that the real exchange rate appreciate
following oil price increases.
Productivity differential (prod): Following Habib and Kalamova (2007), we proxy the
productivity differential with a variable defined as the trade weighted relative productivity
differential of Algeria against its trading partners' productivity where the productivity is taken to
be PPP GDP per capita, i.e., GDP per capita based on purchasing power parity (PPP). This proxy
is used to capture the so-called Balassa-Samuelson effect (Balassa, 1964) according to which
countries with higher productivity growth in the tradable sector experience higher relative prices
of non-tradables, and hence an exchange rate appreciation without a loss of competitiveness.
Thus, it is expected that an increase in this variable leads to an appreciation of the real effective
exchange rate. This prod series is computed using data from The IMF, The World Bank, and UN
Comtrade databases.
Net foreign assets (nfa): This variable corresponds to the ratio of total net foreign assets to GDP.
It is meant to capture the impact of the foreign reserves on the real effective exchange rate. Note
29
that it also provides an idea of the extent of government intervention in the capital of the
economy. The series for this variable was computed using data obtained from The Office National
des Statistiques (ONS), The National Currency and Credit, Rétrospective 1960-2011, and The
IMF.
Terms of trade (tot): This variable represents the % value of Algeria’s exports relative to that of
its imports. If it is less than 1, there is obviously more capital going out (to buy imports) than
there is coming in while if it is greater than 1 it means that the country is accumulating capital,
i.e., more money is coming in from exports. Note that this variable also informs on any changes
in the international economic environment, in particular, in the foreign prices a country face. The
sign of its relationship with the real effective exchange rate depends on the relative weights of the
income and substitution effects and hence cannot unambiguously be predicted without ambiguity.
The series are computed using data from The World Bank’s Africa Development Indicators 2013
dataset.
Government expenditure (gex): This variable represents government expenditure as a ratio of
GDP and is meant to capture the effect of fiscal policy on various aspects of an economy. No real
consensus exists in the literature as to the impact of government spending on the real effective
exchange rate. Indeed, it depends on where extra funds are channeled toward tradable or nontradable goods and exchange rate tends to appreciate if non-tradables are receiving more and
depreciate if tradables receive the extra funds (Dibooglu, 1996, Iossifov and Loukoianova, 2007).
Nevertheless, the literature tends to privilege the negative effect of government spending on the
real exchange rate as, unlike the private sector; the government tends to spend more resources on
non-tradable sectors than on tradable (Baffes et al., 1999; Mongardini, 1998). The series are
computed using data recovered from The IMF and The World Bank databases.
Variables used to test the resource movement effect and theoretical predictions
Manufacturing value added (manu): This variable aggregates the value added of the industries
belonging to the International Standard Industrial Classification (ISIC) codes 15 through 37. The
value added corresponds to the net output of a sector after adding up the value of all outputs and
subtracting those of all the intermediate inputs. The origin of value added is determined by the
ISIC revision 3. This variable is used as a proxy for the level of development of Algeria’s
30
manufacturing sector, hence for its level of industrialization. It is the dependent variable of
equation (7) in the text. The figures for this variable have been collected from The World Bank
databases.
Inflation rate (inf): This variable corresponds to the annual growth rate of the GDP implicit
deflator, which is the ratio of GDP in current local currency to GDP in constant local currency.
Recall that the resource movement effect highlights the shift in production from manufacturing to
services following increases of non-tradable goods prices (Corden and Neary, 1982). This
variable is used in our regression to control for the general increase in price levels. The inflation
rate is intended to capture the net short run impact on profitability resulted from changes in the
cost of imported inputs associated to exchange rate movements together with the ability of firms
to pass these costs on in the form of higher prices. The increase in the relative inflation rate
should increase the profitability of each industry and therefore the expected sign of the
coefficient associated with this variable should be positive. This series was downloaded from The
World Bank databases.
Real GDP per capita (rgdp): This variable is the gross domestic product divided by midyear
population and expressed in constant US dollars. It is included in our regression to control for the
changes in Algeria’s level of economic development. This is a control variable that has been
commonly used in empirical studies seeking to test the resource movement effect (Jones, 1965).
A per capita rather than a total measure is used in order to control for the relative size per
economy. As the country develops and devotes more attention to the manufacturing sector, per
capita GDP should increase. As such, this variable also controls for the industrialization process,
and thus, is expected to have a positive effect on manufacturing. The series for this variable was
obtained from The IMF and The World Bank databases and The ONS.
Real effective exchange rate (reer): This is the same variable used to investigate the spending
effect. According to the Dutch disease theory, the sign of the coefficient attached to this variable
in our regression (equation (7)) is negative since an appreciation of the real exchange rate is
expected to harm the manufacturing competitiveness.
Real oil prices (rop): This is the same variable used to investigate the spending effect. The sign
of the coefficient associated with this variable in our regression is negative since an increase in
31
oil prices should to lead to an appreciation of the real exchange rate and thus to a manufacturing
output contraction.
Degree of openness (open): This variable is defined as the ratio of the sum of imports and
exports of goods and services to GDP. This indicator measures the country’s openness or
integration in the world economy. It represents the combined weight of total trade in its economy,
a measure of the degree of dependence of domestic producers on foreign markets and their trade
orientation (for exports), and the degree of reliance of domestic demand on foreign supply of
goods and services (for imports). It is included in the regression to capture the effect of Algeria’s
international commerce policy. This criterion of openness has been used in the literature to reflect
the degree of integration of a country within an optimum currency area (Hyden, 1990). It has
been since applied in multiple empirical papers to capture the degree to which an economy is
exposed to trade (Kang et al., 2013). In the classical Dutch Disease setting, this variable can have
a significant effect on the manufacturing sector because an increase in this index means that the
manufacturing sector exports more. One should then expect a positive sign of the coefficient
attached to this variable in the regression. The series is computed with data recovered from The
World Bank’s Africa Development Indicators 2013.
The bounds test procedure
Following Pesaran et al. (2001), as summarized in Choong et al. (2005), we applied the bounds
testing procedure by specifying a general vector autoregressive (VAR) model of order
( + 1)-variate random process
=
in the
:
+ . +
∅
+
, = 1,2, … ,
(A.1)
where
,
, and the ∅’s are ( + 1)-dimensional vectors of respectively intercept, trend, and
lagged-variable-associated unknown coefficients. Pesaran et al. (2001) derive the following
vector equilibrium correction model (VECM):
32
∆
=
+ . + ∏.
+
Γ.Δ
+
, = 1,2, … ,
(A.2)
where Δ is the first difference operator and the square ( + 1) × ( + 1) matrices ∏ =
∑
Ψ and Γ = − ∑
Ψ,
= 1,2, … , − 1,
+
being the ( + 1)-dimensional unit
matrix, contain the long-run multipliers and short-run dynamic coefficients of the VECM.
= ( ,
In our analysis, we take
=
where
)=(
is the I(1) dependent variable and
,
,
,
,
,
,
)
= (
,
,
,
,
,
)
is the matrix of I(0) and I(1) regressors with a multivariate identically and independently
distributed zero mean error vector. Assuming that a unique long-run relationship exists among
the variables, the conditional VECM given in equation (A.2) above rewrites as:
∆
=
+ . +
+
Δ
+
Δ
+
, = 1,2, … ,
(A.3)
Coefficient correlations between the dependent variable manu and the independent
variables reer, rop, inf, open, and rgdp of equation (7) in the text.
Table A1: Correlation coefficients
Variable x
Corr(manu, x)
reer
rop
inf
open
rgdp
0.73
-0.45
0.42
-0.47
-0.47
33
References
Allegret, J.P. and M.T. Benkhodja, 2011, "External shocks and monetary policy in a small open
oil exporting economy," EconomiX Working Paper 2011-39, University of Paris-Ouest
Nanterre la Défense.
Baffes, J., I. Elbadawi, and S. O'Connell, 1999. "Single-Equation Estimation of the Equilibrium
Real Exchange Rate," World Bank, Policy Research Department 1800, Washington, DC.
Balassa, B., 1964, "The purchasing power parity doctrine: A reappraisal," Journal of Political
Economy, 72: 584-596.
Barry, F. and J. Bradley, 1997, "FDI and trade: The Irish host-country experience," The
Economic Journal, 107: 1798-1811.
Benjamin, N.C., Devarajan, S., and R.J. Weiner, 1989, "The Dutch disease in a developing
country: Oil reserves in Cameroon," Journal of Development Economics, 30: 71-99.
Benjamin, N.C., S. Devarajan, and R.J. Weiner, 1986, "Oil revenues and the Dutch disease in a
developing country: Cameroon," OPEC Review, 10: 143-162.
Bjornland, H.C., 1998, "The economic effects of North Sea oil on the manufacturing sector,"
Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 45(5): 553-584.
Bruno, M. and J. Sachs., 1982, "Energy and resource allocation: A dynamic model of the Dutch
Disease," Review of Economic Studies, 49(5): 845-59.
Choong, C.K., Zulkornain Y., and K.S. Venus Liew, 2005, "Export-led growth hypothesis in
Malaysia: an investigation using bounds test," Sunway Academic Journal, 2: 13-22.
Corden, W. M. and J.P. Neary, 1982, "Booming sector and de-industrialization in a small open
economy," Economic Journal, 92: 825-48.
Corden, W., 1984, "Booming sector and Dutch disease economics: survey and consolidation,"
Oxford Economic Papers, 36: 359-380.
Corden, W., 2012, "Dutch disease in Australia: Policy options for a three-speed economy,"
Australian Economic Review, 45(3): 290-304.
Darvas, Z., 2014, "Real effective exchange rate for 178 countries: A new database," Bruegel
Working Paper 06.
Dibooglu, S., 1996, "Real disturbances, relative prices and purchasing power parity," Journal of
Macroeconomics, 18(1): 69-87.
34
Elbadawi, I., A. and S. Raimundo, 1997, "Real Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Adjustment
in Sub-Saharan Africa and Other Developing Countries," Journal of African Economies,
6(3): 74-120.
Engle, R.F. and C.W.J. Granger 1987, "Cointegration and error-correction: Representation,
estimation, and testing," Econometrica, 55(2): 251-76.
Fardmanesh, M., 1991, "Terms of trade shocks and structural adjustment in a small economy
Dutch disease and oil price increases," Journal of Development Economics, 34: 339-353.
Gasmi, F. and I. Laourari, 2015, "The dynamics of the real purchasing power of Algeria’s oil
revenues: 1970-2013," Les cahiers du cread, Forthcoming.
Gylfason, T., 2001, "Natural resources and economic growth: What is the connection?," CESIFO
Working Paper 530, Info Institute for Economic Research, Munich.
Habib, M.M., and M.M. Kalamova, 2007, "Are there oil currencies? The real exchange rate of oil
exporting countries," ECB Working Paper 839.
Harris, D., B. McCabe, and S. Leybourne, 2002, "Stochastic cointegration: Estimation and
inference," Journal of Econometrics, 111(2): 363-384.
Hartwick, J. and K. Hamilton, 2009, "Oil stock discovery and Dutch disease," Working Paper
1220, Department of Economics, Queen's University.
Hyden, G., 1990. "The changing context of institutional development in Sub-Saharan Africa,"
World Bank Long Term Perspective Study of Sub-Saharan Africa Background Papers, 3:
43-59.
Iossifov, P. and E. Loukoianova, 2007. "Estimation of a Behavioral Equilibrium Exchange Rate
Model for Ghana," IMF Working Paper 07/155, Washington, DC.
Ismail, K., 2010, "The structural manifestation of the Dutch disease: the case of oil exporting
countries," IMF Working Paper No. 10/103.
Jbira, R. and S. Zouari-Ghorbela, 2011, "Oil Price and Dutch disease: the case of Algeria,"
Energy Sources, Part B: Economics, Planning, and Policy, 6(3): 280-293.
Johansen, S. and K. Juselius, 1990, "Maximum likelihood estimation and inference on
cointegration with application to the demand for money," Oxford Bulletin of Economics
and Statistics, 52: 169-210.
Johansen, S., 1988, "Statistical Analysis of Cointegrating Vectors," Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control, 12: 231-254.
Jones, R.W., 1965. "The Structure of Simple General Equilibrium Models," Journal of Political
Economy, 73: 557-572.
35
Kakkar, V. and I. Yan, 2014, "Detreminants of real exchange rate: An empirical investigation,"
Bank of Finland Institute for Economies in Transition Discussion Papers 1/2014.
Kang, J. S., Prati, A., and A. Rebucci, 2013. "Aid, Exports, and Growth: A Time-Series
Perspective on the Dutch Disease Hypothesis," IMF Working Paper 13/73, Washington,
DC.
Kojo, N.C., 2014, "Demystifying Dutch Disease," World Bank Policy Research Working Paper
6981, Washington, DC.
Krugman, P., 1987, "The Narrow Moving Band, the Dutch Disease, and the Competitive
Consequences of Mrs. Thatcher: Notes on Trade in the Presence of Dynamic Scale
Economies," Journal of Development Economics, 37: 41-55.
Kutner, M.H., Nachtsheim, C.J., and J. Neter, 2004, Applied Linear Regression Models (4th ed.),
McGraw-Hill Irwin.
Larsen, E.R., 2005, "Are rich countries immune to the resource curse? Evidence from Norway’s
management of its oil riches," Resources Policy, 30: 75-86.
Lartey, E.K., 2008, "Capital inflows, resource reallocation and the real exchange rate,"
International Finance, 11: 131-152.
Maddala, G.S. and I.M. Kim, 1998, Unit Roots, Cointegration, and Structural Change. Themes in
Modern Econometrics, Cambridge University Press.
McKinnon, R.I., 1963, "Optimum currency areas," American Economic Review, 53: 717-725.
Mironov, V. V. and A.V. Petronevich, 2015, "Discovering the signs of Dutch disease in Russia,"
Bank of Finland Institute for Economies in Transition Discussion Papers 3/2015.
Mongardini, J., 1998. "Estimating Egypt`s Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate," IMF Working
Paper 98/5, Washington, DC.
Narayan, P.K., 2004, "Fiji’s tourism demand: the ARDL approach to cointegration", Tourism
Economics, 10(2): 193-206.
Oomes, N. and K. Kalcheva, 2007, "Diagnosing Dutch Disease: Does Russia Have the
Symptoms?" Bank of Finland, BOFIT Institute for Economies in Transition Discussion
Paper No. 7.
Ouattara, B., 2004, "Foreign Aid and Fiscal Policy in Senegal," Mimeo, University of
Manchester.
Office National des Statistiques (ONS), 2012, Rétrospective 1962-2011, Algiers.
Palley, T., 2003, "Lifting the natural resource curse," Foreign Service Journal, 80: 54-61.
36
Pesaran M. H., Shin, Y., and R.J. Smith, 2001, "Bounds Testing Approaches to the Analysis of Level
Relationships," Journal of Applied Econometrics, 16: 289-326.
Pesaran, H.M., Shin, Y. and R.J. Smith, 2000, "Structural analysis of vector error correction
models with exogenous I(1) variable," Journal of Econometrics, 97: 293-343.
Pesaran, M. H., and B. Pesaran, 1997, Microfit 4.0 (Window Version). New York: Oxford
University Press.
Pesaran, M. H., Y. Shin, and R.J. Smith, 1996, "Bounds testing approaches to the analysis of
level relationships," DEA Working Paper 9622, Department of Applied Economics,
University of Cambridge.
Pesaran, M.H. and R. Smith, 1995, "Estimating long-run relationships from dynamic
heterogeneous panels," Journal of Econometrics, 68: 79-113.
Robinson J.A., Torvik R., and T. Verdier, 2002, "Political foundations of the resource curse,"
CEPR DP Series n° 3422, London Centre for Economic Policy Research.
Sachs, J.D. and A.M. Warner, 2001, "The curse of natural resources," European Economic
Review 45: 827-838.
Shakeri, M., 2009, Essays on Dutch disease and exchange rate pass-through: Evidence from
Canadian manufacturing industries, PhD Thesis, Department of Bioresource Policy,
Business, and Economics, University of Saskatchewan, Canada.
Wijnbergen, S., 1984, "The Dutch disease: A disease after all?," Economic Journal, 94(373): 4155.
37