Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Managerial Economics, SS14 Second Homework Solution (1) Bundling Kebap price Coke price P e10 e5 e7 e0 e2 e2.5 e10 e7 e9.5 e3 e1 e4 A B C MC Optimal separate prices1 Kebaps: • PK = 10 → πK (10) = 10 · (10 − 3) = 70 • PK = 7 → πK (7) = 20 · (7 − 3) = 80 • PK = 5 → πK (5) = 30 · (5 − 3) = 60 Cokes: • PC = 2.5 → πC (2.5) = 10 · (2.5 − 1) = 15 • PC = 2 → πC (2) = 20 · (2 − 1) = 20 • PC = 0 → πC (0) = 30 · (0 − 1) = −30 max =⇒ πK = 80 =⇒ πCmax = 20 Given the WTP’s of the three costumer segments, the highest possible profit selling Kebaps and max Cokes separately is e100 (= πK + πCmax ). Optimal pure bundle prices • PK,C = 10 → 10 · (10 − 4) = 60 • PK,C = 9.5 → 20 · (9.5 − 4) = 110 • PK,C = 7 → 30 · (7 − 4) = 90 max =⇒ πK,C = 110 The optimal pure bundle price is e110. (2) Price leadership a) The total supply curve for the follower firms is obtained by horizontally aggregating their marginal cost curves. First we rewrite the M C curves as follows: M C(qi ) = 20 + 5qi = P 5qi = −20 + P 1 qi = −4 + P 5 The total supply curve is thus 5 X 1 Qf = qi = 5 · −4 + P 5 i=1 = −20 + P b) The dominant firm’s residual demand curve is given by the difference between the market demand curve and the total supply curve of the follower firms: Qd = 400 − 2P − (−20 + P ) = 420 − 3P 1 Note that potential profits are calculated by multiplying the profit margin P −M C by the number of costumers who are willing to buy the product at the respective price (i.e. whose willingness-to-pay exceeds the price). 1 Managerial Economics, SS14 Second Homework Solution c) The dominant firm will set marginal revenue equal to marginal cost. First we have to rewrite the dominant firm’s demand curve as P = 140− 31 Q, marginal revenue is thus M R = 140− 32 Q. Hence, 2 140 − Q = 20, 3 Q∗d = 180, Pd∗ = 140 − 1 · 180 = 80 3 d) Each follower firm will charge the same price as the dominant firm, Pf = Pd = 80. The total output produced by the follower firms is Qf (80) = −20 + 80 = 60. Since they are identical, each firm will therefore produce 12 (= 60/5) units of output. (3) Oligopoly I a) Firm a faces the following maximization problem: πa = T Ra − T Ca = 300qa − 3qa2 − 3qa qb − (30qa + 1.5qa2 ) max q (1) a The first-order condition for qa yields firm a’s reaction function: ∂πa = 270 − 9qa − 3qb = 0 ∂qa 1 qa (qb ) = 30 − qb 3 (2) By symmetry, the reaction function of firm b is 1 qb (qa ) = 30 − qa 3 (3) b) If firm a produces 9 units, firm b will produce qb (9) = 30 − 13 · 9 = 27 units. c) Solving the reaction functions simultaneously by substituting (2) into (3) yields qb = 30 − 1 1 1 30 − qb = 20 + qb 3 3 9 ∗ qb = 22.5 qa∗ = 22.5 Since qa = qb , the profit function in (1) can be rewritten as πi = 270qi − 7.5qi2 ∀i ∈ {a, b} Thus, each firm’s profit is πi = 270 · 22.5 − 7.5 · 22.52 = $2,278.13. d) If firms decide to collude, they maximize joint (monopoly) profits. Because both firms are identical, each produces Q/2 units. The cartel’s profit function therefore reads Π(Q) = P (Q)Q − 2C Q 2 2 " Q = 300Q − 3Q − 2 30 2 = 270Q − 3.75Q 2 + 1.5 Q 2 # 2 (4) 2 Managerial Economics, SS14 Second Homework Solution Thus, the first-order condition for joint profit-maximization is ∂Π(Q) = 270 − 7.5Q = 0 ∂Q QC = 36 Substituting QC = 36 into the profit-function given by (4) yields a joint-profit of $4,860, of which half is earned by the single firms (πaC = πbC = $2,430). Each firm can therefore improve its profit by $151.87 through colluding. e) If firms engage in price competition, each price above marginal cost will be underbid by the rival. Profits and quantity produced will be lower, whereas the price will be higher compared to the Cournot-Nash equilibrium. Using the demand and cost functions given in this example, the Bertrand equilibrium is found where qaB = qbB = 30 and P B = 120. The profit of each firm is πiB = 1,350. (4) Oligopoly II P = 10 − qx − qy ACx = 5 ACy = 2qy −→ −→ T Cx = ACx qx = 5qx T Cy = ACy qy = 2qy2 −→ −→ M Cx = ∆ACx /∆qx = 5 M Cy = ∆ACy /∆qy = 4qy Under Bertrand competition, the market equilibrium is found where price equals marginal cost, because every price above will be underbid by the rival: P = M Cx 10 − qx − qy = 5 qx = 5 − q y P = M Cy 10 − qx − qy = 4qy qy = 2 − 0.2qx (5) (6) Solving the system of reaction functions by plugging (5) into (6) yields qy = 2 − 0.2 · (5 − qy ) qy = 1.25 =⇒ qx = 5 − 1.25 = 3.75 The price will end up at P = 10 − 1.25 − 3.75 = $5. The firms’ profits are therefore πy = P qy − T Cy = 5 · 1.25 − 2 · 1.252 πy = $3.125 πx = P qx − T Cx = 5 · 3.75 − 5 · 3.75 πx = $0 If firm y was able to push its rival out of the market entirely, e.g. through rent-seeking activities such as bribery, it would serve the market as a monopolist. The monopoly equilibrium is found where M R = M C, resulting in a quantity of QM = 35 and a price of P M = 25 . Firm y’s profit 3 would then be (coincidentally) π M 2 25 5 5 = · −2· 3 3 3 = 25 3 Compared to the Bertrand equilibrium, profits could be improved by approximately $5.21. 3 Managerial Economics, SS14 Second Homework Solution (5) Game theory I a) A dominant strategy is a strategy that earns a player a larger pay-off than any other strategy, regardless of the strategies played by other players. In this example, neither player has a dominant strategy. b) A Nash equilibrium is a situation where no player has an incentive to unilaterally change his strategy. In this example, there are two Nash equilibria; one where firm A enters but firm B doesn’t – {10,0} –, and one where firm B enters but firm A doesn’t – {0,5}. c) It is not obvious at first sight what the outcome of this game will be. However, we see that firm A has higher potential pay-offs from entering than firm B, so the equilibrium is most likely {10,0} . (6) Game theory II Suppose each decision node is a day of the week. On the third day (the decision node on the right), firm K decides between abiding (a) and cheating (c). K will choose c, because it yields a higher pay-off compared to a (3 > 2). On day 2, firm L therefore expects a pay-off of 3 if it abides (α) by the agreement, because it anticipates firm K to cheat the day after. Hence, firm L will cheat also on day 2, since 4 > 3. On day 1, firm K’s pay-off is 0 when it expects firm L to cheat on day 2, thus it will choose to cheat on day 1 as well (1 > 0). The outcome of this game is therefore that firm K will already cheat on day 1 if it knows that it will cheat sometime in the future – the cartel will therefore break down. Two crucial assumptions have been made here: (1) players act rationally, and (2) both players correctly anticipate all actions of the other player. 4