* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download total cost function
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Chapter 10 Cost Functions Explicit Costs and Implicit Costs Explicit Costs – Costs that involve a direct monetary outlay. Implicit Costs – Costs that do not involve outlays of cash. 2 Opportunity Cost The relevant concept of cost is opportunity cost: the value of a resource in its best alternative use. The only alternative we consider is the best alternative 3 Economic Costs and Accounting Costs Economic Costs – Sum of a firm’s explicit costs and implicit Costs. Accounting Costs – Total of a firm’s explicit costs. 4 Economic Cost • The economic cost of any input is the payment required to keep that input in its present employment – the remuneration the input would receive in its best alternative employment • Sunk Cost – Expenditure that has been made and cannot be recovered – Because a sunk cost cannot be recovered, it should not influence the firm’s decisions. – E.g: Consider the purchase of specialized equipment for a plant. – Suppose the equipment can be used to do only what it was originally designed for and cannot be converted for alternative use. – The expenditure on this equipment is a sunk cost. – Because it has no alternative use, its opportunity cost is zero. Two Simplifying Assumptions • Inputs are hired in perfectly competitive markets – firms are price takers in input markets • There are only two inputs – homogeneous labor (l), measured in laborhours – homogeneous capital (k), measured in machine-hours Economic Profits • Total costs for the firm are given by Total costs = C = wl + vk • Total revenue for the firm is given by Total revenue = pq = pf(k,l) • Economic profits () are equal to = Total revenue - Total cost = pq - wl - vk = pf(k,l) - wl - vk Economic Profits • Economic profits are a function of the amount of k and l employed – We could examine how a firm would choose k and l to maximize profit – We will assume that the firm has already chosen its output level (q0) and wants to minimize its costs Cost-Minimizing Input Choices • We seek to minimize total costs given q = f(k,l) = q0 • Setting up the Lagrangian: ℒ = wl + vk + [q0 - f(k,l)] • FOCs are ℒ /l = w - (f/l) = 0 ℒ /k = v - (f/k) = 0 ℒ / = q0 - f(k,l) = 0 Cost-Minimizing Input Choices • Dividing the first two conditions we get w f / l MRTS (l for k ) v f / k • The cost-minimizing firm should equate the MRTS for the two inputs to the ratio of their prices Solution to cost minimization: • Slope of isoquant = slope of isocost line MRTS L , K w (or) r MPL w MPK r • Ratio of marginal products = ratio of input prices MPL MPK w r 11 • At point E MPL w MPK v MPL MPK (or ) w v • This implies the firm could spend an additional dollar on labor and save more than a dollar by reducing its employment of capital and keep output constant 12 • At point F MPL w MPK v MPL MPK (or ) w v • This implies the firm could spend an additional dollar on capital and save more than a dollar by reducing its employment of labor and keep output constant 13 Cost-Minimizing Input Choices • The inverse of this equation is also of interest w v MPl MPk • The Lagrangian multiplier shows how the extra costs that would be incurred by increasing the output constraint slightly Cost-Minimizing Input Choices Given output q0, we wish to find the least costly point on the isoquant k per period C1 C3 Costs are represented by parallel lines with a slope of w/v C2 C1 < C2 < C3 q0 l per period Cost-Minimizing Input Choices The minimum cost of producing q0 is C2 k per period This occurs at the tangency between the isoquant and the total cost curve C1 C3 C2 k* q0 l* The optimal choice is l*, k* l per period Interior Solution Suppose: Q = 50L1/2K1/2 Suppose that the wage rate of the laborer is given as $5, the rental price is given as $20 and the firm produces an output of 1000. What is the cost minimizing level of output? 17 Corner Solution The cost-minimizing input combination for producing Q0 units of output occurs at point A where the firms uses no capital. At this corner point the isocost line is flatter than the isoquant. MPL w ( ) ( ) MPK r MPL MPK w r 18 Contingent Demand for Inputs • In Chapter 4, we considered an individual’s expenditure-minimization problem – to develop the compensated demand for a good • Can we develop a firm’s demand for an input in the same way? Cost-Minimizing Input Choices The minimum cost of producing q0 is C2 k per period This occurs at the tangency between the isoquant and the total cost curve C1 C3 C2 k* q0 l* The optimal choice is l*, k* l per period Contingent Demand for Inputs • In the present case, cost minimization leads to a demand for capital and labor that is contingent on the level of output being produced • The demand for an input is a derived demand – it is based on the level of the firm’s output Some Key Definitions An increase in Q0 moves the isoquant Northeast. • Expansion Path: A line that connects the cost-minimizing input combinations as the quantity of output, Q, varies, holding input prices constant. • Normal Inputs: An input whose cost-minimizing quantity increases as the firm produces more output. • Inferior Input: An input whose cost-minimizing quantity decreases as the firm produces more output. 22 The Firm’s Expansion Path • The firm can determine the cost-minimizing combinations of k and l for every level of output • If input costs remain constant for all amounts of k and l, we can trace the locus of costminimizing choices – called the firm’s expansion path An Expansion Path As output increases, the cost minimization path moves from point A to B to C when inputs are normal 24 The Firm’s Expansion Path The expansion path is the locus of cost-minimizing tangencies k per period The curve shows how inputs increase as output increases E q1 q0 q00 l per period The Firm’s Expansion Path • The expansion path does not have to be a straight line – the use of some inputs may increase faster than others as output expands • depends on the shape of the isoquants • The expansion path does not have to be upward sloping – if the use of an input falls as output expands, that input is an inferior input An Expansion Path As output increases, the cost minimization path moves from point A to B to C when labor is an inferior input 27 Cost Minimization • Suppose that the production function is Cobb-Douglas: q = kl • The Lagrangian expression for cost minimization of producing q0 is ℒ = vk + wl + (q0 - k l ) Cost Minimization • The FOCs for a minimum are ℒ /k = v - k -1l = 0 ℒ /l = w - k l -1 = 0 ℒ/ = q0 - k l = 0 Cost Minimization • Dividing the first equation by the second gives us w k l 1 k 1 v k l l • The MRTS depends only on the ratio of the two inputs • The expansion path is a straight line Total Cost Function • The total cost function shows that for any set of input costs and for any output level, the minimum cost incurred by the firm is C = C(v,w,q) • As output (q) increases, total costs increases Average Cost Function • The average cost function (AC) is found by computing total costs per unit of output C(v ,w , q ) average cost AC (v ,w , q ) q Marginal Cost Function • The marginal cost function (MC) is found by computing the change in total costs for a change in output produced C(v ,w , q ) marginal cost MC(v ,w , q ) q Graphical Analysis of Total Costs Total costs With constant returns to scale, total costs are proportional to output AC = MC C Both AC and MC will be constant Output Graphical Analysis of Total Costs • Suppose that k1 units of capital and l1 units of labor input are required to produce one unit of output C(q=1) = vk1 + wl1 • To produce m units of output (assuming constant returns to scale) C(q=m) = vmk1 + wml1 = m(vk1 + wl1) C(q=m) = m C(q=1) Graphical Analysis of Total Costs • Suppose that total costs start out as concave and then becomes convex as output increases – one possible explanation for this is that there is a third factor of production that is fixed as capital and labor usage expands – total costs begin rising rapidly after diminishing returns set in Graphical Analysis of Total Costs Total costs C Total costs rise dramatically as output increases after diminishing returns set in Output Graphical Analysis of Total Costs Average and marginal costs MC is the slope of the C curve MC AC min AC If AC > MC, AC must be falling If AC < MC, AC must be rising Output Shifts in Cost Curves • Cost curves are drawn under the assumption that input prices and the level of technology are held constant – any change in these factors will cause the cost curves to shift Some Illustrative Cost Functions • 1) Suppose we have a fixed proportions technology such that q = f(k,l) = min(ak,bl) • Production will occur at the vertex of the Lshaped isoquants (q = ak = bl) C(w,v,q) = vk + wl = v(q/a) + w(q/b) v w C(w ,v , q ) a a b Some Illustrative Cost Functions • 2) Suppose we have a Cobb-Douglas technology such that q = f(k,l) = k l • Cost minimization requires that w k v l w k l v Some Illustrative Cost Functions • Suppose we have a CES technology such that q = f(k,l) = (k + l )/ • To derive the total cost, we would use the same method and eventually get C(v ,w , q ) vk wl q 1/ (v / 1 w / 1 )( 1) / C(v ,w , q ) q 1/ (v 1 w 1 )1/ 1 Properties of Cost functions • 1) Homogeneity • 2) Total cost functions are nondecreasing in q, v, and w. • 3) Total cost functions are concave in input prices. Properties of Cost Functions • Homogeneity – cost functions are all homogeneous of degree one in the input prices • a doubling of all input prices will not change the levels of inputs purchased Properties of Cost Functions • Nondecreasing in q, v, and w – cost functions are derived from a costminimization process • any decline in costs from an increase in one of the function’s arguments would lead to a contradiction Properties of Cost Functions • Concave in input prices – costs will be lower when a firm faces input prices that fluctuate around a given level than when they remain constant at that level • the firm can adapt its input mix to take advantage of such fluctuations Concavity of Cost Function At w1, the firm’s costs are C(v,w1,q1) Costs If the firm continues to buy the same input mix as w changes, its cost function would be Cpseudo Cpseudo C(v,w,q1) C(v,w1,q1) Since the firm’s input mix will likely change, actual costs will be less than Cpseudo such as C(v,w,q1) w1 w Properties of Cost Functions • Some of these properties carry over to average and marginal costs – homogeneity – effects of v, w, and q are ambiguous Input Substitution • A change in the price of an input will cause the firm to alter its input mix • The change in k/l in response to a change in w/v, while holding q constant is k l w v Input Substitution • Putting this in proportional terms as ( k / l ) w / v ln(k / l ) s (w / v ) k / l ln(w / v ) gives an alternative definition of the elasticity of substitution – in the two-input case, s must be nonnegative – large values of s indicate that firms change their input mix significantly if input prices change Partial Elasticity of Substitution • The partial elasticity of substitution between two inputs (xi and xj) with prices wi and wj is given by ( x i / x j ) w j / w i ln( x i / x j ) sij (w j / w i ) x i / x j ln(w j / w i ) • Sij is a more flexible concept than – it allows the firm to alter the usage of inputs other than xi and xj when input prices change Size of Shifts in Costs Curves • The increase in costs will be largely influenced by – the relative significance of the input in the production process – the ability of firms to substitute another input for the one that has risen in price Technical Progress • Improvements in technology also lower cost curves • Suppose that total costs (with constant returns to scale) are C0 = C0(q,v,w) = qC0(v,w,1) Technical Progress • Because the same inputs that produced one unit of output in period zero will produce A(t) units in period t Ct(v,w,A(t)) = A(t)Ct(v,w,1)= C0(v,w,1) • Total costs are given by Ct(v,w,q) = qCt(v,w,1) = qC0(v,w,1)/A(t) = C0(v,w,q)/A(t) Shifting the Cobb-Douglas Cost Function • The Cobb-Douglas cost function is C(v ,w , q ) vk wl q 1/ Bv / w / where B ( ) / / • If we assume = = 0.5, the total cost curve is greatly simplified: C(v ,w , q ) vk wl 2qv 0.5w 0.5 Shifting the Cobb-Douglas Cost Function • If v = 3 and w = 12, the relationship is C(3,12, q ) 2q 36 12q – C = 480 to produce q =40 – AC = C/q = 12 – MC = C/q = 12 Shifting the Cobb-Douglas Cost Function • If v = 3 and w = 27, the relationship is C(3,27, q ) 2q 81 18q – C = 720 to produce q =40 – AC = C/q = 18 – MC = C/q = 18 Shifting the Cobb-Douglas Cost Function • Suppose the production function is q A( t )k 0 .5 0 .5 l e 0.03t k 0 .5 0 .5 l – we are assuming that technical change takes an exponential form and the rate of technical change is 3 percent per year Shifting the Cobb-Douglas Cost Function • The cost function is then 0.5 0.5 0.03t C 0( v ,w ,q ) C(t v ,w ,q ) 2qv w e A( t ) – if input prices remain the same, costs fall at the rate of technical improvement Contingent demand for inputs 60 Contingent Demand for Inputs • Contingent demand functions for all of the firms inputs can be derived from the cost function –Shephard’s lemma • the contingent demand function for any input is given by the partial derivative of the total-cost function with respect to that input’s price Contingent Demand for Inputs • Shepherd’s lemma is one result of the envelope theorem – the change in the optimal value in a constrained optimization problem with respect to one of the parameters can be found by differentiating the Lagrangian with respect to the changing parameter Contingent Demand for Inputs • Suppose we have a fixed proportions technology • The cost function is v w C(w ,v , q ) a a b Contingent Demand for Inputs • For this cost function, contingent demand functions are quite simple: C(v ,w , q ) q k (v ,w , q ) v a c C(v ,w , q ) q l (v ,w , q ) w b c Contingent Demand for Inputs • Suppose we have a Cobb-Douglas technology • The cost function is C(v,w, q ) vk wl q 1 / Bv / w / Contingent Demand for Inputs • For this cost function, the derivation is messier: C 1/ / / k (v ,w , q ) q Bv w v c 1/ w q B v / Contingent Demand for Inputs C l (v ,w , q ) q 1/ Bv / w / w c 1/ w q B v / • The contingent demands for inputs depend on both inputs’ prices Contingent Demand for Inputs • Suppose we have a CES technology • The cost function is C( v ,w ,q ) q 1/ v 1 w 1 /( 1 ) Contingent Demand for Inputs • The contingent demand function for capital is 1/ 1 1 C 1 k ( v ,w ,q ) q v w v 1 1/ 1 1 /( 1 ) q v w v c /( 1 ) ( 1 )v Contingent Demand for Inputs • The contingent demand function for labor is 1/ 1 1 C 1 l ( v ,w ,q ) q v w w 1 1/ 1 1 /( 1 ) q v w w c /( 1 ) ( 1 )w Short-Run, Long-Run Distinction • In the short run, economic actors have only limited flexibility in their actions • Assume that the capital input is held constant at k1 and the firm is free to vary only its labor input • The production function becomes q = f(k1,l) Short-Run Total Costs • Short-run total cost for the firm is SC = vk1 + wl • There are two types of short-run costs: – short-run fixed costs are costs associated with fixed inputs (vk1) – short-run variable costs are costs associated with variable inputs (wl) Short-Run Total Costs • Short-run costs are not minimal costs for producing the various output levels – the firm does not have the flexibility of input choice – to vary its output in the short run, the firm must use nonoptimal input combinations – the MRTS will not be equal to the ratio of input prices Nonoptimality of Short-Run Total Costs k per period Because capital is fixed at k1, the firm cannot equate MRTS with the ratio of input prices k1 q2 q1 q0 l per period l1 l2 l3 • Long run-all variables are variable and the expansion path is from A –B–C • Short run-some variables are fixed (capital)-the expansion path is from D –B –E 75 • Short run: One input is fixed, capital K . Firm can vary the other input, labor. SO demand for labor will be independent of price of K • Short run demand for labor will also depend on quantity produced. • As quantity increased, labor used increases holding capital fixed. 76 Short-Run Marginal and Average Costs • The short-run average total cost (SAC) function is SAC = total costs/total output = SC/q • The short-run marginal cost (SMC) function is SMC = change in SC/change in output = SC/q Long and Short Run Total Cost Functions Total Cost ($/yr) STC(Q,K0) TC(Q) The long-run C curve can be derived by varying the level of k K0 is the LR cost-minimising quantity of K for Q0 0 Q0 Q1 Q (units/yr) 78 Long and Short Run Total Cost Functions STC(Q,K0) Total Cost ($/yr) TC(Q) TC0 The long-run C curve can be derived by varying the level of k A • K0 is the LR cost-minimising quantity of K for Q0 0 Q0 Q1 Q (units/yr) 79 Long and Short Run Total Cost Functions STC(Q,K0) Total Cost ($/yr) TC(Q) •C TC1 TC0 A • The long-run C curve can be derived by varying the level of k K0 is the LR cost-minimising quantity of K for Q0 0 Q0 Q1 Q (units/yr) 80 Long and Short Run Total Cost Functions STC(Q,K0) Total Cost ($/yr) • •C TC2 B TC1 TC0 A • TC(Q) The long-run C curve can be derived by varying the level of k K0 is the LR cost-minimising quantity of K for Q0 0 Q0 Q1 Q (units/yr) 81 Short-Run and Long-Run Costs Costs SMC (k0) SAC (k0) MC AC SMC (k1) q0 q1 SAC (k1) The geometric relationship between shortrun and long-run AC and MC can also be shown Output Short-Run and Long-Run Costs • At the minimum point of the AC curve: – the MC curve crosses the AC curve • MC = AC at this point – the SAC curve is tangent to the LAC curve • SAC (for this level of k) is minimized at the same level of output as AC • SMC intersects SAC also at this point AC = MC = SAC = SMC Returns to Scale & Economies of Scale • 1) When the production function exhibits increasing returns to scale, the long run average cost function exhibits economies of scale so that AC(Q) decreases with Q, all else equal. •2) When the production function exhibits decreasing returns to scale, the long run average cost function exhibits diseconomies of scale so that AC(Q) increases with Q, all else equal. • When the production function exhibits constant returns to scale, the long run average cost function is flat: it neither increases nor decreases with output. 84 LONG-RUN COST WITH ECONOMIES AND DISECONOMIES OF SCALE The long-run average cost curve LAC is the envelope of the shortrun average cost curves SAC1, SAC2, and SAC3. With economies and diseconomies of scale, the minimum points of the short-run average cost curves do not lie on the long-run average cost curve. Economies of Scope If a firm produces multiple goods, the cost of one good may depend on the output level of the other. • Outputs are linked if a single input is used to produce both. •There are economies of scope if it is cheaper to produce goods jointly than separately. Economies of Scope – a production characteristic in which the total cost of producing given quantities of two goods in the same firm is less than the total cost of producing those quantities in two singleproduct firms. 86 Economies of Experience Economies of Experience – cost advantages that result from accumulated experience, or, learning-by-doing. Experience Curve (or Learning Curve)– a relationship between average variable cost and cumulative production volume – typical relationship is AVC(N) = ANB, where N – cumulative production volume, A > 0 – constant representing AVC of first unit produced, -1 < B < 0 – experience elasticity (% change in AVC for every 1% increase in cumulative volume – slope of the experience curve tells us how much AVC goes down (as a % of initial level), when 87 cumulative output doubles Graphing the Learning Curve A firm’s production cost may fall over time as managers and workers become more experienced and more effective at using the available plant and equipment. The learning curve shows the extent to which hours of labor needed per unit of output fall as the cumulative output increases. ECONOMIES OF SCALE VERSUS LEARNING Economies of Scale: A firm’s average cost of production can decline over time because of growth of sales when increasing returns are present (a move from A to B on curve AC1), Learning Curve: A firm’s average cost of production can decline because there is a learning curve (a move from A on curve AC1 to C on curve AC2).