* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Origins and Measurement of Financial Repression: The
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Origins and Measurement of Financial Repression: The British Case in the mid-20th Century Garrick Hileman Cambridge Centre for Alternative Finance Financial History Workshop, Brussels, 27 May 2016 OriginsandMeasurementofFinancialRepression:TheBritishCasein themid-20thCentury GarrickHileman Abstract: A disagreement has emerged over whether advanced countries such as BritainengagedinfinancialrepressionfollowingtheSecondWorldWar.Areviewof the historical and archival evidence shows that policies associated with financial repression played an important role in sustaining post-war Britain's record-setting levels of public debt. In Britain, eleven pieces of legislation and sixteen polices/directivesareidentifiedthatsupportedfinancialrepressionduringthisperiod. A critique of two leading methods for measuring financial repression highlights the need for additional measurement tools, such as a proposed composite indicator of financialrepression.ThepaperdiscussesvariousaspectsofBritishfinancialrepression, suchasinterestratepolicy,capitalcontrols,directedlending,andtheconscriptionof theBritishbankingsystem.FreemarketbondyielddataareusedtocalculateBritish government savings attributable to financial repression of over 8% of GDP in 1948, whichismorethandoublepreviousestimatesforBritainandsignificantlygreaterthan estimatesfordevelopingcountriesduringthe1970s-80s. JEL:H63,E58,E61,E62,H12,H27,P24 Keywords:financialrepression,capitalcontrols,sovereigndebt,debtsustainability,inflation, Britisheconomichistory,Britishbankingsystem,interestrates,financialregulation, macroprudentialregulation 1Introduction Financialrepressionhasreceivedrenewedacademicandpublicattentioninrecent yearsaspartoftheongoingeconomicandpolicydebateoverhowbesttoachieveeconomic growthwhilesustainingpublicdebts.Therenewedinterestinfinancialrepressionhasbeen promptedinpartbythehighestlevelsofpublicandprivatesectordebtsinadvanced economiessincetheSecondWorldWar,theperiodwhichsomescholarsarguewasthelast timeadvancedcountriespracticedfinancialrepressiononawidescale. Untilrecentlyproblemsposedbyunsustainablelevelsofsovereigndebtwerenearly exclusivetodevelopingeconomies.Accordingly,emergingmarketshavebeenthefocusof sovereigndebtresearchandpolicymakersoverthelastfourdecades.However,debt sustainabilitymeasuresthataretypicallyemployedbydevelopingcountries,suchas repudiationandinflation,areviewedasimpractical,undesirable,orevenimpossibleformany advancedeconomiestoimplement.Atthesametime,outstandingdebtsanddeficitsarelarge enoughthatothertraditionalmechanismsforachievingfiscalbalance,suchasreductionsin governmentexpendituresorassetsales,areviewedbymanyasinsufficienttomakeamaterial impactonsovereigndebtsustainability.Ifadvancedeconomiesareultimatelyunableto achievesufficienteconomicgrowthtomaketheirdebtssustainablethenfinancialrepression maybethemostcompellingpolicyoption. AdisagreementemergedbetweenReinhartandSbrancia(2011)andTaylor(2011)over theevidenceofwidespreadfinancialrepressioninthepost-SecondWorldWarperiod.1The disagreementisexploredinmoredepthlaterinthepaperbutcanbesummarizedasfollows: ReinhartandSbranciastatethatthedeclineintherealvalueofpublicdebtisprimafacie evidenceoffinancialrepression,whileTaylorcounteredthatthetruereasonswhyrealyields ongovernmentdebtmayturnnegativearenotalwaysclear. 1 (C.M.Reinhart&Sbrancia,2011;Taylor,2011) Thispapermakesthreecontributions:first,existingmethodsformeasuringtheeffects offinancialrepressionarecritiqued,revealinganumberofmethodologicalissuesand limitationsthatcanbeaddressedinpartthroughaproposedcompositeindicator(composite index)offinancialrepression.Second,thedisagreementovertheexistenceoffinancial repressioninpost-SecondWorldWarperiodisexploredbyexaminingtheBritishcasein-depth, andawiderangeoffinancialrepressionpoliciesemployedbyBritainareidentified.Last,an alternativemeasureofBritishfinancialrepressionispresentedusingfreemarketbondyield data;Britishfinancialrepression‘savings’arecalculatedatover8%ofGDPin1948,whichis significantlygreaterthansavingsestimatesforothercountriesduringthepost-SecondWorld Warperiod. Theremainderofthepaperisstructuredasfollows:section2coversthedefinitionand historyoffinancialrepression.Section3comparestwoleadingmethodsformeasuringfinancial repression.Section4exploresthecaseofBritishpost-SecondWarfinancialrepression.Section 5concludes. 2Literaturesurvey Beforeanystudycanbeundertakenitisusefultohaveaprecisedefinitionofthetopic tobestudied.However,arrivingatbothaclearandgenerallyagreedupondefinitionofthe termfinancialrepressionisproblematic;awiderangeofpoliciesandpracticescanbe,and oftenare,placedunderitsbanner.Thetermfinancialrepressionisfrequentlyemployedasa pejorativetocriticizeparticularpolicies,evokingstrongreactionsinacademicandpolicy discussions.Addingfurthertroubleistheinterchangeableusebysomescholarsoftermslike fiscalrepressionwithfinancialrepression,sometimesinthesamepaper.2Overlapcanalsobe foundbetweenpoliciesassociatedwithfinancialrepressionandthepoliciesthatfallunderthe moreagreeablytermedmacroprudentialregulation.3Forexample,increasedreserve requirementsandholdingmore‘safe’governmentdebtinlieuofothercapitalisconsidered bothprudentorthodoxyforachievingfinancialstabilityaswellasacorecomponentoffinancial repression. Financialrepressioncanbedefinedasanymeasuretakenbycentralauthoritiesthat directslendablefundstowardsthesovereign’spubliclyissueddebt,oftenonattractiveterms (belowmarket).Inotherwords,intheabsenceoffinancialrepressionthegovernmentwould havetopayahigherrateofinteresttoenticelenders;otherwisethegovernmentwouldrisk losingsignificantinvestorfundstootherfreemarketinvestmentsthatgeneratehigherratesof return.Hereweseeoneofthedifficultiesinidentifyingfinancialrepression,whichisthe relianceonthecounterfactualthateconomicactorswouldbehavedifferentlyifcertainpolicies werenotinplace. Thecorepolicyelementsoffinancialrepressioncanperhapsbebestgroupedintotwo categories4–capitalcontrolsanddomesticfinancialregulation: 2 (Drelichman&Voth,2008) Forfurtherdiscussionsee(C.Reinhart,Kirkegaard,&Sbrancia,2011) 4 Frameworkadaptedfrom(C.M.Reinhart&Sbrancia,2011,p.6) 3 1. Captivedomesticcreditproviders,whichtypicallyincludethebankingsystem,pension funds,insurancecompaniesandotherinstitutions(e.g.,governmentagencies).Such entitiescanbeownedordirectlyoperatedbythegovernmentunderaregimeof financialrepression.Alternatively,firmscanalsoberegulatedornudgedthroughmoral suasion.Publicdebtfinancingfromtheseentitiesisoftendirectedbythegovernment viathefollowingmechanisms: a. Reserverequirementsthatgovernboththepercentageandtypeofcapital(e.g., governmentdebt)andmustberetainedbythebankingsysteminreserve againstdeposits. b. Exchangeandcapitalcontrolsthatrestrictbothinstitutionsandindividualsto domesticsavingsandinvestmentvehicles,therebypreventingthemfromtaking advantageofpotentiallymoreattractiveoffshorereturns. c. Preferentialtaxtreatmentforgovernmentdebtoverothercompetingfinancial instruments,suchasequities.5 d. Restrictionsonholdingcertainassets(i.e.,foreigncurrency,gold),including prohibitingtheownershipofgold,orlimitationsonthesaleortransferofgold withinorbeyondthedomesticmarket. 2. Interestratecapsintheformofrateceilings,orotherindirectmeasuresthathelp maintainlowinterestrates.Lowratescanbothreducegovernmentdebtexpenseand influencethedemandforgovernmentdebt.Forexample,savingsdepositsthatare regulatedtopayalowerrateofinterestthangovernmentdebtwillincentivizethe migrationofcapitalintogovernmentdebt. Theabovedefinitionoffinancialrepressionisbynomeanscomprehensive.Indeed,a myriadofmeasuresareoftensuggestedasaformfinancialrepression.Forexample, governmentrestrictionsontheactionsofcreditratingsagencieshasbeencharacterizedas financialrepression.6Insum,whilethebroadconceptoffinancialrepressionisgenerallywell 5 6 Formoreonthisspecificareasee(Campbell&Froot,1994) (Evans-Pritchard,7July,2011) established,thereisroomfordebateoverpreciselywhichpoliciesoractionsshouldandshould notbeconsideredfinancialrepression. 2.1Historicaloverviewoffinancialrepression Tomoreclearlydefineandunderstandfinancialrepressionitishelpfultoexamineits origins.Somepoliciesassociatedwithwhatcametobecalledfinancialrepressioninthelatterhalfofthe20thcenturyhaveexistedlongbeforethetermwasinvented.Restrictionsoninterest andusurydatebacktoatleast1800B.C.andtheBabylonianCodeofHammurabi.7Lending withinterest,orinterestratesconsideredusurious,haveoftenbeenframedinmoraland religioustermsandarechastisedinboththeKoranandOldTestament.Forexample,Jews,like Christians,wereingeneralnotsupposedtolendmoneyatusuriousratesofinterest,butthe OldTestamentbookofDeuteronomycontaineda‘get-outclause’forJewslendingtogentiles.8 Morerecentlyasystemofcompulsorygovernmentfinancecalledprestitiwasin operationin14thand15thcenturyVeniceandFlorence.9Restrictionsonthefreemovementof capital,suchastheexportofspecie,areseenasearlyas16thcenturySpainandtheNapoleonic period.10However,exchangecontrols,astheyarecommonlyunderstoodandpracticedtoday, arguablyfirstcameintowiderexistenceduringtheFirstWorldWarwhenGermanyintroduced exchangeregulationsshortlyafterhostilitiescommenced.11On3April,1918Francefollowed suitandenactedexchangecontrolstolimitcapitalflight.Britain,undertheguidanceofathen youngemployeeoftheExchequernamedJohnMaynardKeynes,practicedalighterversionof capitalcontrols,whichincludedlicensingimportsandplacingrestrictionsonthewayinwhich warloanscouldbespent.12Later,inhis1936GeneralTheory,Keynesexpressedhimselftobeat leastasometimeproponentofinterestratecaps,stating: 7 (Lane,1937) (Ferguson,2008,pp.35-36)‘Untoastrangerthoumayestlenduponusury;butuntothybrotherthoushaltnot lenduponusury’ 9 (Blitz&Long,1965) 10 (Cooper,Tarullo,&Williamson,1999,pp.6-7) 11 (Dulles,1929,p.223;Moulton&Mcguire,1923,p.166) 12 (R.F.Harrod,1951,pp.204-205) 8 “…therateofinterestisnotself-adjustingatalevelbestsuitedtothesocialadvantage butconstantlytendstorisetoohigh,sothatawisegovernmentisconcernedtocurbit bystatueandcustomandevenbyinvokingthesanctionsofmorallaw.”13 Whilecapsoninterestcanpreventmonopolistoroligopolisticlendersfromabusingtheir pricingpower,capsalsobringdownthecostofborrowingforgovernment. GurleyandShaw(1955,1960)werethefirsttoarticulatethebroadereconomicsystem offinancialrepression.14In1973ShawandMcKinnonsimultaneouslycoinedtheterm‘financial repression’intheirrespectivebooksontheroleofthefinancialsectorineconomic development.15McKinnonandShawfocusedontwochannelsfortransmittingfinancial repression:first,thereductionintheefficiencyofthebankingsectorinallocatingsavings, meaningbankersoperatinginafinanciallyrepressedenvironmentareunabletomanagecredit accordingtomarketratesandprices.Second,maintainingartificiallylowinterestratesreduces thesavingslevel,whichinturncanreducecapitalaccumulation.16 Thetermfinancialrepressionbecamesomewhatofacatch-alldescriptionforexcessive financialregulationindevelopingeconomiesbypromotersofthe‘Washingtonconsensus’, whichwasasetofpoliciesassociatedwiththepushformarketliberalizationinthe1970s1980s.McKinnon,Shawandsubsequentscholarsfocusedtheirresearchontheeconomic developmentbarrierscreatedbyfinancialrepressionforlessdevelopedeconomies. 13 (Keynes,1936,p.351) (J.G.Gurley&Shaw,1955;JohnG.Gurley,Shaw,Enthoven,&BrookingsInstitution.,1960) 15 (McKinnon,1973;Shaw,1973) 16 (Shaw,1973,Ch.2and3) 14 2.2Economicimpactoffinancialrepression SinceGurleyandShaw'sgroundbreakingworkinthemid-1950s,anumberofresearch studieshavefoundthatfinancialrepressionhasanegativeimpactoneconomicgrowth.17A morespecificcriticismoffinancialrepressionisthenegativeimpactithasonthemarginal productivityofcapital;controlssuppressinginterestratesbelowtheirequilibriumlevelcause projectswithotherwisepositivereturnsoninvestmenttogounfinanced.18Financial developmentislikelytosufferundersuchconditionsasthelowreturnonfinancialassets reducestheincentiveforsavingstobeallocatedtothefinancialsystemforintermediation.19 Theresultingdragoncapitalaccumulationundercutsentrepreneurshipandeconomic development. Capitalmobility,whichisrestrictedbyfinancialrepression,helpschannelresourcesto theirmostproductiveusesbothlocallyandworldwide.CapieandWood(2002)studiedthe effectsofBritishcapitalcontrolsandfoundthattheyresultin‘deadweightlosses’,meaning higherprices,reducedproduction,andincreasedbureaucraticandadministrativecosts.20 Capitalcontrolscanalsobedifficulttoabandononcetheyareinplace,andtheycannegatively impactacountry’sattractivenessasadestinationforforeigncapitalbyreducingthe‘free market’credibilityofthenationsthatimplementcapitalcontrols.Exchangecontrolscanalso createwhatamountstoaquotaonimports,thustriggeringanincreaseinrelativedomestic prices.21Foreignexchangerationinghasalsobeenshowntohaveanegativeimpactonoutput andemployment.22 Boththeempiricalandtheoreticalliteratureclearlysupportthecasethatfinancial repressioncannegativelyimpacteconomicgrowth.However,itmustbenotedthatrobust 17 Seeforexample(Easterly,1993;Galindo,Micco,Ordoñez,Bris,&Repetto,2002;Lanyi&Saracoglu,1983; Roubini&Salaimartin,1992;WorldBank,1989) 18 (Goldsmith,1969) 19 (DelaTorre,Gozzi,&Schmukler,2007) 20 (Capie&Wood,2002) 21 (Agénor,1992,p.11;Bhagwati,1978;Greenwood&Kimbrough,1987) 22 (Austin,1989) economicgrowthandfinancialrepressionmaynotbemutuallyexclusive.Forexample,manyof thecountriesthatReinhartandSbranciaargueashavingactivelyengagedinfinancial repressionfollowingtheSecondWorldWaralsomanagedtogenerateoutsizedeconomic growth.From1948to1973therealGDPofWesternEuropegrewtwiceasfastasduringany otherperiodofcomparablelength,beforeorsince.23Inotherwords,ifReinhartandSbrancia arecorrectintheirassessment,the‘eraoffinancialrepression’followingtheSecondWorld Warcoincidedwiththe‘goldenageofeconomicgrowth’. Alsoofnoteisthefactthatfrom1945through1980therewasnotasinglemajor systemicinternationalbankingcrisis.Thisfactstandsinstarkcontrastwithrepeatedbanking crisesthatoccurredbothbeforeandfollowingthe‘eraoffinancialrepression’.24Onepossible explanationforthisphenomenonisthat,incontrasttothegrowinginternationaltrade integrationfollowingtheSecondWorldWar,financialintegrationacrossborderswasprevented throughanumberofrestrictions.25Asnotedearlier,financialrepressionpoliciessharesome commonfeatureswithprudentialmeasures,suchasbankreserverequirementsthatmandate anincreaseingovernmentdebtholdings.Researchhasshownthatbankingcrisesoften foreshadowsovereigndebtdefaults.26 Arguablyoneofthemostimportantelementsoffinancialrepressionisitsimpacton publicdebt.Governmentsareoftenforcedtopayahigherrateofdebtinterest,orinextreme casescanbeentirelyshutoutofdebtmarkets,astheratioofpublicdebt-to-nationalincome (debt-to-GDP)climbs.Inflation,whichoftenaccompaniesfinancialrepression,iscapturedin nominalGDPandcanhelpreducethedebt-to-GDPratio.However,significantinflation,or negativerealinterestrates,neednotaccompanyfinancialrepressiontohaveapositivedebt sustainabilityeffect;anybelow-marketinterestratereducestheservicingcostofgovernment 23 (B.Eichengreen,1996) (Bordo&Landon-Lane,2010;CarmenM.Reinhart&Rogoff,2009) 25 (Obstfeld&Taylor,2004) 26 (C.M.Reinhart&Rogoff,2011) 24 debt.However,likeinflation,financialrepressionisonlyeffectiveagainstgovernmentdebts thataredenominatedinthedomesticcurrency. 3Measurementoffinancialrepression GiovanninianddeMelo(1993)andReinhartandSbrancia(2011)developedmethods forquantifyingandmeasuringtheimpactoffinancialrepression.Thissectionofcontainsa discussionofthesemethods,theirresults,andsuggestedalternativeapproaches. 3.1GiovanninianddeMelo Giovannini’sanddeMeloassembledataforasampleoftwenty-fouremergingmarket countriesfortheperiodof1972through1987.27GiovanninianddeMelocalculategovernment revenuefromfinancialrepressionasthedifferencebetweenthegovernment’sforeignand domesticcostoffunds,multipliedbythepublicdebtofthecentralgovernment: FR=(if–id)*PD wheregovernmentrevenuefromfinancialrepression(FR)iscalculatedbysubtractingthe artificiallylowdomesticinterestrate(id)fromtheforeignmarketinterestrate(if),andthen multiplyingbygovernmentpublicdebt(PD). Theirresultsestimatethe'governmentrevenue’fromfinancialrepressionrangedas highas5.8%ofannualGDPinMexico,or40%oftheMexicangovernment’staxlevies.To determinetheir‘market’ratetheauthorsutilizedatafromtheWorldBankDebtorReporting System,whichisbasedonforeign‘commercial’debtinterestfromfinancialinstitutionsthat havefloatedLIBOR-basedborrowingsoninternationalmarkets,suchasNewYorkandLondon. 27 (Giovannini&Demelo,1993,p.957)Somedataismissingforsomeyears,andtheauthorsacknowledgethe debatabledecisionofincludingGreeceandPortugalintheirsample,bothofwhicharegenerallyconsideredas ‘advanced’countries. Oneproblemwiththismethod,whichtheauthorsdonotdiscuss,isthatcommercial ratesofinterestarenearlyalwayshigherthangovernmentrates,oftenbyasignificantmargin. Accordingly,commercialratesmaynotberepresentativeofforeignsovereignrates,leadingto anupwardbiasintheirfinancialrepressioncalculations.Asecondissuewiththeirmethodis thatratesofinterestcansignificantlyvarybytypeoffinancialinstitution.Manydifferenttypes offinancialoperatingentitiesbesidesdepositories,suchasinsurancecompanies,investment banks,specialtyfinancelenders,andautofinancecompanies,canbeclassifiedasa‘financial institution’.Indefenceoftheauthors,itwasanotuncommonpracticeduringtheperiod studiedforgovernmentstoown,orexercisesomedegreeofcontrol,overdomesticfinancial institutions.Itcouldthereforebereasonabletoarguethatfinancialinstitutionsservesarea reasonableproxyforthemarketinterestratethatforeigninvestorswouldrequiretohold government'sdebt.However,theauthorsfailtomakethiscase. Aperhapssignificantconceptualproblemwithrepresentinganinterestratefromthe periodunderstudyasa‘market’rateisthepervasivenessoffinancialrepressionduringthe period.28Thelooseningofcapitalcontrolsandfinancialderegulationtookplaceoverthecourse ofthesampleperiod,notbeforetheperiodofstudy.29Onepossiblewayofaddressingthis issuewouldbetosegmentandcomparedatabetweendifferentsubperiods.However,suchan approachwasnotundertakenordiscussedbytheauthors. Theauthorsexcludedebtheldbythecentralbankintheirfinalcalculation,asthe interestisreturnedtothegovernment.However,thedebtholdingsofmonetaryauthoritiesare includedintheireffectivedomesticinterestratecalculations“becausethetreasurynormally remuneratesthecentralbankforitsholdingsofinterest-bearingtreasurydebt”.30Whilethe explanationforexcludingcentralbankholdingsinthefirstinstanceseemsreasonable,the inconsistenttreatmentofcentralbankholdingsisnotsufficientlyjustifiedbytheauthors. 28 (C.M.Reinhart&Sbrancia,2011) (Obstfeld&Taylor,2004;D.Quinn,1997) 30 (Giovannini&Demelo,1993,pp.956-957) 29 Last,theauthorsuseoftheterm‘governmentrevenue’todescribetheeffectsof financialrepressionisproblematic.Thegovernmentdoesnotinfactcollectanytaxrevenue fromfinancialrepression.Thebenefitsgovernment’srealizefromfinancialrepression,suchas reducedinterestexpense,areinfactmoreakinto‘savings’thanrevenue. 3.2ReinhartandSbrancia ReinhartandSbranciareferenceGiovannini'sanddeMelo'smethodsandtakeasimilar ‘bottomline’approachtocalculatethe‘liquidationeffect’,whichtheyalsorefertoas‘financial repressiontax’,throughanexaminationofrealinterestratesofgovernmentdebt.31They assembledataforaten-countrysampleofadvancedanddevelopingeconomies,includingthe UnitedKingdomfor1945-1980.Theirresultsshowthatnegativerealinterestrateshada significantimpactonreducingtherealcostofpublicdebt.ReinhartandSbranciaacknowledge thesimilaritybetweentheirsandGiovanninianddeMelo’smethod.Theydonot,however, considertheGiovanninianddeMelomethodappropriateforthepost-BrettonWoodsera becausemanycountriesdidnothavemuchifanyexternaldebtdenominatedinaforeign currency. ReinhartandSbranciaconstructa‘synthetic’debtportfolioforeachsamplecountryto determinetheappropriatedomesticinterestrate.Next,theycalculatetherealinterestrate(rt) foreachcountryasfollows: rt = it −1 − π t 1 + π t Where π andiareCPIinflationandnominalinterestrates,respectively.Savingstogovernment occuranyyearinwhichtherealinterestrate(rt)isnegative.The‘liquidationeffect’,or 31 (Sbrancia,2011,p.35)Theauthorsalsostatetheyhavealsochosentoremain“silentabouttheoptimalityor desirabilityofrelyingonthismechanismtoreducedebts”. ‘financialrepressiontax’inanygivenyear,issimplycalculatedbymultiplyingthenegativereal interestrate(rt)bytheoutstandingpublicdebt. ReinhartandSbranciaalsoproposea“supplementary”methodforcalculatingdebt liquidationthattakesintoaccountcapitallosses,ordeclinesinbondprices,ongovernment debt.Thismethodcouldbeimportantforgovernments(orcentralbanks)thatpurchasetheir country’sdebtinsignificantquantitywhenitisadvantageoustodoso.ReinhartandSbrancia calculateaholdingperiodreturn(HPR)foreachdebtinstrumentasfollows: HPRt = ( Pt − Pt −1 ) + Ct Pt −1 WherePtandPt-1arebondpricesattimetandt-1,respectively,andCtistheyearlyinterest payment.Similartotheirpreviousmethodpresentedabove,agovernmentdebtliquidation yearisdeterminedasanyyearinwhichtherealreturnofthedebtportfolioisnegative.The authorsdonoteseveralproblemswiththissecondapproach,suchashowtofactorinnonmarketabledebt(forwhichthereisnopricedata),aswellasthegeneraldifficultyofobtaining historicalbondpricedataforsomecountries. Withthefirstmethod,Reinhart’sandSbrancia’sfindingsfortheUnitedKingdom suggestthatnearlyone-halfoftheyearsfrom1945-1980(including1948-1953)weredebt liquidationyears,withanaveragenegativerealinterestrateof3.8%.32TheirresultsfortheUK usingthesecondmeasurewereslightlylowerthantheirfirst,withliquidationasapercentage ofGDPof2.4%versus3.2%,respectively.However,theyonlyutilizebondpricedatafortheUK fromthe1960onwards. 32 Atthetimeofwritingtheirfulldatabasehasnotyetbeenmadeavailableforamoredetailedreviewofmethods andresults(i.e.,individualyearsorisolatedperiods). OneofthefirstquestionstoemergefromReinhart’sandSbrancia’sworkiswhythe years1945-1947werefoundtobenon-debtliquidationyearsfortheUnitedKingdom?As shownlater,significantinflationcontinuedaftertheendofthewar.Further,whiledebtlevels peakedin1946,theUK’soveralldebtpositionwasroughlysimilarin1948asitwasin1945,the firstpost-waryearthatauthorsidentityasadebtliquidationyear.Partoftheexplanationis thattheirmethodologymaybeoverlyconservative.Theyconsideradebtliquidationyearas oneinwhichrealinterestratesarenegativeasopposedtowhenrealinterestratesaresimply belowmarketrates.Theauthorsjustifytheirhigherthresholdduetothedifficultyand conceptualchallengesassociatedwithdeterminingatrue‘market’rateduringaperiodof widespreadfinancialrepression.True,negativerealreturnsondepositsandbondswereanear universalphenomenonduringmuchofthepost-warperiod.Further,eveniftherewereno restrictionsoninterestratesinarelativelyfreemarketlikeSwitzerland,itisreasonableto believethatglobalrateshadsomedownwardinfluenceonSwissrates. Whileitisunclearhowtobesttoadjustfortheeffectof‘worldinterestrates’inanyuse ofmarketratesincalculatingtheeffectsoffinancialrepression,acknowledgementofthis problemisinsufficientjustificationforaltogetherdisregardingmarketrates.33Duringandafter theSecondWorldWarsophisticatedfreemarketsdevelopedinlightlyregulatedvenues.34In Switzerland,forexample,foreignsecuritiesandcurrenciesweretradedatsignificantdiscounts totheirofficialrates.35TheBankofEngland“obsessed”withoverseastradingof‘free’sterling, andapproximately$300millionoffreesterlingwastradedduringoneyearyearinNewYork alone.36Further,currencyblackmarketsunderminetheefficacyofcapitalcontrols,which typicallyplayacrucialroleinfinancialrepression.Theexistenceofsizablecurrencyblack marketscouldconceivablynegatetheeffectivenessoffinancialrepression,particularlyfor economicactorsthathaveaccesstosuchmarkets.Thesefreemarketsarenotmentionedby theauthors. 33 Forfurtherdiscussionofa‘worldinterestrate’see(Barro&Salaimartin,1990;Blanchard&Summers,1984; Chinn&Frankel,2005;Koedijk,Kool,&Kroes,1994;Lucas,1990;Yi,Blankenau,&Kose,2001) 34 Seeforexample(Frey&Waldenström,2004) 35 (TheEconomist,22May,1948) 36 (Cairncross,1985,pp.258,263) Asecondwayinwhichtheauthor'scalculationsmayproveconservativerelatestotheir useofofficialinflationdatasources.37Forexample,theinflationstatisticsreflectedinRichards (2002)showconsistentlylowerlevelsofinflationthanotherestimatesforthesameperiodthat areshownlaterinthispaper.Theauthorsdomakenoteofthisissue,butforreasonsthatare uncleartheydonotutilizearguablymorerealisticinflationfigures. Thereis,however,aperhapsmorefundamentalissueinReinhart’sandSbrancia’s secondmethodthatisnotdiscussedbytheauthors.38Itistruethatagovernment,followinga declineinthepricesofitsbonds,canretiredebtatanadvantageouscosttothegovernment. However,theinterestexpenseincurredbythatgovernmentonsubsequentdebtissuancemay increaseasthepriceinvestorsarewillingtopayonanynewlyissueddebtisdeterminedbythe currentyieldonalreadyissuedbonds.Bondyieldsareinverselyrelatedtobondprices: 𝑐𝑢𝑟𝑟𝑒𝑛𝑡𝑦𝑖𝑒𝑙𝑑 = 𝑎𝑛𝑛𝑢𝑎𝑙𝑐𝑜𝑢𝑝𝑜𝑛 𝑚𝑎𝑟𝑘𝑒𝑡𝑝𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒 Inotherwords,forfixedcoupongovernmentbonds,asbondpricesdeclineyieldsincrease,and higheryieldsequatetohighernominalinterestexpensebornbytheissuinggovernmentonany newlyissuedgovernmentdebt.Insum,anyeconomicgainagovernmentrealizesbyretiring anyofitsbondsthathavedeclinedinvaluemaybeoffsetorexceededbyhigherinterestcosts associatedwithnewdebtissuance.Asimplehypotheticalillustrationoftheabovepointis presentedinTable1,whichshowstheimpactofdebtretirementandnewsovereignbond issuanceonagovernmentbalancesheet. 37 38 (C.M.Reinhart&Sbrancia,2011,p.28) (C.M.Reinhart&Sbrancia,2011,pp.30-31) Table1:IllustrationofIntertemporalChangesinPublicDebtInterestExpenseDuetoCapital Gains(Losses) HypotheticalTreasuryBondIssuanceandTreasuryBalanceSheet TreasuryBondIssuance 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 Bond(1)principal £100 Couponpayment(fixed) £2.50 £2.50 £2.50 Couponyield(fixed) 2.50% MarketpriceofBond(1) £100 £100 £75.00 CurrentYield 2.50% 2.50% 3.33% Bond(2)-principal £100 Couponpayment(fixed) £3.33 £3.33 Couponyield(fixed) 3.33% MarketpriceofBond(2) £100 £100 CurrentYield 3.33% 3.33% TreasuryBalanceSheet 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 BeginningofYearCash £0.00 £100.00 £97.50 £10.00 £10.00 AnnualSurplus/Deficit £0.00 £0.00 -£10.00 -£100.00 £0.00 Interestexpense £0.00 £2.50 £2.50 £3.33 DebtIssued-Deficit-Interest=Cash £100.00 £97.50 £85.00 £10.00 £6.67 BondRepurchases £75.00 £0.00 £0.00 Gain(Loss)onBondRepurchase(onetime) £25.00 Gain(Loss)oninterestrefinancing(reoccurring) -£0.83 Cash-BondRepurchases £100.00 £97.50 £10.00 £10.00 £6.67 Theaboveillustrationdemonstrateshowabeneficialone-timecapitalgainrealizedbya governmentthroughadeclineinthemarketvalueofitsbondscanbepartially,ifnotwholly, offsetbymodestlyhigherreoccurringinterestexpensethegovernmentwillincuron subsequentdebtissuance.Thereasonforthisisthatadeclineinbondpricesresultsinhigher yieldsonoutstandingdebt,anditistheseexpostyieldsthatguidethepricingofnewlyissued debt. Last,theauthorsacknowledgethatinthereductionofpost-SecondWorldWardebts that“otherfactors,suchasrealgrowth,mayhavebeenrelevantaswell.”39AsnotedinChapter 2,popularnarrativesaswellasacademicanalysisbyBuiter(1985)andothersonhowpostSecondWorldWardebtswerereducedthrougheconomicgrowthareincompleteatbest,and possiblymisleading.However,ReinhartandSbranciadonotattempttocompareorquantify therelativecontributionofrealgrowthandfinancialrepression.Suchacomparisoncouldbe helpfulforunderstandingtherelativeimpactofeachonpost-SecondWorldWardebt reduction. 3.3Alternativesmeasuresoffinancialrepression Thissectionpresentsanalternativecalculationofgovernmentsavingsfromfinancial repressionforBritainduringthepost-SecondWorldWarperiod.Thisalternativecalculationcan becharacterizedasahybridofthepreviouslydescribedmethodsdevelopedbyGiovanniniand deMeloandReinhartandSbranciaandaddressessomeoftheissuesidentifiedearlier. Specifically,thealternativecalculationpresentedbelowdoesawaywiththecommercialrateof interestusedbyGiovanninianddeMeloandinsteadutilizesafreemarketrate.40 Inadditionto‘free’sterling,thereisevidenceofamarketfor‘free’Britishsovereign debt.InAmerica,NewYork-tradedUKbearerbondswereyielding7%,whichwasmorethan 39 (Sbrancia,2011,p.35) AnothersupplementaryapproachtotheReinhartandSbranciamethodnotperformedherethatcouldbeuseful wouldbetoallowforalowerthresholdofwhatconstitutesadebtliquidationyear,suchaswheneverrealinterest ratesarebelowmarketrates. 40 doubletheapproximately3%yieldthatBritish2.5%couponConsolswerepayinginLondon duringthistime(Table2).41 Table2:PricesandYieldsofLong-TermBritishGovernmentSecurities,1935-1961 Year 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 Annual Avg. Yield% High Yield 86.500 2.89% 94.3750 2.65% 85.000 2.94% 87.2400 2.87% 76.250 2.28% 84.8125 2.95% 74.000 3.38% 79.3750 3.16% 67.250 3.72% 71.1250 3.51% 73.500 3.40% 77.0000 3.25% 79.875 3.13% 82.8750 3.02% 82.500 3.03% 83.6250 2.99% 80.625 3.10% 83.2500 3.00% 79.625 3.14% 82.2500 3.04% 85.625 2.92% 92.8125 2.69% 96.188 2.60% 99.6250 2.51% 90.500 2.76% 99.1250 2.52% 77.875 3.21% 83.3750 3.01% 75.750 3.30% 81.9375 3.05% 70.375 3.55% 74.6875 3.35% 66.000 3.79% 71.5000 3.50% 59.125 4.23% 62.0000 4.03% 61.240 4.08% 65.2500 3.83% 66.500 3.76% 69.7500 3.58% 60.000 4.17% 66.5000 3.76% 52.750 4.74% 56.7500 4.41% 50.250 4.98% 55.6875 4.49% 50.250 4.98% 52.8125 4.73% 51.875 4.82% 53.6250 4.66% 46.375 5.40% 49.7500 5.02% 40.375 6.20% 44.0000 5.70% Low 80.000 82.250 73.125 64.000 61.000 68.125 76.750 81.000 78.250 78.688 91.563 81.125 80.000 74.500 65.128 68.125 60.125 55.000 58.375 58.375 54.875 49.875 45.000 46.750 48.625 43.875 36.250 YieldRangeofAllIssues30-yearsor Longer Yield 3.13% 3.04% 3.42% 3.91% 4.10% 3.67% 3.26% 3.09% 3.19% 3.18% 3.06% 3.08% 3.12% 3.36% 3.84% 3.67% 4.16% 4.55% 4.28% 4.28% 4.56% 5.01% 5.56% 5.35% 5.14% 5.71% 6.90% Low 2.88% 2.96% 3.37% 3.56% 3.65% 3.25% 3.03% 3.03% 3.14% 3.07% 2.74% 2.53% 3.00% 3.13% 3.56% 3.53% 4.06% 4.27% 3.89% 3.81% 4.39% 4.90% 5.41% 4.89% 4.99% 5.68% 6.45% High 3.13% 3.17% 3.43% 3.62% 3.77% 3.44% 3.19% 3.18% 3.23% 3.18% 2.91% 2.67% 3.05% 3.19% 3.81% 3.73% 4.44% 4.61% 4.27% 4.15% 4.50% 5.08% 5.62% 5.20% 5.40% 6.07% 6.85% MaxCurrentYield ofPremiumIssues 3.48% 3.54% 3.64% 3.87% 3.62% 3.58% 3.62% 3.62% 3.62% 3.62% 3.44% 3.69% 3.65% 3.94% 3.90% 41 ('FreeSterlinginEurope',TheEconomist,22May,1948)Atpresentonlyasinglefreeyielddatapointhasbeen located. 42 Source:Homer(1963) TheNewYork‘free’yieldcanbeemployedtocalculategovernmentsavingsfrom financialrepressionthroughaslightlymodifiedversionofGiovanninianddeMelo’smethod: (1) FRS=(im–id)*PD wheregovernmentsavingsfromfinancialrepression(FRS)iscalculatedbysubtractingthe artificiallylowdomesticinterestrate(id)fromthefreemarketinterestrate(im),andthen multiplyingbygovernmentpublicdebt(PD).Theresultsofsuchacalculationfortheyears 1945-1951arepresentedinTable3. 42 (Homer,1963,p.16) Table3:UKFinancialRepressionSavingsEstimate,ConstantFreeMarketInterestRate,194660 UKNet Freemarket PublicDebt interest (£bs) rate* 23.64 7.00% 25.63 7.00% 25.62 7.00% 25.17 7.00% 25.80 7.00% 25.92 7.00% 25.89 7.00% 26.05 7.00% 26.58 7.00% 26.93 7.00% 27.04 7.00% 27.01 7.00% 27.23 7.00% 27.38 7.00% 27.73 7.00% Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 Avg.Yieldof Long-Term UKDebt 2.60% 2.76% 3.21% 3.30% 3.55% 3.79% 4.23% 4.08% 3.76% 4.17% 4.74% 4.98% 4.98% 4.82% 5.40% Financial Repression Savings(£bs) 1.04 1.09 0.97 0.93 0.89 0.83 0.72 0.76 0.86 0.76 0.61 0.55 0.55 0.60 0.44 Financial RepressionSavings %ofGDP 10.9% 10.1% 8.1% 7.3% 6.7% 5.6% 4.5% 4.4% 4.8% 3.9% 2.9% 2.5% 2.4% 2.5% 1.7% *Note:Atpresentonlyasinglefreeyielddatapointhasbeensourced('FreeSterlinginEurope',TheEconomist22 May,1948) Sources:HMTreasury,TheEconomist,Homer(1963),IMF,UKONS TheresultsindicatethattheeffectsofUKfinancialrepressionwerelikelylargest(asa percentageofGDP)intheyearsimmediatelyfollowingtheSecondWorldWar,butthensteadily diminished.In1948,savingsattributabletofinancialrepressionwereover8%ofGDP,or significantlylargerthanGiovanninianddeMelo’slargestfindingof5.8%ofGDPforMexico. However,astimeprogressestheaverageyieldoflong-termUKdebtnearlydoubleswhilethe netpublicdebtonlyincreasesfrom£23.6billionin1946to£27.7billionin1960,orby17%. However,theaboveestimationassumesnochangeovertimeinthe7%freemarketyieldonUK debtsourcedfromthe1948TheEconomistarticle.Theresultsfromadjustingthefreemarket yieldproportionallytotheadjustmentinofficialmarketyieldsarefoundinTable4. Table4:UKFinancialRepressionSavingsEstimate,AdjustedFreeMarketInterestRate,194660 UKNet Freemarket PublicDebt interest (£bs) rate* 23.64 5.50% 25.63 5.86% 25.62 7.00% 25.17 7.20% 25.80 7.74% 25.92 8.26% 25.89 9.22% 26.05 8.90% 26.58 8.20% 26.93 9.09% 27.04 10.34% 27.01 10.86% 27.23 10.86% 27.38 10.51% 27.73 11.78% Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 Avg.Yieldof Long-Term UKDebt 2.60% 2.76% 3.21% 3.30% 3.55% 3.79% 4.23% 4.08% 3.76% 4.17% 4.74% 4.98% 4.98% 4.82% 5.40% Financial Repression Savings(£bs) 0.69 0.79 0.97 0.98 1.08 1.16 1.29 1.25 1.18 1.33 1.51 1.59 1.60 1.56 1.77 Financial RepressionSavings %ofGDP 7.2% 7.4% 8.1% 7.7% 8.1% 7.8% 8.1% 7.3% 6.5% 6.8% 7.2% 7.2% 6.9% 6.4% 6.8% *Note:Adjustedproportionallybasedonchangesintheyieldoflong-termBritishgovernmentdebt.Atpresent onlyasinglefreeyielddatapointhasbeensourced('FreeSterlinginEurope',TheEconomist22May,1948) Sources:HMTreasury,TheEconomist,Homer(1963),IMF,UKONS Oneuntestedmethodforcalculatingfinancialrepressionsavingsthatisbeyondthe scopeofthispaperinvolvesthecreationofsyntheticmarketyield.Asnotedearlier,thelackof amarketinterestratewouldaddressonethemostsignificantissueswiththeGiovanniniandde Melomethod,whichisthedeterminationofasuitablefreemarketrateofinterest(if)to comparewiththefinanciallyrepressedrateofinterest(id).‘Free’currencyexchangeratedata couldbeusedtoconstructasyntheticmarketyieldforbondsbyemployingamodifiedversion oftheuncoveredinterestrateparityequation: (2)(1 + 𝑖£ ) = 78 98 (1 + 𝑖: ) whereFtisthecurrent‘free’exchangerate(whichsubstitutesintheclassicversionofthe equationfortheexpectedfuturespotexchangerate,giventhatfreecurrencywasoftentrading atadevaluedfreeratethatanticipatedfutureofficialdevaluations),Stisthecurrentfixed officialexchangerateattimet,i£istheinterestrateinthethefreecurrencyissuingcountry, andifisthesyntheticmarketyield. Furtherstudyisnecessarytodeterminethefeasibilityoftheaboveapproach,but researchsuggestsastatisticallysignificant,negativelylaggedinfluenceofcurrenciesondebt.43 Further,Flandreau&Oosterlinck(2011)imputedcurrencyvaluesfromgovernmentdebtyields, anditcouldbeworthexploringwhethersuchatransformationcanbereversedtocalculatea syntheticmarketyield.44 3.4TheFinancialRepressionIndex BothGiovanninianddeMeloandReinhartandSbranciausetheresultsfromtheir quantitativemethodstocomparethedegreeoffinancialrepressionacrossdifferentcountries. However,withregardstotheReinhartandSbranciamethod,Taylor(2011)notesthatthe actualreason(s)behindnegativerealyieldsongovernmentdebtarenotalwaysclear.For example,inMay2012theGermangovernmentsuccessfullyfloatedtwo-yearbondswithazero coupon,andin2015theSwissgovernmentissuednewdebtwithanegativenominalyield. TheseeventsoccurredinspiteofthefactthatpositiveinflationexistedinbothGermanyand Switzerlandatthetimeofdebtissuance,andfutureexpectationsofinflationwerealsopositive. InvestorsappeartobepayingtheGermanandSwissgovernmentinrealandnominalterms, respectively,fortheopportunitytolendmoneytothegovernment.IftheReinhartandSbrancia methodwereemployedinthesecasestheresultswouldsuggestthatbothGermanyand 43 44 (Dreher,Herz,&Karb,2006) (Flandreau&Oosterlinck,2011) Switzerlandwereengagedinfinancialrepression.However,thenotionthatfinancialrepression ineithercountryisresponsiblefortheobservednegativeyieldsisdubious.Instead,aflightto highercreditqualityinresponsetotheEuropeansovereigndebtcrisesisthelikelyexplanation behindtheGermanandSwissrates. Insum,‘bottom’s-up’approachestoidentifyingfinancialrepressioncanproduce incompleteormisleadingresults.Furtherinsightscanbegainedbycomparingcountriesacross qualitativemeasuresoffinancialrepressionsuchasacompositeindicator(compositeindex), whichallowsforcross-countrycomparisonsoffinancialrepressionoveraseriesofstandardized measuresanddifferenttimeperiods.Samplevariablesthatcouldbeutilizedforthe constructionofanindextakenfromexistingdatasourcessuchastheIMF,BIS,WorldBank,and OECDaresummarizedinAppendix1.45 45 Unfortunately,forthetimeperiodunderstudyinthisthesismuchofthedatarequiredtocreateafinancial repressioncompositeindexwaseithernevercollectedorhasnotyetbeenlocated. 4Britishfinancialrepression Thissectionofthepaperaddressesthedisagreementintheliteratureoverwhatrole financialrepressionmayhaveplayedinsustainingBritain’srecord-settinglevelsofpublicdebt followingtheSecondWorldWar.Largelymissingisadetailedhistoricalaccountofthepolicies andpracticesthatmayormaynothavefacilitatedfinancialrepressionincountriessuchas Britain.Inotherwords,doesthehistoricalrecordsupportorcontradictReinhartandSbrancia’s quantitativeargumentoffinancialrepression?Theshortanswertotheabovequestionisthat yes,Britaindidinfactenactnumerouspoliciesandlegislationthatcanbecharacterizedas financialrepression.Further,thesepoliciesplayedausefulroleinsustainingBritishsovereign debt.However,itisfartoosimplistictorefertofinancialrepressionisasimplebinary,yesor no,fashion.Differentdegreesandtypesoffinancialrepressionexist. Theremainderofthispaperdescribesthenuanced,multi-facetednatureofBritish financialrepressionbyfirstexploringtheoriginsofBritishfinancialrepression,thenexamining thevariousaspectsofBritishfinancialrepression,andconcludeswiththeimpactfinancial repressionhadonselectareasoftheBritisheconomy. 4.1TheoriginsofBritishfinancialrepression ThegrowingthreatposedbyanevermoreassertiveNaziGermanyledtheBritishto rearminthelatter-halfofthe1930s.Whilethisbroughtfullemploymentitalsotriggered concernsoverinflationandimbalancesinBritain’snationalaccounts.46Itwasduringthistime thatJohnMaynardKeynes’theoriesonwartimeandpost-warfinance,whichwouldprove highlyinfluentialtoBritishfinancialrepression,tookshape.InAprilandJuly1939Keyneswrote severalarticlesintheTimesoutliningadualpolicyoflowinterestratesandcapitalcontrols, whichwentontobepartiallyadoptedinApril1941.47Keynesalsoadvocatedfordeferred 46 (Skidelsky,2000,p.20) th th Keynes’ideaswerefirstpublicizedviatwoeditorialsintheTimesonthe14 and15 November1939.Abooklet versiontitledHowtoPayfortheWarfollowedon27Februaryin1940.However,anearlierlectureonthistopic wasgivenbyKeynesatCambridge’sMarshallSocietyon20October,1939titled‘WarPotentialandWarFinance’ 47 deposits,whichweretobeblockedandhaveanopen-endedreleasedatetobedeterminedat thediscretionoftheTreasury.48Originallycalled‘compulsorysavings’,theprogramwaslater rebrandedas‘deferredpay’formarketingpurposes.49Theplancalledforthegovernmenttoset long-terminterestratesat2.5%,whichrepresenteda17%reductionontheapproximately3% yieldsoflonger-termBritishdebtinstrumentsatthattime.50 LordKeynesprofessedhimselftobeaproponentofinterestratecapsinhisGeneral Theory51,andina12January,1937TimeseditorialKeynesstated“wemustavoid[dear money]…aswewouldhell-fire”.52Thedoctrineof‘permanentlycheapmoney’wouldgoonto reignoverBritishmonetarypolicyuntil1951.KeynesadvocatedthattheBritishChancellorof theExchequershouldannouncethathewouldborrowatnomorethan2.5%socreditorshave zerodoubtthatthesearethebesttermsavailableforlong-datedBritishdebt.Keyneshad‘an appreciationthatthesocialandpoliticalclimatewouldnotpermitarepeatoftherentierfriendlypolicyofFirstWorldWar’,althoughKeyneslaterrevisedupwardshissuggested interestrateto3%.53TobeeffectiveKeynesfelttheChancellor’sstatementwouldneedtobe buttressedbycontroloverdomesticcapitalissuesandanembargoonforeignlending,meaning capitalcontrolswouldneedtobeinstituted.54Lowinterestrates,oneofthehallmarksof financialrepression,werefacilitatedbytheBankofEngland(whereKeyneswasaCourt member),whichkepttheshort-termTreasurybillrateat1%from1939-1945. Itisherewiththeselate-1930sproposalsthatweseeKeyneslayingsome,butnotall,of thetheoreticalandpolicyfoundationsforpost-warBritishfinancialrepression.However, (Skidelsky,2000,p.43).Coincidentally,theLabourpartyalsopublishedatthistimeanidenticallytitledbookon warfinance(Durbin,1939).ThereasonKeynes’ideasultimatelywonoutwasbecause,asSkidelskyputit,hehad the“onlytheoryonofferwhichpromisedbothguns,butterandlowinterestrates”(Skidelsky,2000,p.20). 48 (Keynes,1940,p.47) 49 (Skidelsky,2000,p.59) 50 (Keynes,1940,p.44) 51 (Keynes,1936,p.351) 52 (Skidelsky,2000,p.22) 53 (Kynaston,1999,p.464) 54 (Skidelsky,2000,pp.24-25) Keynes’crucialcontributionstoBritishfinancialrepressiongoentirelyunacknowledgedby Keynes’biographersandothereconomichistorians.55 EvidenceofBritishfinancialrepressionpriortothe1940salsoexists.AfterBritain abandonedthegoldstandardforasecondandfinaltimein1931,aprohibitiononloansto overseasborrowerswasimposed.In1933thepurchaseofforeignsecuritieswasalso prohibited,althoughdirectinvestmentsabroadweretreatedmoreleniently.56Itisunclearwhat roleifanyKeyneshadonshapingthesepolicies.Onedifferencebetweenthisperiodandwith thefollowingdecadeappearstobetherelianceoftheBankofEnglandandWhitehallonthe useofmoralsuasion,asopposedtoregulationsorlaw,toexecute1930spolicychanges.This approachmayhavealsoplayedatleastsomeroleintherelativelyspeedyreversalofsome policies,suchastherelaxationofloanrestrictionstoCommonwealthborrowersin1933.These examplesillustratehowfinancialrepressioncantakebothexplicitandimplicitform. AsearlyasSeptember1941Britishofficialswerecontemplatingthepost-warfinancial andeconomicorder.57InDecember1941,ontheothersideoftheAtlantic,TreasurySecretary MorgenthauaskedHarryDexterWhitetobeginworkonwhatwastobecometheBretton Woodsagreement.58ItwasduringthistimethatgroundworkwaslaidinbothBritainandthe U.S.forthepost-warinternationalframeworkthatwouldprovesoconducivetofinancial repression.Stringentcapitalcontrols,imposedatthebeginningoftheSecondWorldWarin September1939,providedthenecessaryconditionforthecreationoftheSterlingArea,which wouldplayasupportingroleinenforcinginternationalfinancialrepression.59Underthenew rulesallpurchasesofforeignexchangerequiredpriorapprovalofBritishofficials,andcountries thatdidnotparticipateinthewarceasedtobeapartoftheSterlingBloc(e.g.,Sweden).The outbreakofwarledBritaintoimposeexchangecontrolonpaymentsoutsidetheSterlingBloc, whilerelativelyfreemovementofcapital,coordinatedbytheBankofEngland,waspermitted 55 (R.F.Harrod,1951;Skidelsky,2000) (CairncrossandEichengreen,1983,p.22) 57 (Fforde,1992,p.36) 58 (Skidelsky,2000,pp.256-263) 59 (Capie,2010,p.146) 56 within.60TheregulationsandrulesgoverningtheSterlingAreawerecomplex;varyingdegrees offreedomexistedonthetransferabilityofcurrency,dependentuponlocationandpurpose. Importrestrictionsalsoexistedsothat“whiletheremightbefreedomtomakeapayment, therewasnotalwaysfreedomtomakeapurchase”.61Duringthewara‘DollarPool’was establishedamongSterlingAreacountriesthatwouldremaininplaceafterhostilitiesended.Its purposewastoconserveU.S.dollarsamongstSterlingAreamembersbyimposinglicensing restrictionsondollarimports,andmemberswererequiredtodepositexcessdollarsandgoldat theBankofEngland.62 Keynes,inadditiontoprovidingtheintellectualfoundationsformuchofBritishfinancial repression,wouldalsogoontoplayaleadingroleinimplementingfinancialrepressionpolicies duringandafterthewarfrominsideTreasury.However,itisimportanttonotethatnotall facetsofpost-warBritishfinancialrepressionwereprescribedbyKeynes.Further,Keyneswas notaloneinadvocatingforBritishfinancialrepression.Forexample,theBankofEnglandwasat leastwillingtogoalongwith,ifnotplaytheroleofaccomplice,inthemaintenanceoflow interestrates. WhileothereconomichistorianshaveindirectlycoveredvariousaspectsofBritish financialrepressionwithoutlabellingitassuch,ReinhartandSbrancia(2011)arethefirstto explicitlymakethecasethatfinancialrepressionwaspracticedinpost-SecondWorldWar Britainandotheradvancedcountries.Oneofthefirstquestionswhichemergesafterreviewing Reinhart’sandSbrancia’sresearchthatpromptedTaylor’scritiqueiswhatpoliciesand outcomesshouldconstitutesufficientevidence,orproof,offinancialrepression?Inother words,isfinancialrepressionakintotheU.S.SupremeCourt’sdefinitionofpornography,which basicallyamountsto‘weknowitwhenweseeit’?Orcanthe‘financialrepression’labelbe assignedinamorerigorous,systematicfashion?Debtliquidationdoesnotrequirefinancial 60 (Cairncross&Eichengreen,1983,p.24). (Capie,2010,p.146;CatherineRuthSchenk,1994) 62 (Cairncross&Eichengreen,1983,p.25) 61 repressionasitcanbeduesolelytotheeffectsofinflationinexcessofnominalinterestrates. Inotherwords,demonstratingthatdebtliquidationoccurredinanygivenyear,oroveran extendedperiodduetonegativerealinterestrates,isinsufficientproofoffinancial repression.63 ReinhartandSbranciasupporttheirquantitativeevidencebyidentifyingseveral financialrepressionmeasuresineachsamplecountry.64FortheUK,theyhighlightthefollowing threeDomesticFinancialRegulationsmeasures: 1. TheGoldmarketclosedinearlySecondWorldWar,reopenedonlyin1954.65 2. TheBankofEnglandstoppedpublishingtheMinimumLendingRatein1981. 3. In1986,thegovernmentwithdrewitsguidanceonmortgagelending. ThefollowingtwomeasuresarelistedforCapitalAccount-ExchangeRestrictionsintheUK: 1. AllrestrictionsonoutwardForeignDirectInvestmentabolished,andoutwardportfolio investmentliberalized. 2. ExchangeControlActof1947suspendedinOctober1979;allremainingbarriersto inwardandoutwardflowsofcapitalremoved. Theabovemeasuresareperhapssomeofthemoresignificantfinancialrepression policiesinBritainfollowingtheSecondWorldWar.However,theauthorsdonotmakeany referencetotherelativeimportanceofthesepolices,orexplainwhythesewerehighlighted overotherpoliciesthatcouldconstitutefinancialrepression.Further,theyoverlookanumber ofotherBritishfinancialrepressionpolicies.Forexample,ChancellorDaltondirected 63 Sbrancia(2011)developsaconceptualframeworkutilizinginflationexpectationestimatestodistinguish betweendebtliquidationrelatedtounanticipatedinflationandfinancialrepression. 64 (C.M.Reinhart&Sbrancia,2011,p.17) 65 (BankforInternationalSettlements.,1941) governmentdepartmentstosupportTreasurydebtauctionsbymakingpurchasesthathelped financegovernmentdebtatlowratesofinterest.66 Britishfinancialrepressionduringthisperiod,intheformoflegislationand directives/policies,aresummarizedinTable5andTable6,respectively.Intotal,elevenpieces oflegislationandsixteenpolices/directivesthatsupportedBritishfinancialrepressionwere foundeitherinarchivalevidenceortheliterature.Theselegislativeandpolicyactshighlightthe intricateandcomprehensivenatureofBritishfinancialrepressionduringthisperiod. 66 (Cairncross,1985,pp.432-433;Worswick&Ady,1952,pp.196-198). Table5:UKFinancialRepressionLegislation,1936–1998 Legislation Tripartite Agreement Repealed/ Reduced 1973 DateEnacted 1936 CapitalIssues Committee 1936 Late-1950s Formalgovernmentapplicationprocessforcontrollingcapital flowstoforeignanddomesticapplicants;only£31million 67 exportedannuallyfrom1932-36 ;alsoreviewedalldomestic issuesover£50,000,andtheBankofEnglandreviewed 68 anythingover£100,000 DeferredPay April1941 post-WWII Originallycalled‘compulsorysavings’,depositsweretobe blockedandhaveanopen-endedreleasedate,tobe determinedatthewhimoftheTreasury.Aninterestrateof only2.5%ayear,whichwas17%cutontheroughly3%yielded bylonger-terminstrumentsatthattime. Capital Controls Sept.1939 Treasury Deposit Receipt (TDRs) WWII post-WWII Permissionfromauthoritiesrequiredpriortomakinganyforex purchases;restrictionsonforeignexchangeonpaymentsmade outsidetheSterlingArea.Limitsonsterlingbanknotestravellers cantakeoutoftheUKof£20and£10,respectively,and“no sterlingcanbesentoutoftheUnitedKingdomwithout 69 permission”. post-WWII NewsecuritywhichallowedtheTreasurytobypasstheLondon moneymarketandborrowdirectlyfrombanksthroughthe issuanceofnon-marketableTDRs Closureof LondonGold Market WWII 1945 67 Description Beginningwiththe1936Tripartiteagreementbetweenthe U.K.,FranceandtheU.S.andsubsequentbilateraland multilateralagreementsthoughSecondWorldWarandthe 1944BrettonWoodsagreement,exchangerateswere managedsothatforeignexchangecouldonlybelegally convertedatofficialexchange ClosureofLondongoldmarket,tradingandownershipofgold, andrestrictionsonimports/exportsofgold (Ingham,1984,pp.195-197;Wilson,1995,p.183) (Morgan&Thomas,1962,p.210;Wilson,1995,p.189) 69 C261,LetterfromBankofEnglandtoManageroftheFederalReserveBankofNewYork,NewYorkFederal ReserveBankArchive,17October,1946 68 Legislation Bankof EnglandAct DateEnacted Aug.1946 Repealed/ Reduced 1998 Exchange ControlAct 1947 Oct.1979 Minimum LendingRate TaxIncrease onDividends post-WWII post-WWII N/A Increaseinthedividendstaxfrom5%to12.5%madeBritain’s sovereigndebtamoreattractiveinvestmentvis-à-visequities Mortgage Lending Guidance post-WWII 1986 GovernmentguidanceonUKmortgagelending 1981 Description BankofEnglandnationalizedbytheUKgovernment;clause4(3) gavetheBank,withTreasuryapproval,explicitpowertogovern theproportionofcommercialbankassets Restrictedsomeexternalloansaswellasinwardcapitalflows; repealin1979ledtotheremovalofallremainingbarrierson inwardandoutwardcapitalflows PublishedbytheBankofEngland Table6:UKFinancialRepressionPoliciesandDirectives,1931–1973 Policy LowInterest Rates(‘Cheap Money’) DateEnacted 1931 Repealed/ Reduced 1951 Foreignloan embargo 1932 1934forSterlingbloc Withdrawalof largesterling notes 1943 post-WWII BankAdvances Restrictions IssuingHouses Association 1945,1947,1949 post-WWII 1945 post-WWII BankLending Restrictions Mid-1950s post-WWII Special Deposits Mid-1950s post-WWII 70 Description Exceptforabrieffluctuationatthebeginning ofthewar,BankRatewasmaintainedat2%; short-termTreasurybillrateat1%from19391945 Thebanonforeignloanspartiallyremovedfor othercountriesinFeb.1938butthen 70 reinstatedinDec.1938 Retirementofallnotesof£10anupto “provideanadditionalhandicapforthosewho maycontemplatebreachesofExchange 71 Control” Restrictionsonbankadvanceswereissued threetimesbytheCapitalIssuesCommittee 72 (CIC) Organizationof52Britishmerchantbanks whichfacilitatedthemonitoringandcontrol 73 oflending Enactmentofthefirstquantitativelimitson 74 loansfrombanks. “a(relativelysmall)callfor‘specialdeposits’ 75 madebyCIC C261,‘BritishandCanadianConversionPolicies.Appendix:BritishTreasuryControloverthePriceofGilt-Edged Securities,1932-39’,CorrespondencebetweenL.M.PumphreytoMr.House,NewYorkFederalReserveBank Archive,23October,1941 71 FromC261p.1,‘WithdrawalofLargeBankNotes:TheBritishExperience’,NewYorkFederalReserveBank Archive,4December,1944:“Therealpurposesweretomakemoredifficulttheillegaloperationofnotesmugglers desirousofevadingexchangecontrolregulations,ofblackmarketoperators,andoftaxevaders—allofwhom predominantlyuselargedenominationnotesinordertocoveruptheirtracks”.BankofEnglandnotesin circulationduringthistimeconsistedof£1,£5,£10,£20,£50,£100,£200,£500and£1000. 72 (Capie,Collins,&InstituteofEconomicAffairs.,1992,p.68) 73 (Wilson,1995,p.189) 74 (Capieetal.,1992,p.68) 75 (Capieetal.,1992,p.68) DateEnacted 1964 StampDutyon Transfersof Financial Securities Restrictionson Lendingin Foreign Currency post-WWII 1963 Cutsecuritiestransfertaxfrom2%to1%to encourageinternationalfinancialactivityin 77 theCityofLondon post-WWII Oct.1963 Chancellorannouncesthatforeigncurrency 78 loans‘allowedalmostwithoutrestriction’ Taxeson Bearer Securities post-WWII 1963 Reducedfrom6%ofnominalvalueto3%and 2%ofthemarketvalueforresidentsandnon79 residents,respectively Registered SecuritiesTax DollarPool post-WWII 1963 80 Ratereducedfrom2%to1% WWII post-WWII Bank advances-togovernment debtratio Restrictionson forward exchange (forexoptions) WWII post-WWII WWII post-WWII 76 Repealed/ Reduced Description post-SecondWorldWar BankofEnglandestablishedloanpriorities whichgavepreferencetoexportsand 76 discouragedspeculation Policy ExportLending Requiredthatmembersdeposittheirexcess U.S.dollarsandgoldatBankofEngland Reductioninbankadvances-to-government debtratiosothatbankscouldholdmore governmentdebt RestrictionsonUKBanksdealinginforward exchangeincluded:i)a“genuinecommercial contractisinexistence”;ii)“itisnotaswap” butan“outrightpurchaseorsaleof exchange”;iii)“thematuritydatemustnotbe morethanfourmonthsahead”.Some exceptionswereallowedbytheBankof England“whensuchapracticeisanormaland 81 necessaryfacilityofthetradeinquestion”. (Capieetal.,1992,p.68) (Quennouëlle-Corre&Cassis,2011,p.225) 78 (Quennouëlle-Corre&Cassis,2011,p.225) 79 (Quennouëlle-Corre&Cassis,2011,p.226) 80 (Quennouëlle-Corre&Cassis,2011,p.226) 81 C260.3p.1,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,9October,1945 77 Policy FixedExchange Rates DateEnacted 1936 Repealed/ Reduced 1973 Description Beginningwiththe1936Tripartiteagreement betweentheU.K.,FranceandtheU.S.and subsequentbilateralandmultilateral agreementsthoughSecondWorldWarand the1944BrettonWoodsagreement, exchangeratesweremanagedsothatforeign exchangecouldonlybelegallyconvertedat officialexchange. RegardingtheefficacyofthepolicieshighlightedbyReinhartandSbrancia,evenwith exchangerestrictionsBritainexperiencedsignificantcapitaloutflowstotheSterlingArea,which callsintoquestionjusthoweffectivecapitalrestrictionswereduringthistime.Dow(1964) claimsthat20%ofcapitaloutflowswereduetotheloosenessofcontrols.82Therearealso frequentreportsinarchivaldocumentsofgoldtradeoccurringdespiteofrestrictionsinthe Londonmarket.Forexample,inaletterdated30January,1947fromMr.WernerKnokeatthe NewYorkFederalReserveBank(NYFRB)tohiscounterpartandfrequentcorrespondentatthe BankofEngland,Mr.GeorgeBolton,KnokeinquiresabouttheLondongoldtransactionsthat are: “carriedonaverysubstantialscalewearetold,forinstancebySamuelMontagu,who purchasesthegoldallovertheworld,shippingitdirectlyorviaLondonforsalein marketslikeChina,theNearEast,etc.?”83 SamuelMontaguwastheproprietorforSamuelMontagu&Co,whichwasoneofthesix ‘AuthorisedDealers’ingoldotherthantheBankofEngland.84Inareplydated13February, 1947,BoltoninformsKnokethat“beforethewarLondonwasaninternationalcentreforgold arbitrageandwearethereforeundergreatpressuretoallowLondonfirmstoparticipateinthe 82 (Dow&NationalInstituteofEconomicandSocialResearch.,1964,p.24;CatherineR.Schenk,2010)Forfurther discussionontheeffectsandeffectivenessofcapitalcontrolssee(Dulles,1929,pp.226-227;Edwards,1999;B.J. Eichengreen,1998;Montiel&Reinhart,1999) 83 C261,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,30January,1947 84 TheotherauthorizedLondonbullionbanksatthistimewereJohnsonMatthey&Co.Ltd,Mocatta&Goldsmid, Pixley&Abbell,N.M.Rothschild&Sons,andSharps&Wilkins.C261p.2,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive, 10February,1947 business”.85HegoesontosaythatthereareexceptionstotheUKrulesagainstgoldownership, including: “anypersonnotresidentintheUnitedKingdomorthosepartsoftheSterlingArea whichprohibittheholdingofgoldbyresidents,mayowngoldintheUnitedKingdom” andclaimthatanytradeinthevarious“freemarkets”ofgoldatpremiumtotheofficial “doesnotnecessarilydamagethemajorcurrencies”.86 WhiletheUKofficiallyposedrestrictionsontheexportofgold,importationwas encouragedasitservedtoenhanceLondon’sstatusasafinancialcapitalandincreasedthe likelihoodthatitmaybeofferedforsale(orotherwisemadeavailable)toagold-strappedBank ofEngland.Boltonalsospeaksofthe“handsomeprofit”thatcanbeearnedinthegold arbitragetrade,wheregoldispurchasedat$43perounce,claimingthat: “noirreparableharmresultsfromthesaleoftherelativelysmallgoldproductionof LatinAmericainthevarious‘freemarkets’atasubstantialpremium.Itfeedsahoarding demandcausesaminorwaveofdisturbanceandmanyconsequentialreactionsbut, whileitunderliestheweaknessofcertainpapercurrencies.”87 However,thistrademayhavealsoincreasedtheopportunityforspeculationandprofiteering atblackmarketrates.Inamemodated2July,1947,theNYFRBconfrontedtheBankofEngland abouthow“FranckofSamuelMontaguandGoldsmidofMocatta&Goldsmidseemedthemost activefactorsinthepremiumgoldmarket”.Bolton,inhisreplytoKnoke,saidhe“wouldtryto keeptheminline”.88 ThisaboveexchangebetweenBoltonandKnokeonthesubjectoffreemarketgold tradeisoneofseveralfoundinboththeNYFRBandBankofEnglandarchivalrecordsonthis subject.Whilethecorrespondencegenerallyimpliesacloserelationshipbetweenofficials, 85 C261p.2,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,10February,1947 C261p.1,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,10February,1947 87 C261p.2,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,10February,1947 88 C261p.2,PeterLangrecordoftelephoneconversationwithMr.Bolton,BankofEngland,NewYorkFederal ReserveBankArchive,2July,1947 86 differencesofbothopinionandfactsfrequentlyemerge.Forexample,Knoketakesissuewith Bolton’sclaimthatgoldissellinginNewYorkat$43anounce,stating“wehavenotsunksolow astohave(black)marketatthiscountryat$43!!!”89PeraNYFRBmemo,aclaimmadebyLord CattooftheBankofEnglandthatBritain“disapprovesofthesalesofgoldontheblackmarkets inGreece”isdoubtedinsidetheFederalReserve.NYFRBheadSproulconveystoKnokethat“it hasalwaysbeenmyunderstandingthatinGreecetheBritishhadbeentheonesanxiousto makesovereignsavailableforsalethere”.90 Atothertimes,typicallyontheeveofacrisis,apalpabletensionemergesbetweenthe BankofEnglandandNYFRB.Forexample,on17June,1947,shortlybeforethesterling convertibilitycrisis,Knokespokewithan“audiblydisturbed”Boltonwhocomplainedthatthe NYFRBwasbeing“unnecessarilylegalistic”ona“questionconcerningthewholeconstitutional positionbetweentheBritishTreasuryandBankofEngland”withregardtoarequestbythe BankofEnglandforanuncollateralizedloan.ThepriorcustomattheNYFRBhadbeentosecure loanswithgoldonhandinthebasementsafe,andtheBritishgovernmenthadpreviously informedtheNYFRBthatallgoldonhandwasthepropertyofthegovernment,nottheBankof England.91 Knokealsoemphasizesthe“seriousmonetaryconsequencesifdealingsingoldat unofficialandvaryingpricesshouldbecomewidespread”.92Freemarketsingoldandcurrencies wereaseriousconcernonbothsidesoftheNorthAtlantic,andthereappearstobeaquidpro quo,whereMr.BoltonoftheBankofEnglandwould“appreciatekeepinghiminformedofany unusualdevelopmentsinthesterlingmarkethere(NewYork)”,andviceversaontheFederal Reserve’sinterestinLondonfreegoldactivity.Overall,amplearchivalevidenceindicatesthat significantgoldtradewasoccurringinLondon,andthatthistradewouldhaveundercutthe impactofBritishfinancialrepression.Londonplayedacriticalroleinmanagingtheglobalgold 89 C261p.2,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,18February,1947 C261p.1,LetterfromSproultoKnoke,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,6March,1947 91 C261p.1,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,17June,1947 92 C261p.2,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,18February,1947 90 market,throughlocally-headquarteredSouthAfricanmininginterests,aswellthroughthe relationshipwiththeSouthAfricangovernmentthatpurchasedalllocallyminedgoldatparity.93 However,incontrasttoBritain’sfocusonfreesterlingtradeinNewYork,theAmericanswere theoneswhowereprimarilyconcernedaboutfreetradeingold.TheNYFRBwantedBritain’s helpto“smashthepremiumbetweenfreemarkettransactionsbetweengoldandthedollar”, buttheFedalsorecognizedthat“itmightbemuchmoredifficulttosmashthepremiumin transactionsbetweengoldandthepoundsterling”.94PertheBrettonWoodsagreements,the U.S.dollarwastheonecurrencytiedatafixedratetothevalueofgold.BoltonandtheBankof England’spartialassurancesnotwithstanding,anytradeingoldatapremiumover$35per ounceofficialparitywasclearlyofsignificantconcerntotheU.S.governmentasitsuggested thattheU.S.dollarwasovervalued,fanningunwantedspeculationofofficialdevaluation. AsnotedbyCairncross(1985),capitalexportstotheSterlingAreawerenotfullyblocked until1972.95AsCairncross’analysishighlights,evenwiththeintroductionofthe1947Exchange ControlActtherewerecapitaloutflowsof£643million,orastaggering8%ofGDP.96Reinhart andSbranciaaresilentontheactualeffectofsuchcontrols. Financialrepressioniscomprisedofmanyinterrelatedcomponentsandcannotbefully appreciatedorunderstoodthroughjustthemeasurementofdebtliquidationandthelistingof ahandfulofpoliciesofuncertaineffect.Insum,whileReinhartandSbranciaaretheonly authorstodatetoattempttoquantifytheeffectsondebtofBritishfinancialrepressioninthe post-SecondWorldWarperiod,theirargumentthatBritainengagedinfinancialrepressionis nosufficientlysupported.Questionsremainoverwhetherfinancialrepressionwasaconscious policychoice,andwhatifanyalternativestofinancialrepressiondidcountriessuchasBritain possess.AndwithrespecttotheroleofBritishbanks,wasmoralsuasionsufficienttoenlist firmsintoaidinggovernment?Orwiththechangingpoliticalclimateandthedepartureafter 93 C261p.4,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,10February,1947 C261p.2,LetterfromJ.BurkKnappoftheFedBoardofGovernorstoWernerKnoke,NewYorkFederalReserve BankArchive,4March,1947 95 (Cairncross,1985,p.119) 96 (Cairncross,1985,pp.153-154) 94 twenty-fouryearsofthepowerfulcentralbankpersonalityofMontaguNorman,didcorralling theCitynowrequiretheimpositionofnewformalizededicts? Theremainderofthepaperisstructuredaroundseveralofthecoreareasofthe economywhichplayaroleindebtsustainabilityandfinancialrepression,includinginterest rates,capitalcontrols,andinstitutionssuchastheBankofEnglandandtheBritishbanking system. 4.2Interestrates Lownominalandnegativerealinterestratesaregenerallyconsideredtobeahallmark offinancialrepression.However,thequestionofwhatpreciselyconstitutea‘low’interestrate isunclear.97Whilethereisconsiderableroomforargumentoverwhatisandisnotanartificially lowinterestratethereislessdebateonthepoliciesandforcesthatmightcontributetolow ratesofinterestpaidbygovernmentsonpublicdebt. Inthe1940stheUKgovernmentsoughtandsecuredwhatitatleastconsideredtobe lowratesofinterestonpublicdebt.Knownas‘cheapmoney’,lowinterestrateshadbeen advocatedbyKeynesasearlyas1937andwasadoptedasacornerstoneofwartimecredit policy.98Britain’sfundingstrategyduringandafterthewarhasbeencharacterizedas‘heavy governmentborrowingatafixedrateofinterest’.99Exceptforabrieffluctuationatthe beginningofthewar,theBankofEngland’sBankRatewasmaintainedat2%through1951.100 Thelongendoftheyieldcurvewasmanagedtowardsthegoalofrunning‘a3percentwar’.101 97 Foradiscussionofthe‘worldinterestrate’conceptsee(Barro&Salaimartin,1990;Blanchard&Summers,1984; Chinn&Frankel,2005;Koedijketal.,1994;Lucas,1990;Yietal.,2001) 98 (Skidelsky,2000,pp.22,88)Keynespushedfor“permanentlycheapmoney”,saying“wemustavoid(dear money)…aswewouldhell-fire”TheTimes,12January,1937 99 (Cairncross,1985) 100 (Fforde,1992,p.92;R.S.Sayers,1981)BankRatehadbeenloweredtothe2%levelin1931. 101 (R.S.Sayers,1956) TheFirstandSecondWorldWarswerefinancedatfiveandthreepercentratesof interest,respectively,andtheSecondWorldWar’slowerrate“preventedathreefoldincrease intheinternalNationalDebt”fromFirstWorldWarlevelswhileleavingtheinterestburdenin 1945comparabletowhatitwasin1919.102WorswickandAdy(1952)explainthislowrateof interestinfinancialrepressiontermsbystating“solongastheexpenditureoftheprivatesector waslimitedbyrationingandothercontrols,incomerecipientswouldhavelittleelsetodowith alargepartoftheirearningsbuttolendittotheGovernment”.103Debtserviceexpense-to-GDP wasroughly8%and6%followingFirstandSecondWorldWars,respectively.104 Forcesthatcaused“the‘natural’rateofinteresttoberelativelyhigh”inBritainincluded inflationarypressures,alownaturalsavingsrate,andtheneedforcapitalexpenditures.105 InternaldocumentsfromtheBankofEnglandsupporttheviewofscholarsonthegoaloflow interestrates.Forexample,aBankofEnglandsurveymarkedconfidentialandtitled ‘DevelopmentsintheControlofCreditintheUnitedKingdom’sharedwiththeNYFRBon25 September,1952describeshow: “lowandstablelevelsofshort-terminterestrates,withconsequentlyeasycredit conditions,haditsoriginintheneedsofwarfinanceandwascontinued,andeven increased,inthepost-warperiodwiththedualobjectofkeepingdownthecostofthat nationaldebtandofmaintainingfullemploymentbyfacilitatingborrowingbyindustry andpublicbodiesalike.”(italicsdenoteemphasisadded)106 Post-warChancelloroftheExchequerHughDalton,whohasbeencharacterized simultaneouslyastheenemyofrentierandthefriendofthespeculator,wasnotcontentwith thealreadyhistoricallylowratesofinterest.107Daltonsoughtapolicyofevencheapermoney fromlate-1945through1947,openlystatinghisobjectiveto“bringdownthelong-termrateof 102 (Worswick&Ady,1952,pp.191-192) (Worswick&Ady,1952,pp.191-192) 104 (Buiter1985,p.17Figure2) 105 CV61p.2,Mr.KlopstocktoMr.Sproul,‘TheCheaper–MoneyPolicyinBritain–ALessonfortheUnitedStates”’, NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,7September,1948 106 C261Ap.1,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,25September,1952 107 (Paish,1947,1950) 103 interest”.108InJuly1947DaltontoldtheHouseofCommonsthat“cheapmoneyisto continue”.109OnefinancialinstrumentthatplayedakeyroleinDalton’sefforttodeliverlower interestrateswastheTreasuryDepositReceipt(TDRs),anewwartimeinventionthatallowed theTreasurytobypasstheLondonmoneymarketandborrowdirectlyfrombanks.110TDRswere veryunpopularwithbankersastheywerenon-marketableinstruments,meaningtheycould notbesoldontheopenmarketbutinsteadonlyexchangedforalosswiththeBankof England’sdiscountwindow.AsnotedbyWorswickandAdy,"bankerswouldhavewelcomeda reductioninthevolumeofgovernmentindebtedness,especiallyofTDRs."111 RatesonTDRswereoriginally1-1/8percent,aratethatDaltoninSeptember1945 slasheddownbynearlyinhalftojust5/8ofapercent.112AtthesametimeDaltonalsocutthe rateonT-Billsbyasimilaramountto1/2apercent.Thesetwochangesreducedthenominal interestburdenonfloatingdebtbyapproximatelyhalf.Daltonthenmovedtocutlonger-term ratesthroughanumberofconversionsandthefloatationofseveralissuesatarateof2.5%, includingtheTreasuryStock1975securities,whichthereaftercametobenon-affectionately referredtoinbankingcirclesas‘Daltons’.113 TheintellectualinspirationbehindtheDaltons,includingtheoriginalsuggestionofthe 2.5%rate,appearstobeKeynes.InhisGeneralTheoryKeynesstatedthatthatagovernment couldachieveitsinterestratetargetsifitletthemarketdeterminethetermstructure.114 KeynesoriginallyadvocatedthattheChancellorshouldannouncethatinnocircumstancewill 108 C261Dp.2,NYFRBResearchMemorandumtitled‘NotesontheNationalizationoftheBankofEngland’,New YorkFederalReserveBankArchive,19October,1952 109 CV61p.6,Mr.KlopstocktoMr.Sproul,‘TheCheaper–MoneyPolicyinBritain–ALessonfortheUnited States”’,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,7September,1948 110 (Howson,1988;Worswick&Ady,1952,pp.212-213) 111 WorswickandAdy(1952,p.198,214) 112 (Worswick&Ady,1952)TheauthorsprovidetwodifferentratesforTDRsonpp.198and214of5/8and7/8, respectively 113 (Worswick&Ady,1952,p.199) 114 (Booth,1989,p.157)InTheGeneralTheoryKeynesalsostates“Theremedyfortheboomisnotahigherrateof interestbutalowerrateofinterest!Forthatmayenabletheso-calledboomtolast.Therightremedyforthesocalledtradecycleisnottobefoundinabolishingboomsandthuskeepinguspermanentlyinasemi-slump;butin abolishingslumpsandthuskeepingusinapermanentboom.”(Keynes,1936,p.322) heborrowatmorethan2.5%solendershavezerodoubtsthatthesearethebestterms availableforlong-datedbonds.SkidelskysummarizesKeynes’positiononhowtoachievethis interestrateasfollows: “Inordertoenforcethisratethemarketshouldbegiven‘anincreasedamountof liquidity’topreventthe‘congestionofcredit’,whichKeyneshadwarnedin1938.Tobe effectivethesetechniqueswouldneedtobebuttressedbythefollowingthree elements:1)Controlofdomesticcapitalissues,2)Prioritizingtheuseofphysical resources(rationing),and3)anembargoonforeignlending(capitalcontrols).”115 Keynes,however,laterexpressedthat3%wastheappropriaterateatwhichthegovernment shouldborrowtoensuredemandandhepersonallyopposedtheissuanceofDaltons.116Asthe Daltonswerefloatedonthemarketthevalueoflonger-datedgiltissuesbegantosoften.Bythe timeCrippsreplacedDaltoninNovember1947yieldsonConsolshadclimbedbackupto3%, andwouldclimbfurtherto3.5%during1949.117Archivaldocumentsstatethatthisclimbin yieldswas“permitted”bytheUKTreasury,whichhad“rigged”theTreasurybondmarket throughtheuseofpublicdepartmentstopurchaseUKpublicdebt.118 Theuseofinterestratepolicy,throughchangesintheBankofEngland’sBankRate,was almostnon-existentduringthetwentyyearsprecedingtheToriesreturntopowerin1951. Previously,BankRatehadbeenraisedattimeswhenBritain’sreservesweredeclining.Upon thementioningofthisideaasapossiblemeansofaddressingthe1949devaluationcrisis, Daltonstated“IsayMontaguNormanwalksagain.Ithoughtwehadburiedallthisstuffabout BankRate”.119KeynesagreedwithDalton,addingthatthe“socialandpoliticalclimatewould notpermitarepeatoftherentier-friendlypolicyoftheFirstWorldWar”.120Skidelskydescribes 115 (Skidelsky,2000,pp.24-25) (Booth,1989,p.157) 117 (Worswick&Ady,1952,p.202)Anincreaseinbondyieldsreflectsadeclinethemarketvalueofthebonds. 118 CV61p.1,Mr.KlopstocktoMr.Sproul,‘TheCheaper–MoneyPolicyinBritain–ALessonfortheUnitedStates”’, NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,7September,1948 119 (Cairncross,1985,p.176)DouglasJay,EconomicSecretarytotheTreasury,isalsoquotedtothesameeffect. Daltoncouldn’tseethepointofhigherinterestratesbecausecapitalexpenses“isnotnowdeterminedbywhat peoplewantbutbywhatthegovernmentpermits”. 120 (Skidelsky,2000,p.69) 116 Keynes’“hatredoftherentier”,which“wasproofagainsteconomicarguments,becauseat bottomitwastheological,notscientific.Thebondholderishismindwasnothingbutthe medievalusurer,orShylock,someonewhosoughttomakeaprofitoutoflendingmoney.”121 November1951sawthefirstsustainedincreaseintheBankRate,whichwasincreased from2%to2-1/2%.WhatfollowedwasafairlydramaticincreaseinyieldsacrossUK governmentdebt,particularlyshort-datedissues,aswellasprivatesectorsecurities(Table7). TheeffectsoftheincreaseonBankRatewereseenmostdramaticallyontheshort-endofthe governmentyieldcurve,withyieldsonUKshort-dateddebtmorethandoublingfrom1.70%to 3.48%fromOctober1951toJuly1952.Yieldsonmedium-termandthelonger-termwarloan didnotseenearlyaslargeajump,increasingby21%and18%,respectively,whichwas approximatelyin-linewiththeriseseeninprivatesectorsecurities. 121 (Skidelsky,2000,p.69) Table7:AverageYieldofUKSecurities,1950-52 1950Avg. 1951YTDAvg. Oct.1951 Nov. Dec. Jan.1952 Feb. Mar. April May June July 1952YTDAvg. %ΔOct1951 toJuly1952 GovernmentDebtSecurities Short Medium 3-1/2% dated dated WarLoan 2.03% 2.99% 3.77% 1.84 3.59 3.98 1.70 3.66 4.06 1.97 3.78 4.18 2.29 4.08 4.35 2.36 4.14 4.37 2.41 4.17 4.42 2.92 4.31 4.54 3.15 4.24 4.50 3.26 4.27 4.56 3.51 4.45 4.75 3.48 4.42 4.78 3.01% 4.29% 4.56% 105% 21% 18% IndustrialSecurities Ordinary Debentures Shares 4.07% 5.48% 4.28 5.35 4.33 5.26 4.50 5.76 4.70 5.90 4.71 6.35 4.77 6.43 4.92 6.64 4.84 6.37 4.85 6.95 4.94 7.28 4.96 6.78 4.86% 15% 6.69% 29% Source:CV261Ap.4,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,25September1952 The‘Daltons’episodeandotherevidenceappearstohavedemonstrated,toatleast somedegree,theexistenceofa‘marketfloor’.Inotherwords,iftheBritishgovernment offereddebtatanominalinterestratedeemedtoolowbymarketparticipants,thenthe marketwasfreetosell-offBritishdebtinsufficientquantitiestocompelauthoritiestooffera higheryieldonnewbondissues.Forexample,thearchivalrecordsgoontostatethat: “Soonafterthedeclineofgilt-edgedpricesearlyin1947,themarketbecamethin, nervous,andanemic.Anylargeofferingthatinpreviousyearscouldhavebeeneasily absorbedcauseddigestivetroublesandjumpyreactions”.122 122 CV61p.4,Mr.KlopstocktoMr.Sproul,‘TheCheaper–MoneyPolicyinBritain–ALessonfortheUnited States”’,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,7September,1948 InOctober1947Daltonremarkedthat“theestablishmentofaneffective3percentgilt-edge yieldisnomorethanatemporarylapsefromthe2½percentobjective”.However,Dalton wouldbeprovenwrong.123 Theeffectsofmarketforcesonpublicdebtmarketsalsoexistedinthe1960s.ANYFRB studyhighlightshow“themarginbetween(UK)TreasuryBillratesandothershort-termratesis greaterherethanintheUnitedStates”(Table8).Thisfactsuggeststhatiffinancialrepression wasimpactinginterestratesinbothcountriestheimpactwaslessdramaticintheUKbythe early1960s.124 Table8:ComparisonofUKandU.S.InterestRates,September1964 Instrument UnitedKingdom UnitedStates TreasuryBills 5.50% 4.00% LocalAuthorityDeposits(UK)/FinancePaper(U.S.) 6.50% 4.25% FinanceHouseDeposits(UK)/CDs(U.S.) 7.00% 4.38% Source:CV61Ap.8,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,18October1965 TheNYFRBstudygoesontocommentthatintheUKthe“marketinlocalauthoritytemporary moneyhasprovidedforeigners,aswellasdomesticholders,withanattractivealternativeto theTreasurybill”,andthat“thelocalauthoritiesarecompetingforinstitutionalandprivate fundsnotonlyagainsttheGovernment(withitshighercreditrating),butalsoagainstthe financehousesandeachother”.125ThoselookingtoputcashtoworkearninginterestinLondon had“manymoreattractiveoutlets”thanintheU.S.126Bythelate-1950stheLondonEurodollar marketgenerallyofferedbankstheabilitytoearninterestat4%.127ThefactthatratesintheUK privatesectorremainedcompetitiveandabovepublicsectorratesofinterestonoffer,andthe 123 CV61p.6,Mr.KlopstocktoMr.Sproul,‘TheCheaper–MoneyPolicyinBritain–ALessonfortheUnited States”’,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,7September,1948 124 CV61Ap.8,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,18October1965 125 CV61App.11,8.NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,18October1965 126 CV61Ap.16,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,18October1965 127 CV61Ap.17,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,18October1965 lackofcompressionbetweenthedifferentUKinstrumentscomparedtotheU.S.marketplace, underminesclaimsthattheUKinterestratesoperatedunderaregimeofstrictfinancial repression. Insum,thesefindingsaresomewhatatoddswiththeportrayalofpost-warBritish financialrepressionasaregimewithabsolutecontroloverinterestrates,oranerawhere investorshadfewinvestmentoptions.Indeed,therewasasignificantspreadinyieldsacrossa varietyofdifferentdebtsecuritiesavailableforinvestmentpurposes.Thisevidencehighlights theimportanceofdistinguishingbetweendifferenttypesanddegreesoffinancialrepression.In otherwords,whilemoralsuasionandqualitativetechniquesmayhaveencouragedbanksto holdlonger-termBritishdebt,othereconomicactorsintheUKhadavarietyofinvestment optionsoutsidelow-yieldinggovernmentsecurities. 4.3Capitalandexchangecontrols Alongsidelowinterestrates,capitalcontrolsaretypicallyconsideredacornerstoneof financialrepression.128AsnotedbyinternalarchivaldiscussionsbetweentheBankofEngland andFederalReserve,“thewarhasdiminishedconfidenceinpapercurrencies”andcontrols wereseenasonemeansto“avoidtherealdangerofabreakdownorcollapseofsocial institutionsandpoliticalstructure”.129Thestringentcontrolsimposedatthebeginningof SecondWorldWarlaidthegroundworkfortheSterlingArea.130 Anexampleofonepolicydesignedtocontrolthemovementofcapitalwasthe requirementthatpermissionfromauthoritiesbeobtainedpriortomakinganyforex 128 See(Aizenman,Gavin,&Hausmann;Alesina,Grilli,&Milesi-Ferrett,1993;Alexander,Enoch,Baliño,& InternationalMonetaryFund.,1995;Wyplosz,1986,2001)Inrecenttimesithasbeensuggestedthatlowinterest ratesaretheonlyrequirementoffinancialrepressionasothermechanisms,suchasquantitativeeasing,have replacedtheneedforstringentcapitalcontrols. 129 C261p.1,LetterfromSproultoKnoke,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,6March,1947 130 (Capie,2010,p.146;DeVegh&ScudderStevens&Clark.,1939)ForafurtherdescriptionoftheSterlingArea see(R.Harrod&PrincetonUniversity.DepartmentofEconomicsandSociology.InternationalFinanceSection., 1952) purchases.131Keynesarguedagainstclosingdownthestockexchangestatingthat,withforeign exchangecontrolsandaprohibitiononnewsecuritiesissuance,allsavingswouldbeaccessible bytheTreasury,thereby“makingcheapborrowingeasy”forthegovernment.132Indeed,in 1913domesticindustryonlycomprised8%ofissuesquotedontheLondonStockExchange. However,thefigurewouldrisetoandremainover90%fromthelate1940sonwardascapital exports“remain(ed)inthedoldrums”.133AnotherelementofBritishcapitalcontrolswerethe restrictionsonforeignexchangeonpaymentsmadeoutsidetheSterlingArea,whichwere imposedattheoutbreakofwarandmaintainedwellintopeacetime. FollowingtheconclusionofthewarKeynesfeltthat“nothingismorecertainthanthat themovementofcapitalfundsmustberegulated”.134TheBankofEnglandinitiallysoughtto tracehowsomuchsterlinghadwoundupinforeignmarketssuchasNewYork,andcomplex ruleswereestablishedonhowandbywhomsterlingcouldbeexchangedfordollars.135The ExchangeControlActwaspassedin1947,whichhadtheeffectofrestrictingsomeexternal loansaswellasinwardcapitalflows.136ThisactwasnotrepealeduntilOctober1979.137 However,persistentcapitalleakageswereanongoingconcernforpolicymakersinspiteof controls.ByApril1940Keynesestimatedleakagesof£100Msincethestartofthewar.U.S. dollars,whichtheTreasurywasseekingtoraise,wereleakingthroughLondon’sallowancefor non-residentstosellBritishsecuritiesfordollars.ThiscausedKeynesto‘goonthewarpath’to enforcecapitalcontrols;othersintheTreasurywerenotinfavourofactionduetoconcern aboutthelossesofforeignbalancesheldinLondon.138 131 (Cairncross&Eichengreen,1983,p.24) (Skidelsky,2000,p.79) 133 (Wilson,1995,p.188) 134 (Skidelsky,2000,p.205)TheBankofEnglandalsofavouredcapitalcontrols(p.210) 135 C261p.1,BankofEnglandlettertoNYFRB’sMr.Knoke,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,7December, 1945 136 (Cairncross&Eichengreen,1983,p.22) 137 (C.M.Reinhart&Sbrancia,2011,p.17) 138 (Skidelsky,2000,pp.75-76) 132 Asnotedearlierinthepaperduringthediscussionofthefreegoldmarket,thereis somequestionastotheoveralleffectivenessofcapitalcontrols.Further,incertainareasthe exportofcapitalwasnotprohibitedatall.Forexample,Sophisticatedmarketsfor‘free’sterling blossomedinNewYorkandSwitzerland.Inaddition,capitalexportswereallowedwithinthe SterlingAreaupuntil1972atwhichpointexchangecontrolwasapplied.139Dow(1964) estimatesthat20%ofcapitaloutflowswereduetothe‘looseness’ofcontrols(leakages).140The regulationsandrulesgoverningtheSterlingAreaandthemovementofcapitalwere,put simply,complex.Varyingdegreesoftransferabilityofcurrencyanddifferentformsofsterling, manyofwhichhaduniqueexchangeratesandseparaterulesabouthowthecurrencycouldbe used,madeforaconfusingregulatoryenvironment.141AsnotedbytheFederalReserveBoard ofGovernors,sterling’sstatusvariedfromplacetoplace,serving“asahardcurrencyforthe BelgiansbutasoftcurrencyfortheIndians”.142 TheBritishgoldmarketwasclosedintheearlystagesofSecondWorldWaranddidnot officiallyreopenuntil1954.143Regulationgovernedtheexportofgold,andBritishcitizens residingpermanentlyinBritainwereprohibitedfromowninggoldnotmadeintojewellery. However,Britishcitizensresidingpermanentlyinacountrywhichdoespermitpersonalgold ownership(e.g.,France)couldowngold.DuringthisperiodseveralLondongolddealers establishedsubsidiariesinCanada,Beirut,HongKongandSouthAfricawhiletheLondon marketwasclosed.144Whatisnotentirelyclearfromareviewoftheliteratureandarchival materialsiswhateffectinpracticetheclosureoftheLondongoldmarketactuallyhadonflows. Inotherwords,iftheBritishbullionbanks–Rothschild,MocattaandGoldsmid,etal–werestill largelyabletooperate,astheNYFRBclaimed,didtheclosureoftheLondongoldmarkethelp 139 (Cairncross,1985,p.119) (Dow&NationalInstituteofEconomicandSocialResearch.,1964,p.24) 141 (Pick,1953)Someofthemanynamesgiventothedifferentversionsofsterlinginclude:cheap,free,overseas, external,blackmarket,Handpayments,etc. 142 C261p.2,LetterfromJ.BurkKnappoftheFedBoardofGovernorstoWernerKnoke,NewYorkFederalReserve BankArchive,4March,1947 143 (C.M.Reinhart&Sbrancia,2011) 144 (Green,1968,p.115)Seealso(Green,1973,1981) 140 achievetheBritishobjectiveofminimizingthedrainofgoldreserves?Theseandrelated questionsmaywarrantfurtherresearch.145 Britainwasnotaloneinestablishinggreatercontrolovercapitalandforeignexchange. FollowingtheSecondWorldWaranelaboratesetoffinancialrestrictions,interestratecaps, andcapitalcontrolsremainedineffectinadvancedeconomiesuntilthe1970s-1980s,atwhich pointwidespreadfinancialliberalizationwaspursuedacrossmuchofthenon-communist world.TheUKhadahigherdegreeofcontrolsinplaceonitscurrentaccountfrom1950-1980 (Figure1).Britain’sdegreeofcapitalaccountopennessfluctuatedbothaboveandbelowthe sampleaverageduringthistime(Figure2).146 145 Unfortunately,awarehousefiredestroyedmuchofthearchivalmaterialthatwasheldbyRothschildaboutthe Londongoldmarketduringthisperiod,soitisnotclearwhatarchivalmaterialsmayexist. 146 (Obstfeld&Taylor,2004,pp.160-171;D.Quinn,1997;D.P.Quinn&Toyoda,2008) Figure1:Current-accountopenness,1950-2004 (100=moreopen) 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 Sample UK Figure2:Capital-accountopenness,1950-2004 (100=moreopen) 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 Sample UK Note:samplecountriesincludes:Australia,Austria,Belgium,Denmark,Ireland,Italy,Finland,Germany,Greece, France,Japan,NewZealand,Netherlands,Portugal,Spain,Sweden,andSwitzerland. Sources:Quinn(1997),QuinnandToyoda(2008) 4.4Bankingsystem “Thecommercialbankingsystemistobefitted,asanintegralpart,intowhatpromises tobeagreaterdegreeofcentralorganizationoftheBritisheconomythanhasever existedinthepast”. -Anonymous,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive147 BeforeexploringtheparticularsoftheroleplayedbyBritishbankinginpost-Second WorldWarfinancialrepressionitusefultodiscussthehistoryandstructureoftheBritish financialsystem.Onthewhole,theBritishbankingandfinancialsystemhasproven comparativelystable.148Whilenotimmunefromproblems(e.g.,the1890Baring’scrisis)the buoyancyofBritishbankscomparesfavourablywithothercountriesduringperiodsof economicdistress.Forexamples,inthe1930sU.S.banksfailedenmasse(thousands)whilefar fewerBritishbanksfailed(bothinabsolutetotalnumberandasapercentageofthenumberof banksinexistenceatthetime).149 SincetheBaringscrisis,theBankofEnglandhadacceptedfinancialresponsibilityforthe principalmerchantbanks.TheBankwaswillingtobuymerchantbankacceptancesinthe marketwithoutformallimit.PrincipalmerchantbanksheldaccountsattheBankandwere membersoftheAcceptingHousesCommittee(AHC),formedin1914.AllAHCmemberswerea liabilityoftheBankofEngland,whichassistedmerchantbanksin1939(asin1931and1914) whenstandstillsoccurred.OnefurtherreasonfortherelativestabilityofBritishbanksduring thisperiodwasduetothestructureoftheBritishfinancialsystem,particularlytheclearlinesof demarcationbetweeninstitutionsthatcouldengageindifferentfinancialfunctions. Restrictionskeptdiscount,merchantandclearingbanksoutofeachother’slinesofbusiness.150 Ittookthe1933U.S.Glass-SteagallAct,whichrequiredthatseparatecompaniesperformthe 147 CV61Ap.3,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,1946 (Fforde,1992,p.749) 149 (Bemanke&James,1991,pp.51-55;Grossman,1994;Wicker,2001) 150 (Capie&CityUniversity.CentreforBankingandInternationalFinance.CentrefortheStudyofMonetary History.,1987;D.T.Llewellyn,1985;DavidT.Llewellyn,1985,p.10)Seealso(Fforde1992,p.758) 148 functionofmanagingdeposits,investmentbanking,andinsurance,tocreatewhatalready informallyexistedinBritain. DidthegreaterrelativefinancialstabilityenjoyedbytheBritishbankingsystemgohandin-handwithhavinganoligopolisticbankingindustry?TheBritishbanking‘cartel’,asithasbeen sometimesreferred,formedinthelate19thcenturyandhasfurtherconsolidatedthroughthe presentday.151WhiletheBankofEnglandsteppedintoarrangemergers(e.g.,Governor Norman’scoordinationofthemergerbetweentheRoyalBankofScotlandandWilliams DeaconsBank),mergersandfurtherindustryconsolidationbyLondon’sBigFivecleaningbanks waseschewedbytheBankofEnglandgiventheoligopolisticnatureofBritishbanking.152The BankofEnglandcertainlytooktheviewthatlowcompetition,whilereducingefficiency,ledto higherstability. TheBankofEnglandalsofounditeasiertodealwitharelativelysmallnumberofbanks, whichmayhaveplayedanimportantroleinthestate’sabilitytoinfluencethecompositionof bankbalancesheets.Indeed,anarchivaldocumentfromanNYFRBstudyshowshowamuch greatershareofUKTreasuryBillsareheldbytheUKbankingsystemascomparedtotheUnited Statesbankingsystem.153ThestudygoesontodiscusshowbythistimeUKTreasurybills“now fulfilthefunctiononceperformedbycommercialbills”asameansforBritishbankstoconvert liquidassetsintocash,underscoringtheimportanceintheshiftfromprivateinstrumentsof credittopubliccreditinbankoperationsandtheLondonbillmarket.However,therewas arguablyatrade-offbetweenstabilityandlowerefficiency,whichcanbeseenintherelatively highcash/depositandliquidityratiosof8%and28-30%,respectively.154 151 (Strange&RoyalInstituteofInternationalAffairs.,1971,p.162) (Capie,2010,p.327)TheBigFiveLondonClearingbanksduringthistimewere:Midlands,Barclays,Lloyds, NationalProvincialandWestminster. 153 ThiswastrueinspiteofthefactthattheUKandU.S.Treasurybills“fundamentallyalike”instructureCV61Ap. 1,18October1965,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive 154 (Capieetal.,1992,p.69) 152 The‘specialrelationship’betweentheBankofEnglandandLondon’sclearingbanks allowedtheirprofitsandlossestobekeptfromthepublic(aswellastheBankofEngland).155As notedbyFforde(1992): “Thespecialrelationshipwiththebankwasfarmorethanthatofsupervisorand supervised.Itisunlikelythatthosewordswereeverused.Itwasmorelikearelationship betweenpartners,eachpossessingsomedegreeofcontrolovertheother.Itwasall veryinformal.”156 Britishbanksweregivenaspecialdegreeoflatitudebytheirregulator,theBankofEngland,in theformofpracticessuchasthemaintenanceofhiddenreserves.157Thehiddenreservesof Britishbankscloudthequestionofwhatpreciselywerebankprofitsduringthisperiod,and somequestionableclaimsarefoundintheliteratureregardingBritishbankprofitability.For example,WorswickandAdy(1952)describebonddealingsforbanksas“highlyprofitable”.158 However,theydonotprovidesufficientdetailsonhowtheeffectsofinflationmayhaveeroded therealvaluethebondsheldbyBritishbanks. Flexiblearrangementsondisclosureandliquidity,alongwithrestrictionsoncompetition andsomewhatguaranteedmarketshare,couldhelpexplainwhybanksacquiescedtothe substantialreductionseeninthevalueoftheirpublicdebtholdings.Forexample,inthepostwarperiodthedepositreserveratioforUKbankswasrelaxedfrom10%ofdepositsrequiredto bekeptinnotesandcoininreservetojust8%.159Britishbanksdidnotcloselyadheretothe definedminimumrequirementthat30%ofBritishbankliabilitiesbeheldin‘liquid’assetssuch asTreasurybills,commercialbills,andTreasurydepositreceipts.160Furtherexaminationofrates ondepositsatBritishbankscouldbeuseful.AsnotedbyReinhartandReinhart(1999),“banks passthereserverequirementscomponentofthefinancialrepressiontaxontodepositorsvia 155 (R.S.Sayers,1976,pp.552-560) (Fforde1992) 157 (Capie,2010,pp.445,591;Capieetal.,1992,pp.68-69) 158 (Worswick&Ady,1952,p.215) 159 C261Ap.1,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,25September,1952 160 C261Ap.1,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,25September,1952 156 lowerdepositratesand/ornon-governmentborrowersviahigherlendingrates.Thismix betweenthetwodependsuponwhichhasaccesstomorealternatives”.161 SignificantchangecametotheBankofEnglandinthemid-1940s.First,in1944,after servingfor24years,GovernorMontaguNormansteppeddownatage72.TheninAugust1946, theeraofbankregulationreferredtoasthe"theworldofthe'Governor'seyebrows”,cameto anendwhenthe‘OldLadyofThreadneedleStreet’wasnationalizedundertheBankofEngland Act.162AsnotedbyFforde(1992),theBank’s: “relationswithWhitehallandtheCitywereclearenoughinbroadoutline,but ofteninformal,unmodified,anduncertainonthemargins.Maintenanceofthe authorityoftheBank,togetherwithcontroloverthedirectioninwhichitmoved, thereforedependedunusuallyonthesupremacyoftheGovernor.”163 Thisinformalarrangementchangedwhencontroversialclauses4(3)and4(4)ofthe nationalizationactwereadopted,whichformalizedtheBank’srelationshipwithTreasury. WherepreviouslytheBankhademployedmoralsuasion,clause4(3)gavetheBank,withthe approvaloftheTreasury,explicitpowertogoverntheproportionofcommercialbankassets.164 TheformalizationofthispowerandtheadditionoftheTreasuryinthedecisionmaking frameworkonthemixofassetsbankswouldholdcanbeviewedasasignificantadvancement offinancialrepression.Oneofthecoreelementsoffinancialrepressionistheabilityfor governmenttomandatethecompositionoffirmbalancesheetstoensurethegovernmentdebt isheld,andclause4(3)and4(4)formalizedthegovernment’sauthorityinthisregard.These sectionsallowedtheTreasuryto: 161 (C.Reinhart&Reinhart,1999) (Capie,2010,p.590) 163 (Fforde,1992) 164 (Fforde,1992,p.7) 162 “requestinformationfromandmakerecommendationstobankers,andmay,ifso authorizedbytheTreasury,issuedirectionstoanybankerforthepurposeofsecuring thateffectisgiventoanysuchrequestorrecommendation.”165 Indeed,statementsfromboththeMidlandsandWestminsterbankchairmencondemnedthe adoptionofclause4(3)andrepresentoneoftheonlyinstancesfoundintheliteratureofan objectiontoBritishfinancialrepressionpoliciesbybankers.166However,itwasstatedthat “certainsafeguardstobankersandcustomersareprovidedfor”,suchasthe“rightofbankers tomakepriorrepresentationswiththeBankofEnglandandtheTreasurybeforethe‘directions’ areissuedtothem”.167AnoteintheNewYorkFederalReservearchivesrecordsaquote summarizingDalton’sviewonthenewpowerhierarchybetweenBritishbanksandthe government:“inthelastresort…asamatterofprinciple,iftherebeaseriouscaseofconflictor challenge,theBankofEnglandmustbemasterandtheleaderoftheclearingbanks”.168As notedbyWorswickandAdy,“thusthebankingsystemwasausefulinstrumentinthehandsof adeterminedChancellor.”169 WhatultimatelywastheimpactofthenewBankofEnglandcontrolclausesand nationalization?Therearereferencestothegovernment’sshareoftheoverallbusiness handledbybanksincreasingsignificantlyfollowingthewar.170Itisunclearhowmuchthe establishmentofthisclauseimpactedbankassets.171Theliteratureonlyaddressestheprocess whichledtotheAct’spassage,andWorwisckandAdystate“noinstanceofitsusehasbeen publicized”.172Incontrast,archivalevidencepointstosignificantinfluencebytheUKTreasury onbankbalancesheets.Forexample,thepreviouslycited1952BankofEnglandstudyoncredit controlstatesthatthebanks: 165 C261Dpp.19,NYFRBResearchMemorandumtitled‘NotesontheNationalizationoftheBankofEngland’,New YorkFederalReserveBankArchive,19October,1952 166 (Fforde,1992,p.7) 167 C261Dpp.19,NYFRBResearchMemorandumtitled‘NotesontheNationalizationoftheBankofEngland’,New YorkFederalReserveBankArchive,19October,1952 168 CV61Ap.3,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,1946 169 (Worswick&Ady,1952,p.217) 170 (InstituteofBankers.,1949) 171 (Fforde,1992)SeeCh.1(pp.1-30) 172 (Worswick&Ady,1952,p.218) “madeeveryefforttocomplywiththerequestsofsuccessiveChancellorsofthe Exchequerthatcreditshould,asinwar-time,begrantedonlyforessentialpurposes, whichinthepost-warperiod,weretobejudgedinthelightofthecriterialaiddown fromtimetotimefortheguidanceoftheCapitalIssuesCommittee.Thus,thoughthe weaponsofquantitativecontrolofbankcreditcouldnotbeused,abroadqualitative controlwasmaintained.”173 Thisqualitativecontrolonbanklendingwassupplementedwiththereintroductionof quantitativemeasuresinNovember1951,namelythefirstsustainedincreaseinBankRatein nearly20years(from2%to2-1/2%).174Thereturntoquantitativemeasureswasinpartdriven bythefactthatthe“efficacy”ofqualitativemeansofcontrollingbankbalancesheets“was limited,inspiteofthecooperativeattitudesofthebanks”.175 Fromtheliteraturethereisalsoadiscussionofpressureonbankstosupport governmentbonds.Forexample,newdiscounthousesappeartohavebeenforcedtotakeona newroleofholdinggovernmentdebt.176TheaforementionedTreasuryDepositReceipts(TDRs) werealsounpopularamongbankers.177UKbankswererequiredtomaintainacertainratioof liquidassetsthatincludedTreasurybills,whichcontrastedwithU.S.banksthatonlyhadto keepcashanddeposits(butnotgovernmentdebt)withtheFederalReserve.178 Howmuchofthisrepresentedachangefromthepastisnotentirelyclear.Forsome timepriortonationalizationtheBankofEnglandwasdescribedbysomeas“littlemorethana handmaidenoftheTreasury”.179DuringtheSecondWorldWarBritishbankstookonall 173 C261Ap.2,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,25September,1952 C261Ap.2,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,25September,1952 175 C261Ap.2,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,25September,1952.Thememorandumgoesontonote that“thegenerouscompensationtobegiventoprivateownersofpresent(BankofEngland)stock,havealsodone muchtodampenoppositionoftheBill”. 176 (Worswick&Ady,1952,p.215)"Itwasmadeclearthataslongastheywerepreparedtoactasgenuinejobbers -thatis,tobuytocapacityonfallingmarkets-theauthoritieswouldsupporttheirliquidity." 177 (R.S.Sayers,1953) 178 Source:CV61Ap.20,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,18October1965 179 Source:CV61p.1,ResearchMemorandumonthe‘ProsandConsofBankofEnglandNationalization’,NewYork FederalReserveBankArchive,22December1945 174 governmentdebtnotpurchasedbythepublic.Britishbanks’advanceratio(the%ofassets allottedtoloansandoverdrafts)droppedfromthepeacetimelevelof50%to15%,indicatinga largeshiftawayfromprivatesectorloansinfavourofgovernmentdebt.Theadvanceratiodid notreturntothepeacetimelevelasquicklyasithadafterFirstWorldWar,takinguntilthe 1960sfortheratiotoreturnto40%.180Ashiftbybanksawayfromprivatesectorloansin favourofgovernmentdebtisacommonfeaturefinancialrepressionpolicy.Thebankscould discounttheirT-billswiththeBankofEnglandforanycashthatwasneeded,andbywar’send Britain’smoneysupplyhaddoubled.181 AfterthewarBritishbankswereswimminginliquiditywithlargedepositbasesand liquidassets,andthecomparativelyhighlevelofliquiditypossessedbythebankspersistedwell intothe1950s.182TheDaltonpolicyof‘cheapmoney’initiallyledtoariseinthevalueofstocks andgilts.183However,bondpricesdiddeclinelaterbyasignificantmarginfollowingthe introductionofthe2.5%‘Daltons’.Theclearingbanksinparticularwererequiredtokeepon theirbalancesheetsalargepercentageofgovernmentsecuritiesduetothe“subjugationof bankbehaviourtotheperceivedgreaterneedsofgovernmentfinance”.184Afterthewar,banks weretryingtorebuildtheiradvances-governmentdebtratio.Atthesametimeauthoritieswere tryingtosellmoredebtandcapandorslowgrowthinbankadvances.185Forexample,archival documentsdescribeaUKgovernment“fundingoperation”inNovember1951,supportedby thebanksand“importantoverseasholdersofTreasuryBills”,whereby£1billioninUKTreasury Billswereexchangedfor1-3/4%SerialFundingStockmaturingin1952,1953,and1954.186The effectofthisfundingoperationwasto“sharply”reducetheliquidassetsoftheclearingbanks sothat“shouldtheneedarise”thebanksclearingbanks“wouldberelativelysusceptibleto pressure”bytheBankofEnglandonthecompositionoftheirbalancesheet. 180 th (Capieetal.,1992,p.64)Ratioofadvancestototalassetsatcommercialbanksinthelate19 centurywere 60%,50%intheinterwarperiod,and16%in1944. 181 (Fforde,1992,p.7) 182 (Capieetal.,1992,p.64) 183 (Worswick&Ady,1952,p.194) 184 (Capieetal.,1992,pp.67-68) 185 (Capie,2010,pp.80-81) 186 C261Ap.5,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,25September,1952 ThereisalargeacademicliteratureonLondon’sbanks.However,thereisverylittleto nodiscussionofthepoliciesorsentimentsoftenassociatedwithfinancialrepressioninthe bankingliteraturecoveringthisperiod.Forexample,Burk’s(1989)historyofMorganGrenfell,a leadingAnglo-Americanmerchantbank,focusesonpersonalitiesandtransactions,butdoesnot referencefinancialrepression.187ThesameistrueofSayers’(1968)studyofGillets,which includestheyears1945-51.188Whilethisabsenceoffinancialrepressionfromtheliteraturemay inpartbeduetothefactthatmanyofthehistoriesonBritishbankswere‘official’,theprivate diariesofBritishmerchantbankerSiegmundWarburgalsodonotmentionfinancial repression.189OnenotableexceptiontothesilencefrombankersoccurredinJanuary1947, whenthechairmenoftheBigFiveclearingbanksurgedintheirannuallettersanendto Dalton’spolicyof‘cheapmoney’.190However,thegeneralabsenceofdiscordraisesquestions. BritishbankswouldholdlargequantitiesofBritishbondswellintothepost-warperiod(Table 9),andintheUK“amuchhigherproportionofthetotaloutstanding[Treasurybills]isinthe handsofthebankingsystem(includingdiscounthouses)thanitisintheUnitedStates”.191 Table9:InstitutionalComparisonofUKandU.S.TreasuryBillHoldings,30September1964 Sector UnitedKingdom UnitedStates Commercialbanksanddiscounthouses 50% 27% Foreignholders 42% 19% Otherholders 8% 54% Total 100% 100% Source:CV61Ap.10,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,18October1965 187 (Burk,1989) (R.S.Sayers,1968) 189 (Ferguson,2010) 190 (Worswick&Ady,1952,p.201)Anotherexampleofprotestwastheearliernotedcommentsbythechairmenof MidlandsandWestminstercondemningclause4(3)intheBankofEnglandAct(Fforde,1992,p.27). 191 CV61Ap.10,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,18October1965 188 Asnotedearlier,therealvalueofBritishbondsexperiencedasteadyandsubstantial declinefollowingSecondWorldWar.Onewouldexpectthatthepost-SecondWorldWar liquidationofthevalueofBritishdebtofperhapsunprecedentedproportionstogenerateat leastamentioninpassingfrombankers,whichinturnwouldbepickedupinthehistorical literature.Howcanthisapparentparadoxbeexplained?ItishardtoimaginethatBritishbanks werenotawareofthefactthattherealvalueoftheirBritishdebtholdingswasbeingeroded. Thereareatleastfourpossibilitiesthatcouldexplaintheparadoxbehindtheexistence ofBritishfinancialrepressionandtheabsenceofmentionintheliteratureandandby financiers:a)historicalresearchtodatehassimplyoverlookedthisaspectofBritishfinancial history;b)Britishbanksfoundawaytomitigatetheeffectsoffinancialrepression;c)afinancial repressionbargain,sotospeak,existedbetweenthebanksandtheauthorities;d)financial repression’seffectsweresmallenough,andstretchedoutoversufficienttime,toescape protest.Itistemptingtospeculatethatthelattertwoexplanationsarecorrectbasedwhatlater happenedtoBritishbanking.Themerchantbankswereconsideredtobethecrèmedelacrème oftheLondonbanks.However,onceLondon’sfinancialderegulatory‘BigBang’occurredmost ofLondon’smerchantbanksceasedtoexistasindependentgoingconcernsoverthenext severalyears.OftheoriginalmerchantsbanksonlyRothschildhasremainedanindependent entity.192Merchantbankshadbeenshelteredandsimplyfoundtheywerenolonger competitiveinaglobalizedfinancialmarket. 4.5Directedlending Directedlendingisacommonfeatureoffinancialrepression,andBritishgovernment departmentssuchastheNationalDebtCommissionersandthePostOfficeSavingsBankwere directedtosupportTreasurybondauctionsandtheoverallgovernmentbondmarket.Other agenciesthatsupportedgovernmentdebtmarketsincludedthetrusteesavingsbanks,the 192 KleinwortwasboughtbyDresdner.S.G.WarburgwaspurchasedbySwissBankCorp.(nowCreditSuisse). MorganGrenfellwasboughtbyDeutscheBank.Schroeder'swaspurchasedbyCitibank.Hambroswassoldto SociétéGénéralein1998.Baringsfailedin1995. socialinsurancefunds,theExchangeEqualizationAccountandtheIssuesDepartmentofthe BankofEngland.193Thesedepartmentswereoftenusedtosupportconversionsthrough advancebuyingofthesecuritytobeconverted,therebyhelpingtoensureasuccessful conversion. Daltonorchestrateddirectedlendingoperationswiththegoalofmanaginginterest rates.Lowinterestrateswereeffectedbyswappinghigherinterestratelong-termtermdebt withlowerinterestrateshort-termdebt,aswellbyunderwritingnewlower-interestrate issues.194BothWorswickandAdy(1952)andCairncross(1985)brieflydiscusstheseoperations. However,Cairncrossdescribedthemas“rumour”,whileWorswickandAdyrefertothe departmentsasthe“Treasury’screatures”thatwere“takinguptheslackonthoseissueswhich thepublicwouldnottake”.195Whiletheseoperationswereoriginallyconcealedfromthepublic archivaldocumentsrevealtheextentoftheseoperations.196ANewYorkFederalReservereport citesanotherreportbyaMr.Bloomfieldtitled“InterestRatePolicyinGreatBritain-1945-48” thatdescribestheeffectsofBritishdirectedlendingasfollows: “2½percentConsolsundertheimpactofvigorousbuyingbythepublicdepartments hadrisenbyNovember1946towithinapointofparity,thehighestlevelin44years, andthemarkethadbeensufficiently‘rigged’topermittheissueatpartofa2½per centTreasurystockredeemableafter1975attheTreasury’sdiscretion”(the ‘Daltons’).197 Comparingnon-bankprivatesectorinstitutionsintheU.S.andUK,weseethatin1963thatU.S. non-bankprivatesectorinstitutionsheldamuchlargerportionoftheirshort-termassetsin TreasuryBillsthanintheUK( 193 (Worswick&Ady,1952,p.197) (Worswick&Ady,1952,p.197) 195 (Cairncross,1985,pp.432-433;Worswick&Ady,1952,pp.196-198,215) 196 (Worswick&Ady,1952,pp.197,202)WorswickandAdyalsostatedthatitispossibletomakeaback-door calculationbymonitoringcreditcreation,particularlytheincreaseofdeposits.Theyalsonotethattheactivitiesof thedepartmentsdeclinedundertheCrippsChancellorship. 197 CV61p.1,Mr.KlopstocktoMr.Sproul,‘TheCheaper–MoneyPolicyinBritain–ALessonfortheUnitedStates”’, NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,7September,1948 194 Table10). Table10:PrivateSectorInstitutionalComparisonofUKandU.S.TreasuryBillHoldings,%of TotalShort-termAssetsheldinTreasuryBills,1963 Sector Insurancecompanies Corporatepensionfunds Mutualbanks Savingsbanks UnitedKingdom UnitedStates 2% 10% 1% 40% 0% 18% 0% 12% Source:CV61Ap.8,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,18October1965 U.S.companiesweregenerallyconsideredtobemuchmore‘liquid’thantheirUKcounterparts, withcurrentassetsof40%and22%,respectively.UKprivatesectorsinsurancecompanies, whenaskedbytheRadcliffeCommitteetoexplainthispreferenceforlonger-termsecurities, stated: “Wedonotwanttohavesecuritiesthatturnovertoorapidlyortoofrequently,suchas billsorshort-datedinvestments;wewouldratherhavesomethingwhichisgoingtobe thereforareasonableperiodoftime,forpurelyadministrativereasons”.198 HowshouldweinterpretthepreferenceonthepartofBritishinsuranceandpension organizationsfornotholdingUKTreasurybills,eventhoughastheNYFRBstudyputsit“itmight havepaidthemtodoso”?TheNYFRBascribesapartialexplanationto“habit”onthepartof Britishinsuranceandpensionschemes.Perhapsthisandthepreviousexplanationevidencedin theabovequotefromtheinsurancesectordoexplaininpartthepeculiarpreferencefor preferringtoearnaloweryield.However,giventheactiveroleofgovernmentinthe managementofUKeconomicaffairsinthepost-warperiod,questionsaboundoverwhether somedegreeofmoralsuasiononthepartoftheauthoritiescouldplayaroleinthese preferences. 198 CommitteeontheWorkingoftheMonetarySystem(RadcliffeCommittee),Question7092.UKNational Archives,1957-59 OthersignificantdifferencescanbeseenbetweentheUKandU.S.Treasurybillholdings inothersectorsoftheeconomy(Table11andTable12).UKnon-financialcorporationsheld just8%oftheUKTreasurybillmarketcomparedtothe18%heldbyequivalentU.S.firms. However,UKlocalauthoritiesheldjust0.1%oftheUKTreasurybillmarketandsowouldnot appear,atleastasof1964,tohavebeenapartytodirectedlendingschemes. Table11:UK%ofTotalTreasuryBillMarketHeldbySector,30September1964 Sector £smillions %ofT-billmarket Localauthorities £3 0.1% Insurance 3 - Trusteesavings 2 - Privatesectorpensionfunds - 0.1% Othernon-bankfinancialinstitutions 3 0.2% Non-corporatebodies(PublicTrustee) 5 0.1% Non-financialcorporations 4 7.7% Total £229 8.3% Source:CV61Ap.12,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,18October1965 Table12:U.S.%ofTotalTreasuryBillMarketHeldbySector,30September1964 Sector £smillions %ofT-billmarket Stateandlocalgovernments £1,940 12% Insurance 200 1% Mutualsavingsbanks 120 1% Savings&loans 240 1% Corporatepensiontrustfunds 290 2% Non-financialcorporations 2,830 18% Misc.(includingnon-banksecuritydealers) 3,017 19% Total £229 54% Source:CV61Ap.12,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,18October1965 The1964NYFRBstudyremarksonhowtheinstitutionalholdingsofUK(andU.S.)Treasurybills hasremainedconsistent“overthelastfouryears,eventhoughtherehasbeenanincreasein alternativeoutlets(forearninginterest)outsidethepublicsector”,particularlythetime certificateofdeposit.199 4.6Inflation Financialrepressioncanbeeffectivewithoutinflationbysimplyreducingthelevelof nominalinterestexpenseonpublicdebt.200However,inflationoftenaccompaniesfinancial repression,anditneednotbesignificanttohaveamaterialimpactondebtsustainabilityover anextendedperiodoftime.Further,smalldifferencesintherateofinflationcanhavea significantimpactovertimeonthevalueofpublicdebt,aswellasdeterminingthenumberof yearsorperiodswhichcanbelabelledasperiodsof‘debtliquidation’. OtherthantheWorldWarsandtheirimmediateaftermath,thefirsthalfofthe20th centuryinBritainwasmarkedbyverylittleinflation.201AstheSecondWorldWarcommenced Keynesarguedagainstwhathecalledthe‘old-fashionedlaissez-fairesolutionofinflation’asa meansofpayingforthewar.202InasectionofHowtoPayfortheWarcoveringinflationduring theperiodsurroundingfirstgreatconflictofthe20thcentury,Keyneswrote: “Butwhataridiculoussystemwithwagesandpriceschasingoneanother upwardsinthismanner!Noonebenefitedexcepttheprofiteer.Theseedsof muchsubsequenttroubleweresown.AndweendedupwithaNationalDebt vastlygreaterintermsofmoneythanwasnecessaryandveryilldistributed throughthecommunity.”203 MuchofKeynes’pre-andearly-warpolicyeffortswerespentadvocatingagainstthe government’suseofinflationasameansoffinancingthewar.204WhetherornotKeynes 199 CV61Ap.17,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,18October1965 (C.M.Reinhart&Sbrancia,2011) 201 (Capieetal.,1992,p.63)Infactmuchoftheinterwarperiodwasmarkedbydeflation. 202 (Keynes,1940,p.70;Skidelsky,2000,p.63)Keynes:“Anindividualbysavingmorecannotprotecthimselffrom theconsequencesofinflationifothersdonotfollowhisexample.” 203 (Keynes,1940,p.73)Also,inthechaptertitled‘CantheRichPayfortheWar?’,Keynesarguesthattherich wouldbetherelativebeneficiariesofinflation.(p.21) 204 (Skidelsky,2000,p.55) 200 intendedtoremainstaunchlyanti-inflationaryafterthewarisunclearashewasoftencriticized duringthisperiodfor‘makinguptheoryonthehoof’.205 Somewhatsurprisingly,deflationwasreportedbysometobeasgreataconcernas inflationbothduringthewarandthepost-warperiod.206However,aswithmanyotherwars inflationclimbedduringtheSecondWorldWar,withretailpricesincreasingonaverageby6.3% annually.207Thereissomedisputeintheliteratureonthelevelofinflationduringthewar(and afterward)withCairncross’estimating50%inflationduringtheSecondWorldWar.208Inflation intheSecondWorldWarwasapproximatelyhalfthatoftheFirst,withWoodward(1991) claimingthatthis“relativesuccess”wasachievedthrough“muchlessdependenceon borrowingandmoreconcertedefforttoreduceconsumptionthroughincreasedtaxation”.209 Rationingwasdeemedcrucialtomakingpricecontrolseffective.210Avarietyofmeasureswere employedtomanagedemand,prices,costs,andoverallinflationpressure,includingprice controls,subsidies,standardizationschemes,andqualitycontrols.Suchmeasurescould perhapsbeconsideredaselementsthatsupportedfinancialrepression,buttheygenerallyfall outsideofthedefinitionoffinancialrepression. Anotherhallmarkoffinancialrepressionisarelativelyhighsavingsrateinspiteoflow interestratesandorinflationduetofew(ifany)investmentorspendingalternatives.211 Averageweeklywagesfrom1940-1945increasedbyarateof5%peryear,laggingslightly behindpriceincreases.Woodward(1991)speculatesthattradeunions,whichhadastrong wagebargainingpositionduetolowunemployment,exercisedwagerestraintduetoboth sympathiesforthewareffortandtheirinclusioninwaradministration.Paradoxically,the 205 (Skidelsky,2000,p.23) (Dow&NationalInstituteofEconomicandSocialResearch.,1964,p.10)TheWhitePaperonEmployment Policy(Cmd.6527,1944)warnedofdeflation. 207 (Cairncross,1985;Crafts,Woodward,&Duckham,1991,p.189;Mitchell,1975)Wholesalepricesduringthis periodroseby8.8%annually. 208 (Cairncross,1985,pp.14-15) 209 (Craftsetal.,1991,p.190) 210 (Capie,Pradhan,Wood,&CityUniversity.CentrefortheStudyofMonetary,1986;Capie&Wood,2002) 211 (McKinnon,1973;Shaw,1973) 206 savingsratealsogrewduringthisinflationaryperiodofdecliningrealwagesto15%.212 However,thisisrevealedtobelesssurprisinggivenrationingandotherrestrictionson purchasesbothduringandafterthewar.213 Woodward(1991)claimsthatpost-SecondWorldWar(1945-1950)inflationaveraged 4.3%peryear,rangingbetween3-7%annually.214Realwageswereunchangedthrough1951 butrealearningsincreasedby10%.215In1948,30%ofconsumptionwasrationed;by1950only 11%.In194783%ofUKrawmaterialswereundersomedegreeofofficialcontrol;by1950the figurehaddeclinedto47%.216Woodwardalsostatesthatforthisperiod“atnotimewastherea returntotheexcessof1919-20”,whenannualinflationranat21.5%and24.8%,respectively.217 However,otherresearchsuggeststhatactualpost-warinflationwassignificantlyhigherthan nationallyreportedfiguresusedbyWoodwardandRichard(2002),particularlyifoneaddsthe early1950sintotheanalysiswheninflationapproachedpost-FirstWorldWarlevels.218 Cairncross(1985)notesthattheofficialCost-of-Livingindex,basedonpre-FirstWorld Warestimates,was“farfrombeingatruemeasureofthechangeinthevalueofmoney”.219 Woodwardalsostated“intheearlypost-waryearscontrolsweredeliberatelyusedtocontain demandpressuresandtopreventthepricesofanumberofkeycommoditiesfromrising rapidly.However,from1947onwardsthecontrolsweregraduallyrelaxed,andhadmoreorless disappearedwiththechangeingovernmentin1951”.220Whileitistruethatpriceanddemand controlswerelargelyremovedbytheearly1950s,Woodwardsaysnothingoffinancialcontrols, suchasthoseonforeignexchangeconversionandotherrestrictions,whichmayhaveplayeda 212 (Cairncross,1985,pp.13-14) (Zweiniger-Bargielowska,2000) 214 Thesefiguresarein-linewithRichards(2002)morerecentnumbers. 215 (Cairncross,1985,p.18) 216 (Cairncross,1985,p.23) 217 (Richards,2002,p.15) 218 (Díaz,Lüders,&Wagner,2003;Feinstein,1972;Friedman&Schwartz,1982;Price,1988;Wiles,1952) 219 (Cairncross,1985,p.39) 220 (Craftsetal.,1991,p.191) 213 significantroleinsuppressinginflationduringthistime.221ThegrowingconflictontheKorean peninsulain1950-51islargelycreditedwiththespikeininflationduringthisperiod.Thecostof rubbertripled,woolandcottondoubled,andnumerousothercommoditieswentupinpriceby 50%.222ThevariousinflationseriesfoundintheliteraturearepresentedinFigure10andTable 21. Figure3:UKInflation(RetailPrices),AnnualPercentageChange,1941-1960 25.0% 20.0% 15.0% 10.0% 5.0% 0.0% 1941 1943 1945 1947 1949 1951 1953 1955 1957 1959 -5.0% -10.0% Richards Diaz,etal Bain&Price Friedman&Schwartz SampleAverage Sources:Diaz,LudersandWagner(2005)Richards(2002),FriedmanandSchwartz(1982),PriceandBain(1988) Thesmallestandlargestvarianceintherangeofvaluesforanygivenyearduringthis periodare1.6%and10.5%fortheyears1946and1949,respectively.Overall,giventhewide variationininflationestimatesforthisperioditmaybemoreaccuratetoutilizearangeof inflationestimatesforcalculatingdebtliquidation. 221 (Craftsetal.,1991,p.191)WoodwardarguesthepostwarLabourGovernmentuseditcloserelationshipwith thetradeunionmovementtoexercisewagerestraint;1948wastheyearofthefirstvoluntaryincomepolicy, whichinsuredwageincreaseswerekeptwellbelowinflation. 222 (Dow&NationalInstituteofEconomicandSocialResearch.,1964,p.55) Table13:UKInflation(RetailPrices),AnnualPercentageChange,1945-1951 Year Richards 1945 3.2% 1946 3.5% 1947 7.4% 1948 6.6% 1949 2.6% 1950 2.8% 1951 9.5% Annual Average 5.1% Diaz 3.0% 3.6% 9.1% 7.8% 13.1% 0.3% 15.9% Bain& Price 5.1% 5.1% 8.2% 10.8% 5.1% 5.6% 16.6% 7.5% 8.1% Friedman& Schwartz 0.5% 3.8% 8.5% 12.3% 5.2% 1.7% 12.9% Sample Average 2.9% 4.0% 8.3% 9.4% 6.5% 2.6% 13.7% 6.4% 6.8% RangeHighLow* 4.6% 1.6% 1.7% 5.7% 10.5% 5.3% 7.1% 5.2% *Note:thedifferencebetweenthehighestandlowestestimateeachyear. Sources:Diaz,LudersandWagner(2005)Richards(2002),FriedmanandSchwartz(1982),PriceandBain(1988) 5Conclusion Thispaperhasshownthatopportunitiesexistforimprovingbothourquantitativeand qualitativeunderstandingoffinancialrepressionthroughanin-depthexaminationofBritish mid-20thcenturyfinancialrepression.Furtherresearchisnecessaryonwhowerethewinners andlosersoflowinterestrates.WorswickandAdy(1952)statethatlowinterestratesintheUK mayhavecauseda"redistributionfromthesmallertothelargerrentier”.223However,littleto noquantitativeevidenceispresentedtosupportthisclaim.Thereisalsothequestionofthe knock-oneffectsoflowinterestratesontheBritisheconomyandfinancialsystem.Duringthe post-waryears“anundulylargeproportionofworldtradehadcometobefinancedinLondon inordertotakeadvantageofthelowinterestrates”.224Buthowmuchdidthisinflowoffunds fortradefinancefurtherdestabilizethefragilebalanceinBritain,withitshigh-debtand overvaluedcurrency? Furtherresearchisalsonecessarytounderstandthetrade-offsbetweenthenegative consequencesoffinancialrepression,suchasitsimpactoneconomicgrowth,anditspotentially positivefeatures,suchasbuttressingthefinancialsystem.Inadditiontopromotingfinancial stability,financialrepressioncanhelpachievedebtsustainability.Contrarytowhatitsname implies,financialrepressionmayonoccasionbeanappropriatepolicy.Itmaythereforebe appropriatetodetermineamoreneutralnameforfinancialrepression,whichisoftenusedas pejorativeforscoringrhetoricalpointsinpolicydebates. 223 224 (Worswick&Ady,1952,pp.204-205) C261Ap.5,NewYorkFederalReserveBankArchive,25September,1952 References Agénor,P.R.(1992).Parallelcurrencymarketsindevelopingcountries:theory,evidence,and policyimplications:InternationalFinanceSection,DepartmentofEconomics,Princeton University. Aizenman,J.,Gavin,M.,&Hausmann,R.P.Guidotti.(1994):"Capitalcontrols,collectioncosts, anddomesticpublicdebt,".JournalofInternationalMoneyandFinance,13(1),41-54. Alesina,A.F.,Grilli,V.,&Milesi-Ferrett,G.M.(1993).Thepoliticaleconomyofcapitalcontrols. NationalBureauofEconomicResearchCambridge,Mass.,USA. Alexander,W.E.,Enoch,C.,Baliño,T.J.T.,&InternationalMonetaryFund.(1995).The adoptionofindirectinstrumentsofmonetarypolicy.Washington,DC:International MonetaryFund. Austin,K.E.(1989).ForeignExchangeRestrictions,MonetaryPolicy,andMacroeconomic StabilityintheThirdWorld.JournalofEconomicDevelopment,14,7-33. BankforInternationalSettlements.(1941).Foreignexchangeregulations:GreatBritain(2nd ed.ed.).Basle::BankforInternationalSettlements. Barro,R.J.,&Salaimartin,X.(1990).WorldRealInterest-Rates.NberMacroeconomicsAnnual 1990,15-59.Retrievedfrom<GotoISI>://A1990BT47V00002 Bemanke,B.,&James,H.(1991).Thegoldstandard,deflation,andfinancialcrisisintheGreat Depression:Aninternationalcomparison:UniversityofChicagoPress. Bhagwati,J.(1978).ForeignTradeRegimesandEconomicDevelopment:Anatomyand ConsequencesofExchangeControlRegimes(Cambridge,Mass.:Ballinger). Blanchard,O.J.,&Summers,L.H.(1984).PerspectivesonHighWorldRealInterest-Rates. BrookingsPapersonEconomicActivity(2),273-334.Retrievedfrom<Goto ISI>://A1984TX72700001 Blitz,R.C.,&Long,M.F.(1965).TheEconomicsofUsuryRegulation.JournalofPolitical Economy,73(6),608-619.Retrievedfrom<GotoISI>://A1965CAL0200004 Booth,A.(1989).Britisheconomicpolicy,1931-49:wasthereaKeynesianrevolution?London: HarvesterWheatsheaf. Bordo,M.D.,&Landon-Lane,J.S.(2010).TheGlobalFinancialCrisisof2007-08:Isit Unprecedented?Retrievedfrom Burk,K.(1989).MorganGrenfell1838-1988:thebiographyofaMerchantbank.Oxford:Oxford UniversityPresss. Cairncross,A.(1985).Yearsofrecovery:Britisheconomicpolicy1945-51.London:Methuen. Cairncross,A.,&Eichengreen,B.J.(1983).Sterlingindecline:thedevaluationsof1931,1949 and1967.Oxford:Blackwell. Campbell,J.Y.,&Froot,K.A.(1994).InternationalExperienceswithSecuritiesTransaction Taxes.InternationalizationofEquityMarkets,277-308.Retrievedfrom<Goto ISI>://A1994BC79M00007 Capie,F.(2010).TheBankofEngland:1950sto1979.CambridgeU.K.;NewYork:Cambridge UniversityPress. Capie,F.,&CityUniversity.CentreforBankingandInternationalFinance.CentrefortheStudy ofMonetaryHistory.(1987).StructureandperformanceinBritishbanking,1870-1939. London:CityUniversity. Capie,F.,Collins,M.,&InstituteofEconomicAffairs.(1992).HavethebanksfailedBritish industry?:anhistoricalsurveyofbank/industryrelationsinBritain,1870-1990.London: InstituteofEconomicAffairs. Capie,F.,Pradhan,M.,Wood,G.E.,&CityUniversity.CentrefortheStudyofMonetary,H. (1986).Pricesandpricecontrols:arepricecontrolsapolicyinstrument?:CityUniversity, CentreforBankingandInternationalFinance,CentrefortheStudyofMonetaryHistory. Capie,F.,&Wood,G.(2002).Pricecontrolsinwarandpeace:Amarshallianconclusion.Scottish JournalofPoliticalEconomy,49(1),39-60.Retrievedfrom<Goto ISI>://000174169000003 Chinn,M.,&Frankel,J.(2005).Theeuroareaandworldinterestrates.WisconsinandHarvard mimeo. Cooper,R.N.,Tarullo,D.K.,&Williamson,J.(1999).Shouldcapitalcontrolsbebanished? BrookingsPapersonEconomicActivity,1999(1),89-141. Crafts,N.F.R.,Woodward,N.W.C.,&Duckham,B.F.(1991).TheBritisheconomysince1945. OxfordEngland OxfordEngland;NewYork:ClarendonPress; OxfordUniversityPress. DelaTorre,A.,Gozzi,J.C.,&Schmukler,S.L.(2007).Innovativeexperiencesinaccessto finance:marketfriendlyrolesforthevisiblehand?World. DeVegh,I.,&ScudderStevens&Clark.(1939).Thepoundsterling:astudyofthebalanceof paymentsofthesterlingarea.NewYork:s.n. Díaz,J.,Lüders,R.,&Wagner,G.(2003).LaRepúblicaenCifras:Chile1810-2000.Manuscript, CentralBankofChile. Dow,J.C.R.,&NationalInstituteofEconomicandSocialResearch.(1964).Themanagementof theBritisheconomy,1945-60.Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress. Dreher,A.,Herz,B.,&Karb,V.(2006).Isthereacausallinkbetweencurrencyanddebtcrises? InternationalJournalofFinance&Economics,11(4),305-325.doi:10.1002/ijfe.300 Drelichman,M.,&Voth,H.J.(2008).Debtsustainabilityinhistoricalperspective:Theroleof fiscalrepression.JournaloftheEuropeanEconomicAssociation,6(2-3),657-667. Retrievedfrom<GotoISI>://000255691700032 Dulles,E.L.(1929).Frenchfranc,1914-1928:Thefactsandtheirinterpretation. Durbin,E.F.M.(1939).Howtopayforthewar:anessayonthefinancingofwar.London:G. Routledgeandsons,ltd. Easterly,W.(1993).HowMuchDoDistortionsAffectGrowth.JournalofMonetaryEconomics, 32(2),187-212.Retrievedfrom<GotoISI>://A1993MT04400001 Edwards,S.(1999).Howeffectivearecapitalcontrols?Retrievedfrom Eichengreen,B.(1996).Institutionsandeconomicgrowth:EuropeafterWorldWarII.InN.F.R. Crafts,Toniolo,Gianni(Ed.),EconomicgrowthinEuropesince1945(pp.38-72). Eichengreen,B.J.(1998).Globalizingcapital:ahistoryoftheinternationalmonetarysystem: PrincetonUniversityPress. Evans-Pritchard,A.(7July,2011).Europe,FreeSpeech,andthesinisterrepressionofthe RatingAgencies.TheTelegraph.Retrievedfrom http://blogs.telegraph.co.uk/finance/ambroseevans-pritchard/100010742/europe-freespeech-and-the-sinister-repression-of-the-rating-agencies/ Feinstein,C.H.(1972).Nationalincome,expenditureandoutputoftheUnitedKingdom,18551965.London:CambridgeUniversityPress. Ferguson,N.(2008).Theascentofmoney:afinancialhistoryoftheworld.NewYork:Penguin Press. Ferguson,N.(2010).Highfinancier:thelivesandtimeofSiegmundWarburg.London:Allen Lane. Fforde,J.(1992).TheBankofEnglandandpublicpolicy,1941-1958.Cambridge:Cambridge UniversityPress. Flandreau,M.,&Oosterlinck,K.(2011).WastheEmergenceoftheInternationalGoldStandard Expected?MelodramaticEvidencefromIndianGovernmentSecurities.WorkingPapers CEB. Frey,B.S.,&Waldenström,D.(2004).Marketsworkinwar:WorldWarIIreflectedintheZurich andStockholmbondmarkets.FinancialHistoryReview,11(01),51-67. Friedman,M.,&Schwartz,A.J.(1982).MonetarytrendsintheUnitedStatesandtheUnited Kingdom:theirrelationtoincome,prices,andinterestrates,1867-1975.Chicago; London:UniversityofChicagoPress. Galindo,A.,Micco,A.,Ordoñez,G.,Bris,A.,&Repetto,A.(2002).FinancialLiberalization:Does ItPaytoJointheParty?[withComments].Economia,3(1),231-261. Giovannini,A.,&Demelo,M.(1993).GovernmentRevenuefromFinancialRepression. AmericanEconomicReview,83(4),953-963.Retrievedfrom<Goto ISI>://A1993LZ14100014 Goldsmith,R.W.(1969).Financialstructureanddevelopment.NewHaven,Conn:Yale UniversityPress. Green,T.(1968).Theworldofgold.London:Joseph. Green,T.(1973).Theworldofgoldtoday(Rev.ed.).London:ArrowBooks. Green,T.(1981).Thenewworldofgold:theinsidestoryofthemines,themarkets,thepolitics, theinvestors.London:WeidenfeldandNicolson. Greenwood,J.,&Kimbrough,K.P.(1987).Foreignexchangecontrolsinablackmarket economy.JournalofDevelopmentEconomics,26(1),129-143. Grossman,R.S.(1994).Theshoethatdidn’tdrop:explainingbankingstabilityduringthegreat depression.JournalofEconomicHistory,54(3),654-682. Gurley,J.G.,&Shaw,E.S.(1955).Financialaspectsofeconomicdevelopment.TheAmerican EconomicReview,45(4),515-538. Gurley,J.G.,Shaw,E.S.,Enthoven,A.C.,&BrookingsInstitution.(1960).Moneyinatheoryof finance.Washington,D.C.:BrookingsInstitution. Harrod,R.,&PrincetonUniversity.DepartmentofEconomicsandSociology.International FinanceSection.(1952).Thepoundsterling.Princeton:PrincetonUniversity, DepartmentofEconomicsandSociology,InternationalFinanceSection. Harrod,R.F.(1951).ThelifeofJohnMaynardKeynes.London:Macmillan. Homer,S.(1963).Ahistoryofinterestrates. Howson,S.(1988).CheapmoneyanddebtmanagementinBritain1932–51.MoneyandPower: EssaysinHonourofLSPressnell,Basingstoke,Macmillan. Ingham,G.K.(1984).Capitalismdivided?:thecityandindustryinBritishsocialdevelopment. Basingstoke:Macmillan. InstituteofBankers.(1949).CurrentfinancialproblemsandtheCityofLondon:aseriesof lecturesdeliveredatthefirstInternationalBankingSummerSchool.London:Europa Publications. Keynes,J.M.(1936).Thegeneraltheoryofemploymentinterestandmoney.London:Macmillan andCo. Keynes,J.M.(1940).Howtopayforthewar:aradicalplanforthechancelloroftheexchequer. London:MacmillanandCo.,limited. Koedijk,K.G.,Kool,C.J.M.,&Kroes,T.R.P.J.(1994).ChangesinWorldRealInterest-Ratesand InflationaryExpectations.WeltwirtschaftlichesArchiv-ReviewofWorldEconomics, 130(4),714-729.Retrievedfrom<GotoISI>://A1994QA84300003 Kynaston,D.(1999).TheCityofLondonVol.3Illusionsofgold,1914-1945.London:Chatto& Windus. Lane,F.C.(1937).Venetianbankers,1496-1533:Astudyintheearlystagesofdepositbanking. TheJournalofPoliticalEconomy,45(2),187-206. Lanyi,A.,&Saracoglu,R.(1983).Theimportanceofinterestratesindevelopingeconomies. FinanceandDevelopment,20(2),20-23. Llewellyn,D.T.(1985).TheEvolutionoftheBritishFinancialSystem:InstituteofBankers. Llewellyn,D.T.(1985).TheevolutionoftheBritishfinancialsystem.Gilbartlectureson banking(1985),59p. Lucas,R.E.(1990).WorldRealInterest-Rates-Comment.NberMacroeconomicsAnnual,5,6973.Retrievedfrom<GotoISI>://A1990FT84200004 McKinnon,R.I.(1973).Moneyandcapitalineconomicdevelopment.Washington:Brookings Institution. Mitchell,B.R.(1975).Europeanhistoricalstatistics1750-1970.London:MacmillanPress. Montiel,P.,&Reinhart,C.M.(1999).Docapitalcontrolsandmacroeconomicpoliciesinfluence thevolumeandcompositionofcapitalflows?Evidencefromthe1990s.Journalof InternationalMoneyandFinance,18(4),619-635. Morgan,E.V.,&Thomas,W.A.(1962).TheStockExchange:itshistoryandfunctions:Elek. Moulton,H.G.,&Mcguire,C.E.(1923).Germany&scapacitytopay:Astudyofthereparation problem. Obstfeld,M.,&Taylor,A.M.(2004).Globalcapitalmarkets:integration,crisis,andgrowth. Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress. Paish,F.W.(1947).Cheapmoneypolicy.Economica,14(55),167-179. Paish,F.W.(1950).Thepost-warfinancialproblem,andotheressays.London,:Macmillan. Pick,F.(1953).Blackmarketyearbook:Pick'scurrencyyearbook.NewYork. Price,R.a.B.,GeorgeSayers(1988).TheLabourForce.InA.H.Halsey(Ed.),Britishsocialtrends since1900:aguidetothechangingsocialstructureofBritain(pp.iv,600p). Basingstoke:Macmillan. Quennouëlle-Corre,L.,&Cassis,Y.(2011).Financialcentresandinternationalcapitalflowsin thenineteenthandtwentiethcenturies.Oxford;NewYork:OxfordUniversityPress. Quinn,D.(1997).Thecorrelatesofchangeininternationalfinancialregulation.American PoliticalScienceReview,91(3),531-551.Retrievedfrom<Goto ISI>://A1997XV70700002 Quinn,D.P.,&Toyoda,A.M.(2008).Doescapitalaccountliberalizationleadtogrowth? ReviewofFinancialStudies,21(3),1403-1449.doi:Doi10.1093/Rfs/Hhn034 Reinhart,C.,Kirkegaard,J.,&Sbrancia,B.(2011).FinancialRepressionRedux.IMFFinanceand Development,22-26.Retrievedfrom http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2011/06/pdf/reinhart.pdf Reinhart,C.,&Reinhart,V.(1999).Ontheuseofreserverequirementsindealingwithcapital flowproblems. Reinhart,C.M.,&Rogoff,K.S.(2009).Thistimeisdifferent:eightcenturiesoffinancialfolly. Princeton:PrincetonUniversityPress. Reinhart,C.M.,&Rogoff,K.S.(2011).ADecadeofDebt.Retrievedfrom Reinhart,C.M.,&Sbrancia,M.B.(2011).TheLiquidationofGovernmentDebt.Retrievedfrom Richards,P.(2002).InflationThevalueofthepound1750-2001.Retrievedfrom http://www.parliament.uk/documents/commons/lib/research/rp2002/rp02-044.pdf Roubini,N.,&Salaimartin,X.(1992).FinancialRepressionandEconomic-Growth.Journalof DevelopmentEconomics,39(1),5-30.Retrievedfrom<GotoISI>://A1992JJ94600002 Sayers,R.S.(1953).Modernbanking(3rded.).Oxford:ClarendonPress. Sayers,R.S.(1956).Financialpolicy,1939-45.London,:H.M.StationeryOff. Sayers,R.S.(1968).GillettsintheLondonmoneymarket1867-1967.Oxford,:ClarendonP. Sayers,R.S.(1976).TheBankofEngland1891-1944.Volume2.Cambridge:Cambridge UniversityPress. Sayers,R.S.(1981).BankrateinKeynes'scentury:BritishAcademy. Sbrancia,M.B.(2011).Debt,Inflation,andtheLiquidationEffect.UniversityofMaryland, CollegePark.Mimeograph. Schenk,C.R.(1994).Britainandthesterlingarea:fromdevaluationtoconvertibilityinthe 1950s.London;NewYork:Routledge. Schenk,C.R.(2010).Thedeclineofsterling:managingtheretreatofaninternationalcurrency, 1945-1992.Cambridge,UK;NewYork:CambridgeUniversityPress. Shaw,E.S.(1973).Financialdeepeningineconomicdevelopment.NewYork:OxfordUniversity Press. Skidelsky,R.J.A.(2000).JohnMaynardKeynes.Vol.3,FightingforBritain:1937-1946.London: Macmillan. Strange,S.,&RoyalInstituteofInternationalAffairs.(1971).SterlingandBritishpolicy:a politicalstudyofaninternationalcurrencyindecline.London:OxfordUniversityPress fortheRoyalInstituteofInternationalAffairs. Taylor,A.(2011).Commenton'TheLiquidationofGovernementDebt'byReinhartandSbrancia (2011). TheEconomist.(22May,1948,22May,1948).FreeSterlinginEurope.TheEconomist. Wicker,E.(2001).ThebankingpanicsoftheGreatDepression:CambridgeUnivPr. Wiles,P.J.D.(1952).Pre-WarandWar-TimeControlsInTheBritishEconomy,1945–50: London:OxfordUniversityPress. Wilson,J.F.(1995).Britishbusinesshistory,1720-1994.Manchester;NewYork:Manchester UniversityPress:DistributedexclusivelyintheUSAandCanadabySt.Martin'sPress. WorldBank.(1989).WorldDevelopmentReport.Washington,DC:WorldBank. Worswick,G.D.N.,&Ady,P.H.(1952).TheBritisheconomy,1945-1950.Oxford:Clarendon Press. Wyplosz,C.(1986).CapitalControlsandBalanceofPaymentsCrises.JournalofInternational MoneyandFinance,5(2),167-179.Retrievedfrom<GotoISI>://A1986D497600003 Wyplosz,C.(2001).FinancialrestraintsandliberalizationinpostwarEurope.Financial Liberalization:HowFar,HowFast,125-158. Yi,K.M.,Blankenau,W.,&Kose,M.A.(2001).Canworldrealinterestratesexplainbusiness cyclesinasmallopeneconomy?JournalofEconomicDynamics&Control,25(6-7),867889.Retrievedfrom<GotoISI>://000168189100003 Zweiniger-Bargielowska,I.(2000).AusterityinBritain:rationing,controls,andconsumption, 1939-1955.Oxford:OxfordUniversityPress.